首页 > 最新文献

Columbia Law School最新文献

英文 中文
'Une Chose Publique'? The Author's Domain and the Public Domain in Early British, French and Us Copyright Law “我选择了Publique”?早期英国、法国和美国版权法中的作者领域和公共领域
Pub Date : 2006-09-08 DOI: 10.1017/S0008197306007252
J. Ginsburg
Much contemporary copyright rhetoric casts copyright as a derogation from a primordial public domain. Placing the public domain in the initial position buttresses attempts to contain a perceived over-expansion of copyright. I do not take issue with the normative role these endeavors assign to the public domain. The public domain is today and should remain copyright's constraining counterpart. But normative arguments that also claim the support of history may be fundamentally anachronistic. The ensuing examination of the respective domains of author and public at copyright's inception, in 18th-19th century Britain, France and America, reveals more ambiguity than today's critiques generally acknowledge. In England, John Locke supplied the philosophical basis for a common law of authorial property rights before the passage of the first copyright statute, the Statute of Anne of 1710. The post-statutory caselaw belies the proposition that the statute provided the sole source of authors' enforceable legal rights. Had the Statute of Anne created property rights ex nihilo, then the following propositions should be true: 1. Subject matter not included within the statute was not protected 2. Protection for covered subject matter depended on compliance with statutory formalities 3. Rights not included within the statute were not protected 4. The duration of rights was limited to the statutory term In fact, only the last of these ultimately proved to be correct, and the decision that determined the issue, Donaldson v. Beckett, was hotly debated, even deplored, at the time by significant expositors of the common law. More importantly, resolution of the duration issue did not fully contain the author's domain. English judges continued both to grant extra-statutory protections, and to interpret hospitably claims that pushed the limits of statutory scope. In revolutionary France, the rhetoric of "propriete publique" held greater sway than in Britain. Advocates stressed both the public utility of works of authorship and the public's claims to unfettered use following a statutory period to which the author, as the work's creator, was justly entitled. But the author's claims were set against the backdrop of a broader public entitlement. Paradoxically, however, while the French sources articulated a concept of the public domain in many ways consistent with today's characterizations, the substantive law was in fact far more protective of authorial property rights than either British or American law at the time. Finally, early American copyright history reveals even greater ambiguities. If the word "securing" in the constitutional copyright clause indicates that the Framers perceived that authors enjoyed preexisting common law property rights in their works, the heavy formalities imposed by subsequent statutes suggest a more positivistic view. In Wheaton v. Peters, the Supreme Court rejected common law copyright in published works, but for reasons extraneous to compet
许多当代版权修辞将版权视为对原始公共领域的贬损。将公共领域置于首要位置,有助于遏制人们认为的版权过度扩张。我对这些努力赋予公共领域的规范性角色没有异议。公共领域在今天是,并且应该继续是版权的限制性对应物。但是,同样声称有历史支持的规范性论点可能从根本上是不合时宜的。随后,在18 -19世纪的英国、法国和美国,对版权开始时作者和公众各自领域的考察,揭示了比今天的批评普遍承认的更多的模糊性。在英国,约翰·洛克(John Locke)在第一部版权法——1710年的《安妮法令》(statute of Anne)通过之前,为作者财产权的普通法提供了哲学基础。成文法后的判例法掩盖了成文法为作者提供可执行法律权利的唯一来源的主张。如果《安妮法令》无为地创造了财产权,那么下列命题应该是正确的:未包括在法令范围内的标的物不受保护。承保标的物的保护取决于是否遵守法定手续。未列入法令的权利不受保护。权利的持续时间被限制在法定期限内,事实上,只有最后一条最终被证明是正确的,而决定这个问题的判决,唐纳森诉贝克特案,在当时受到了普通法重要阐释者的激烈辩论,甚至是谴责。更重要的是,持续时间问题的解决并没有完全包含作者的领域。英国法官继续给予法律之外的保护,并友好地解释超越法律范围的诉讼请求。在大革命时期的法国,“适当公众”的修辞比英国更有影响力。倡导者强调作者身份作品的公共效用和公众在法定期限后不受限制地使用作品的权利,而作者作为作品的创造者,理应享有这一权利。但作者的主张是在更广泛的公众权利的背景下提出的。然而,矛盾的是,虽然法国文献在许多方面阐明了公共领域的概念,与今天的特征一致,但实体法实际上比当时的英美法律更能保护作者的财产权。最后,美国早期的版权历史揭示了更大的模糊性。如果宪法版权条款中的“保护”一词表明,制宪者认为作者在其作品中享有预先存在的普通法财产权,那么随后的法规所规定的繁文缛节则表明了一种更为实证的观点。在惠顿诉彼得斯案(Wheaton v. Peters)中,最高法院驳回了对已出版作品的普通法版权保护,但理由与作者和公众领域这一相互竞争的概念无关。惠顿依靠“确保”来支持州普通法对其出版的报告的版权保护,这与吉本斯诉奥格登案中汽船垄断者不成功的论点相呼应,后者声称,“确保”意味着各州保护著作和发明的剩余权力,因此纽约有权授予汽船发明者在哈德逊河上的独家航行权。由于“确保”一词带有马歇尔法院在吉本斯案中推翻的州际贸易壁垒的污点,惠顿后来试图说服该法院恢复剩余的国家垄断权力的努力注定要失败。尽管惠顿驳回了普通法对已出版作品的版权保护,但作者的权利范围并未严格限制在联邦法规的狭窄范围内。公共领域始于出版物。未出版的作品仍然是国家普通法权利的对象,随着时间的推移,法院在作品中制定了一个平行的普通法权利领域,这些作品虽然在技术上是"未出版"的,因为它们没有以副本分发给公众,但仍然遇到了重大的,有时甚至是大规模的公众曝光。因此,即使在像美国版权这样实证主义的制度中,法官也会找到机会承认作者的法外文学财产权。
{"title":"'Une Chose Publique'? The Author's Domain and the Public Domain in Early British, French and Us Copyright Law","authors":"J. Ginsburg","doi":"10.1017/S0008197306007252","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1017/S0008197306007252","url":null,"abstract":"Much contemporary copyright rhetoric casts copyright as a derogation from a primordial public domain. Placing the public domain in the initial position buttresses attempts to contain a perceived over-expansion of copyright. I do not take issue with the normative role these endeavors assign to the public domain. The public domain is today and should remain copyright's constraining counterpart. But normative arguments that also claim the support of history may be fundamentally anachronistic. The ensuing examination of the respective domains of author and public at copyright's inception, in 18th-19th century Britain, France and America, reveals more ambiguity than today's critiques generally acknowledge. In England, John Locke supplied the philosophical basis for a common law of authorial property rights before the passage of the first copyright statute, the Statute of Anne of 1710. The post-statutory caselaw belies the proposition that the statute provided the sole source of authors' enforceable legal rights. Had the Statute of Anne created property rights ex nihilo, then the following propositions should be true: 1. Subject matter not included within the statute was not protected 2. Protection for covered subject matter depended on compliance with statutory formalities 3. Rights not included within the statute were not protected 4. The duration of rights was limited to the statutory term In fact, only the last of these ultimately proved to be correct, and the decision that determined the issue, Donaldson v. Beckett, was hotly debated, even deplored, at the time by significant expositors of the common law. More importantly, resolution of the duration issue did not fully contain the author's domain. English judges continued both to grant extra-statutory protections, and to interpret hospitably claims that pushed the limits of statutory scope. In revolutionary France, the rhetoric of \"propriete publique\" held greater sway than in Britain. Advocates stressed both the public utility of works of authorship and the public's claims to unfettered use following a statutory period to which the author, as the work's creator, was justly entitled. But the author's claims were set against the backdrop of a broader public entitlement. Paradoxically, however, while the French sources articulated a concept of the public domain in many ways consistent with today's characterizations, the substantive law was in fact far more protective of authorial property rights than either British or American law at the time. Finally, early American copyright history reveals even greater ambiguities. If the word \"securing\" in the constitutional copyright clause indicates that the Framers perceived that authors enjoyed preexisting common law property rights in their works, the heavy formalities imposed by subsequent statutes suggest a more positivistic view. In Wheaton v. Peters, the Supreme Court rejected common law copyright in published works, but for reasons extraneous to compet","PeriodicalId":10506,"journal":{"name":"Columbia Law School","volume":"19 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2006-09-08","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"81874481","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 21
Whose Ox is Being Gored? When Attitudinalism Meets Federalism 谁的牛被捅了?当态度主义遇上联邦制
Pub Date : 2006-01-01 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.887744
Michael C. Dorf
Empirical research indicates that factors such as an individual Justice's general political ideology play a substantial role in the decision of Supreme Court cases. Although this pattern holds in federalism cases, views about the proper allocation of authority between the state and federal governments - independent of whether the particular outcome in any given case is "liberal" or "conservative" - can sometimes be decisive, as demonstrated by the 2005 decision in Gonzales v. Raich, in which "conservative" Justices voted to invalidate a strict federal drug provision in light of California's legalization of medical marijuana, and "liberal" Justices voted to uphold the federal law. Proponents of a strongly legal realist view of the Court might argue that views about federalism are themselves ideological, or that Justices who commit themselves to defending or opposing states' rights do so because of a calculation about the likely long-term consequences of such a position. But they do so only by draining the realist enterprise of its descriptive and normative power, because, as this Essay argues, genuine principles about federalism are distinctly legal, even if formed on the basis of long-term calculations about the likely effects of various views about federalism. Taking federalism as a point of departure, this Essay describes and justifies a method by which Justices choose the legal principles that bind them.
实证研究表明,大法官个人的一般政治意识形态等因素在最高法院案件的判决中起着重要作用。尽管这种模式在联邦制案件中成立,但关于州政府和联邦政府之间权力的适当分配的观点——与任何特定案件的特定结果是“自由派”还是“保守派”无关——有时可能是决定性的,正如2005年冈萨雷斯诉莱希案的判决所证明的那样,在该案中,“保守派”法官根据加州医用大麻的合法化投票否决了一项严格的联邦药物规定。而“自由派”法官则投票支持联邦法律。对最高法院持强烈法律现实主义观点的支持者可能会争辩说,关于联邦制的观点本身就是意识形态的,或者那些致力于捍卫或反对各州权利的法官之所以这样做,是因为他们对这种立场可能产生的长期后果进行了计算。但他们只有通过耗尽现实主义事业的描述性和规范性力量才能做到这一点,因为,正如本文所论证的那样,关于联邦制的真正原则显然是合法的,即使是在对关于联邦制的各种观点可能产生的影响进行长期计算的基础上形成的。本文以联邦制为出发点,描述并论证了法官选择约束他们的法律原则的方法。
{"title":"Whose Ox is Being Gored? When Attitudinalism Meets Federalism","authors":"Michael C. Dorf","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.887744","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.887744","url":null,"abstract":"Empirical research indicates that factors such as an individual Justice's general political ideology play a substantial role in the decision of Supreme Court cases. Although this pattern holds in federalism cases, views about the proper allocation of authority between the state and federal governments - independent of whether the particular outcome in any given case is \"liberal\" or \"conservative\" - can sometimes be decisive, as demonstrated by the 2005 decision in Gonzales v. Raich, in which \"conservative\" Justices voted to invalidate a strict federal drug provision in light of California's legalization of medical marijuana, and \"liberal\" Justices voted to uphold the federal law. Proponents of a strongly legal realist view of the Court might argue that views about federalism are themselves ideological, or that Justices who commit themselves to defending or opposing states' rights do so because of a calculation about the likely long-term consequences of such a position. But they do so only by draining the realist enterprise of its descriptive and normative power, because, as this Essay argues, genuine principles about federalism are distinctly legal, even if formed on the basis of long-term calculations about the likely effects of various views about federalism. Taking federalism as a point of departure, this Essay describes and justifies a method by which Justices choose the legal principles that bind them.","PeriodicalId":10506,"journal":{"name":"Columbia Law School","volume":"185 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2006-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"74405135","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 3
Takeovers in the Boardroom: Burke Versus Schumpeter 董事会中的收购:伯克与熊彼特
Pub Date : 2005-05-01 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.732783
R. Gilson, Reinier H. Kraakman
This article was written for a symposium on the occasion of the 25th anniversary of Martin Lipton's 1979 article, Takeover Bids in the Target's Boardroom. In our view, Takeover Bids is a Burkean take on a messy Schumpeterian world that, during 1980s, reached its apex in Drexel Burnham's democratization of finance through the junk bond market. But the irony is that today, long after the Delaware Supreme Court has adopted many of Lipton's views, there is a new market for corporate control that no longer poses the threats - or supports the opportunities - that the market of the 1980s created. Today's strategic bidders and their targets share the same boardroom views. And for precisely this reason, "just say no" is no longer the battle cry that it once was. It stirred the crowds in the past precisely because hostile takeovers could be credibly depicted as a sweeping threat to the status quo - a claim that no one would make about today's strategic bidders. The market for corporate control now is a process of peer review, rather than an instrument of systemic change. What is lost as a result is just what, in the conservative view, has been gained: the capacity of the market for corporate control to ignite the dynamism that in our view has served the U.S. economy so well. Although Lipton may still lose today's battle to allow targets to just say no to intra-establishment takeovers, he will still have won the larger war. For now, at least, boardrooms are insulated from much of the force of a truly Schumpeterian market in corporate control of the sort we briefly glimpsed during the 1980s.
这篇文章是为纪念马丁·利普顿1979年的文章《目标公司董事会的收购出价》发表25周年而写的。在我们看来,《收购出价》是伯克式对熊彼特式混乱世界的再现,而熊彼特式混乱世界在上世纪80年代,随着德崇证券(Drexel Burnham)通过垃圾债券市场实现金融民主化,达到了顶峰。但具有讽刺意味的是,今天,在特拉华州最高法院采纳了利普顿的许多观点很久之后,出现了一个新的公司控制市场,它不再构成威胁,也不再支持上世纪80年代市场创造的机会。今天的战略竞标者和他们的目标有着相同的董事会观点。正是由于这个原因,“说不”不再是曾经的战斗口号。这在过去曾引起轰动,正是因为敌意收购可以被可信地描述为对现状的全面威胁——没有人会对今天的战略竞购者这样说。公司控制权市场现在是一个同行评议的过程,而不是系统性变革的工具。结果,在保守主义者看来,失去的恰恰是得到的:企业控制市场的能力,这种能力点燃了我们认为对美国经济非常有益的活力。尽管利普顿可能仍然会在今天的战斗中输掉允许目标对内部收购说不的战斗,但他仍然会赢得更大的战争。至少就目前而言,董事会与我们在上世纪80年代短暂看到的那种真正熊彼特式的企业控制市场的力量隔绝开来。
{"title":"Takeovers in the Boardroom: Burke Versus Schumpeter","authors":"R. Gilson, Reinier H. Kraakman","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.732783","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.732783","url":null,"abstract":"This article was written for a symposium on the occasion of the 25th anniversary of Martin Lipton's 1979 article, Takeover Bids in the Target's Boardroom. In our view, Takeover Bids is a Burkean take on a messy Schumpeterian world that, during 1980s, reached its apex in Drexel Burnham's democratization of finance through the junk bond market. But the irony is that today, long after the Delaware Supreme Court has adopted many of Lipton's views, there is a new market for corporate control that no longer poses the threats - or supports the opportunities - that the market of the 1980s created. Today's strategic bidders and their targets share the same boardroom views. And for precisely this reason, \"just say no\" is no longer the battle cry that it once was. It stirred the crowds in the past precisely because hostile takeovers could be credibly depicted as a sweeping threat to the status quo - a claim that no one would make about today's strategic bidders. The market for corporate control now is a process of peer review, rather than an instrument of systemic change. What is lost as a result is just what, in the conservative view, has been gained: the capacity of the market for corporate control to ignite the dynamism that in our view has served the U.S. economy so well. Although Lipton may still lose today's battle to allow targets to just say no to intra-establishment takeovers, he will still have won the larger war. For now, at least, boardrooms are insulated from much of the force of a truly Schumpeterian market in corporate control of the sort we briefly glimpsed during the 1980s.","PeriodicalId":10506,"journal":{"name":"Columbia Law School","volume":"25 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2005-05-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"74423428","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 9
Institutional Change and M&A in Japan: Diversity Through Deals 制度变迁与日本并购:交易中的多元化
Pub Date : 2001-11-01 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.290744
C. Milhaupt, Mark D. West
This Article offers new perspectives on the market for corporate control, the convergence debate, and Japanese corporate governance. We begin by applying in the corporate governance setting two related insights from other fields: from economics, the theory that there is no universally efficient organizational model; from organizational behavior, evidence that diverse groups outperform homogeneous ones. We then consider the potential for convergence toward a particular governance technology - the market for corporate control - to increase the desirable trait of diversity within economic systems. Takeovers, we argue, are not exclusively a disciplinary device, but also an engine of managerial and legal innovation. We apply these insights to Japan through a detailed examination of previously unexplored data on Japanese M&A. We first link the historically low level of Japanese M&A activity to a thick institutional environment much more complex than the conventional focus on cross-shareholding suggests. Among the more startling findings is the existence of negative control premiums in Japanese tender offers and the role of legal shareholder protections in dampening the market for corporate control. Next, we show how the dearth of takeovers is inextricably linked to the lack of diversity in Japanese corporate practices. We then explore how recent changes in "institutions for deals" in Japan correlate with increased takeover activity, which in turn is linked to the creation of a broader range of governance practices, managerial innovations, and structural shifts in corporate lawmaking processes. The Article concludes by analyzing the implications of our findings for two academic debates: the role of functional substitutes in comparative corporate governance theory, and the impact of legal investor protections on corporate governance patterns.
本文提供了关于公司控制市场、趋同争论和日本公司治理的新视角。我们首先将其他领域的两个相关见解应用到公司治理设置中:从经济学的角度来看,没有普遍有效的组织模型;从组织行为学来看,多样化的团队表现优于同质的团队。然后,我们考虑了向特定治理技术——公司控制市场——趋同的潜力,以增加经济体系内多样性的理想特征。我们认为,收购不仅是一种惩戒手段,也是管理和法律创新的引擎。我们将这些见解应用到日本,通过详细检查以前未开发的日本并购数据。我们首先将日本并购活动处于历史低位与厚重的制度环境联系起来,这种制度环境比传统上对交叉持股的关注所表明的要复杂得多。更令人吃惊的发现包括,日本收购要约中存在负控制权溢价,以及股东法律保护在抑制公司控制权市场方面的作用。接下来,我们将说明收购的缺乏与日本企业实践缺乏多样性是如何密不可分的。然后,我们探讨了最近日本“交易制度”的变化如何与收购活动的增加相关联,而收购活动又与更广泛的治理实践、管理创新和公司立法过程中的结构性转变有关。文章最后分析了本文的研究结果对两个学术争论的启示:功能替代在比较公司治理理论中的作用,以及法律投资者保护对公司治理模式的影响。
{"title":"Institutional Change and M&A in Japan: Diversity Through Deals","authors":"C. Milhaupt, Mark D. West","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.290744","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.290744","url":null,"abstract":"This Article offers new perspectives on the market for corporate control, the convergence debate, and Japanese corporate governance. We begin by applying in the corporate governance setting two related insights from other fields: from economics, the theory that there is no universally efficient organizational model; from organizational behavior, evidence that diverse groups outperform homogeneous ones. We then consider the potential for convergence toward a particular governance technology - the market for corporate control - to increase the desirable trait of diversity within economic systems. Takeovers, we argue, are not exclusively a disciplinary device, but also an engine of managerial and legal innovation. We apply these insights to Japan through a detailed examination of previously unexplored data on Japanese M&A. We first link the historically low level of Japanese M&A activity to a thick institutional environment much more complex than the conventional focus on cross-shareholding suggests. Among the more startling findings is the existence of negative control premiums in Japanese tender offers and the role of legal shareholder protections in dampening the market for corporate control. Next, we show how the dearth of takeovers is inextricably linked to the lack of diversity in Japanese corporate practices. We then explore how recent changes in \"institutions for deals\" in Japan correlate with increased takeover activity, which in turn is linked to the creation of a broader range of governance practices, managerial innovations, and structural shifts in corporate lawmaking processes. The Article concludes by analyzing the implications of our findings for two academic debates: the role of functional substitutes in comparative corporate governance theory, and the impact of legal investor protections on corporate governance patterns.","PeriodicalId":10506,"journal":{"name":"Columbia Law School","volume":"9 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2001-11-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"90427238","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 18
Political Preconditions to Separating Ownership from Corporate Control 所有权与公司控制权分离的政治前提
Pub Date : 2000-12-01 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.165143
M. Roe
The large public firm dominates business in the United States despite its critical infirmities, namely the frequently fragile relations between stockholders and managers. Managers' agendas can differ from shareholders'; tying managers tightly to shareholders has been central to American corporate governance. But in other economically-advanced nations ownership is not diffuse but concentrated. It is concentrated in no small measure because the delicate threads that tie managers to shareholders in the public firm fray easily in common political environments, such as those in the continental European social democracies. Social democracies press managers to stabilize employment, press them to forego even some profit-maximizing risks with the firm, and press them to use up capital in place rather than to down-size when markets no longer are aligned with firm's production capabilities. Since managers must have discretion in the public firm, how they use that discretion is crucial to stockholders, and social democratic pressures on managers induce them to stray from their shareholders' preference to maximize profits. Moreover, the means that align managers with diffuse stockholders in the United States--incentive compensation, transparent accounting, hostile takeovers, and strong shareholder-wealth maximization norms--are harder to implement in continental social democracies. Hence, public firms in social democracies will, all else equal, have higher managerial agency costs, and large-block shareholding will persist as shareholders' next best remaining way to control those costs. Indeed, when we line up the world's richest nations on a left-right continuum and then line them up on a close to diffuse ownership continuum, the two correlate powerfully. True, the effects on total social welfare are ambiguous; social democracies may enhance total social welfare, but if they do, they do so with fewer public firms than less socially-responsive nations. We thus uncover not only a political explanation for ownership concentration in Europe, but also a crucial political prerequisite to the rise of the public firm in the United States, namely the absence of a strong social democracy and the concomitant political pressures it would have put on the American business firm.
大型上市公司在美国的商业中占据主导地位,尽管它存在严重的缺陷,即股东和经理之间经常存在脆弱的关系。管理者的议程可能与股东的有所不同;将管理者与股东紧密联系在一起一直是美国公司治理的核心。但在其他经济发达国家,所有权不是分散的,而是集中的。这在很大程度上是集中的,因为在普通的政治环境中,比如在欧洲大陆的社会民主国家,将上市公司的管理者与股东联系在一起的微妙线索很容易断裂。社会民主主义迫使管理者稳定就业,迫使他们放弃哪怕是一些与企业一起实现利润最大化的风险,并迫使他们在市场不再与企业的生产能力相一致时耗尽现有资本,而不是缩小规模。由于上市公司的管理者必须拥有自由裁量权,他们如何使用这种自由裁量权对股东来说至关重要,而社会民主主义对管理者的压力促使他们偏离股东的偏好,以实现利润最大化。此外,在美国,激励薪酬、透明会计、敌意收购和强有力的股东财富最大化规范等使经理人与分散股东保持一致的手段,在大陆社会民主国家更难实施。因此,在其他条件相同的情况下,社会民主国家的上市公司将有更高的管理代理成本,而大规模持股将继续作为股东控制这些成本的下一个最佳方式。事实上,当我们把世界上最富有的国家按左右连续线排列,然后把它们按近乎分散的所有权连续线排列时,两者之间的相关性很强。诚然,对社会总福利的影响是模糊的;社会民主国家可能会提高社会总福利,但即便如此,它们的公共企业数量也要少于社会反应较差的国家。因此,我们不仅揭示了欧洲所有权集中的政治解释,而且还揭示了美国上市公司崛起的关键政治先决条件,即缺乏强大的社会民主以及随之而来的对美国商业公司施加的政治压力。
{"title":"Political Preconditions to Separating Ownership from Corporate Control","authors":"M. Roe","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.165143","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.165143","url":null,"abstract":"The large public firm dominates business in the United States despite its critical infirmities, namely the frequently fragile relations between stockholders and managers. Managers' agendas can differ from shareholders'; tying managers tightly to shareholders has been central to American corporate governance. But in other economically-advanced nations ownership is not diffuse but concentrated. It is concentrated in no small measure because the delicate threads that tie managers to shareholders in the public firm fray easily in common political environments, such as those in the continental European social democracies. Social democracies press managers to stabilize employment, press them to forego even some profit-maximizing risks with the firm, and press them to use up capital in place rather than to down-size when markets no longer are aligned with firm's production capabilities. Since managers must have discretion in the public firm, how they use that discretion is crucial to stockholders, and social democratic pressures on managers induce them to stray from their shareholders' preference to maximize profits. Moreover, the means that align managers with diffuse stockholders in the United States--incentive compensation, transparent accounting, hostile takeovers, and strong shareholder-wealth maximization norms--are harder to implement in continental social democracies. Hence, public firms in social democracies will, all else equal, have higher managerial agency costs, and large-block shareholding will persist as shareholders' next best remaining way to control those costs. Indeed, when we line up the world's richest nations on a left-right continuum and then line them up on a close to diffuse ownership continuum, the two correlate powerfully. True, the effects on total social welfare are ambiguous; social democracies may enhance total social welfare, but if they do, they do so with fewer public firms than less socially-responsive nations. We thus uncover not only a political explanation for ownership concentration in Europe, but also a crucial political prerequisite to the rise of the public firm in the United States, namely the absence of a strong social democracy and the concomitant political pressures it would have put on the American business firm.","PeriodicalId":10506,"journal":{"name":"Columbia Law School","volume":"1 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2000-12-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"82212365","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 270
期刊
Columbia Law School
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1