首页 > 最新文献

Corporate Law: Corporate & Takeover Law最新文献

英文 中文
The Delisting Decision: The Case of Buyout Offers with Squeeze-Out (BOSO) 退市决策:以BOSO收购要约为例
Pub Date : 2010-11-29 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.1717018
S. Serve, Isabelle Martinez
In this paper, we exploit the specificity of going-private transactions that are initiated by the historic controlling shareholders (i.e. voluntary delistings). In Continental Europe, the majority of firms that become private do so following a buyout offer with squeeze-out (BOSO); using this mechanism, the controlling shareholder can cash out minorities and take the firm private. We argue that the decision to go private results from a cost–benefit analysis. Moreover, we pay particular attention to the consequences and the related costs of compliance resulting from the passage of the French Financial Security Law (FSL) in 2003. A quantitative study was performed using a unique dataset spanning 1997–2006. This data set consists of 140 French firms, of which 70 were voluntarily delisted via BOSO and 70 were industry-matched control firms. Univariate analysis and logistic regressions support the cost–benefit analysis: when listing benefits decrease because of weak liquidity and/or weak analyst coverage, it seems better for the firm to go private. Furthermore, the inherent characteristics of delisted firms (i.e. performance, leverage, and risk as measured by the beta factor) appear to be important driving factors of delisting. The passage of the FSL has strengthened the impact of these characteristics on the decision to go private. Mature firms that have weak performance and low specific risk and that are not financially constrained by debt will decide to go private because they cannot afford the listing status anymore. Finally, we show that the driving factors of delisting differ according to the identity of the controlling shareholder; specifically, the level of risk appears to be the strongest determinant for family firms, while non-family firms also consider their own financial structure.
在本文中,我们利用了历史控股股东发起的私有化交易(即自愿退市)的特殊性。在欧洲大陆,大多数私有化的公司都是在收购要约和挤出(BOSO)之后实现私有化的;利用这种机制,控股股东可以将少数股权套现,并将公司私有化。我们认为,私有化的决定是成本效益分析的结果。此外,我们特别关注2003年法国金融安全法(FSL)通过后的后果和合规相关成本。使用跨越1997-2006年的独特数据集进行了定量研究。该数据集由140家法国公司组成,其中70家通过BOSO自愿退市,70家是行业匹配的控制公司。单变量分析和逻辑回归支持成本效益分析:当上市收益因流动性弱和/或分析师覆盖面弱而下降时,公司私有化似乎更好。此外,退市公司的内在特征(即业绩、杠杆和风险衡量的贝塔因子)似乎是退市的重要驱动因素。FSL的通过加强了这些特征对私有化决策的影响。业绩不佳、特定风险较低、财务上不受债务约束的成熟公司将决定私有化,因为它们再也负担不起上市的费用。最后,根据控股股东身份的不同,退市的驱动因素也不同;具体而言,风险水平似乎是家族企业最重要的决定因素,而非家族企业也会考虑自身的财务结构。
{"title":"The Delisting Decision: The Case of Buyout Offers with Squeeze-Out (BOSO)","authors":"S. Serve, Isabelle Martinez","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.1717018","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1717018","url":null,"abstract":"In this paper, we exploit the specificity of going-private transactions that are initiated by the historic controlling shareholders (i.e. voluntary delistings). In Continental Europe, the majority of firms that become private do so following a buyout offer with squeeze-out (BOSO); using this mechanism, the controlling shareholder can cash out minorities and take the firm private. We argue that the decision to go private results from a cost–benefit analysis. Moreover, we pay particular attention to the consequences and the related costs of compliance resulting from the passage of the French Financial Security Law (FSL) in 2003. A quantitative study was performed using a unique dataset spanning 1997–2006. This data set consists of 140 French firms, of which 70 were voluntarily delisted via BOSO and 70 were industry-matched control firms. Univariate analysis and logistic regressions support the cost–benefit analysis: when listing benefits decrease because of weak liquidity and/or weak analyst coverage, it seems better for the firm to go private. Furthermore, the inherent characteristics of delisted firms (i.e. performance, leverage, and risk as measured by the beta factor) appear to be important driving factors of delisting. The passage of the FSL has strengthened the impact of these characteristics on the decision to go private. Mature firms that have weak performance and low specific risk and that are not financially constrained by debt will decide to go private because they cannot afford the listing status anymore. Finally, we show that the driving factors of delisting differ according to the identity of the controlling shareholder; specifically, the level of risk appears to be the strongest determinant for family firms, while non-family firms also consider their own financial structure.","PeriodicalId":106641,"journal":{"name":"Corporate Law: Corporate & Takeover Law","volume":"1 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2010-11-29","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"130758353","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 45
Shareholder Oppression and Reasonable Expectations: Of Change, Gifts, and Inheritances in Close Corporation Disputes 股东压迫与合理预期:公司纠纷中的变动、赠与与继承
Pub Date : 2010-08-23 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.297503
Douglas K. Moll
By identifying and protecting the "reasonable expectations" of close corporation stockholders, the doctrine of shareholder oppression attempts to safeguard the close corporation minority investor from the improper exercise of majority control. The leading formulation of the reasonable expectations inquiry focuses on the shareholder's expectations at the time he decided to invest in the business. For the disputes that characterize most of the published oppression decisions, this "time of investment" focus is suitable, as the aggrieved shareholder is usually complaining about expectations that were established around the time of the shareholder's actual commitment of capital to the business. In certain significant contexts, however, a time of investment focus is problematic. First, a strict time of investment standard seems to ignore the possibility that post-investment expectations may arise. Focusing on one point in time - the time of investment - to measure the shareholder's expectations fails to capture potentially valid and reasonable expectations that may develop well after a shareholder commits capital to the venture. Second, a strict time of investment framework fails to account for close corporation shareholders who have made no investment at all in the company. This group of "non-investing shareholders" includes, among others, stockholders who receive their shares as gifts or inheritances. Because these shareholders have committed no capital themselves, there is, literally-speaking, no "time of investment" peculiar to them. For this group, therefore, an assessment of reasonable expectations at the time of investment may lead to a conclusion that no specific reasonable expectations exist at all. This Article analyzes whether and how the reasonable expectations inquiry could be applied to these changing expectations and non-investing shareholder cases. By conceiving of oppression as a doctrine that protects the fair value of the shareholder's investment, this Article provides a context for thinking about the purpose of the shareholder oppression doctrine and its accompanying reasonable expectations inquiry. Using this "investment model" of oppression as a guide, the Article argues that the law should view a reasonable expectation as a bargain struck between majority and minority shareholders over a specific entitlement the minority is to receive in return for its investment in the company. Because majority and minority shareholders may strike these "investment bargains" throughout their participation in a close corporation, the Article contends that the oppression doctrine should look for evidence of such bargains during the entirety of the shareholders' relationship, rather than merely at the narrower time of investment. The reasonable expectations inquiry, therefore, should reflect this broader perspective. Moreover, although non-investing stockholders do not, by definition, commit any of their own capital to the company, they too may rea
通过识别和保护封闭型公司股东的“合理预期”,股东压迫原则试图保护封闭型公司的小股东不受不当行使多数控制权的影响。合理期望调查的主要形式是关注股东在决定投资企业时的期望。对于大多数公开的压迫性决策的争议特征,这种“投资时间”的焦点是合适的,因为受害的股东通常抱怨的是在股东实际向企业投入资金时建立的期望。然而,在某些重大情况下,集中投资的时间是有问题的。首先,严格的投资时间标准似乎忽略了投资后预期可能产生的可能性。专注于一个时间点——投资时间——来衡量股东的期望,无法捕捉到潜在的有效和合理的期望,这些期望可能在股东向企业投入资金后很好地发展。其次,严格的投资时间框架没有考虑到没有对公司进行任何投资的公司近距离股东。这类“非投资性股东”包括以礼物或遗产方式获得股票的股东。因为这些股东自己没有投入资金,所以从字面上讲,他们没有所谓的“投资时间”。因此,对于这一群体,在投资时对合理期望的评估可能会得出一个结论,即根本不存在具体的合理期望。本文分析了合理期望调查是否适用于这些变化的期望和非投资股东案件,以及如何适用于这些案件。通过将压迫视为一种保护股东投资公允价值的原则,本文为思考股东压迫原则的目的及其伴随的合理期望调查提供了一个背景。以这种压迫的“投资模式”为指导,文章认为,法律应将合理预期视为大股东和小股东之间就少数股东对公司投资的回报而获得的特定权利达成的交易。由于大股东和小股东在参与一个紧密的公司的过程中可能会达成这些“投资讨价还价”,文章认为,压迫原则应该在整个股东关系中寻找这种讨价还价的证据,而不仅仅是在较窄的投资时期。因此,合理预期调查应反映这一更广泛的观点。此外,尽管根据定义,不投资的股东不会将自己的任何资本投入公司,但他们也可能与大多数人达成共识,如果事实证明,应该作为投资便宜货受到保护。本文第一部分论述了封闭式公司的性质,阐述了股东压迫原则的发展。第二部分阐述了封闭式公司股东投资的特殊性和压迫性投资模式。虽然衡量合理预期的投资焦点时间不太适合涉及不断变化的预期或非投资股东的纠纷,但本部分解释说,投资调查时间与投资模型的理论是一致的。在此分析的基础上,第三部分讨论了股东期望随时间变化所带来的问题。由于公司法旨在防止冻结行为,本部分认为法律应保护投资后预期。此外,通过借鉴关系契约理论,本部分为验证和执行投资后预期提供了额外的基础,即使少数股东没有提供额外的考虑。第四部分探讨了非投资股东的困惑,以及压迫主义对这些各方可能采取的各种立场。在讨论了非投资股东是否应该(1)完全没有具体的合理期望,(2)只有其投资转让方的具体合理期望,或(3)有任何可以证明的具体合理期望之后,本部分得出结论,第三种选择促进了公平,并与压迫投资模型提供了一致性。最后,第五部分考虑了在单一创始人案例中转让人意图的作用。本部分建议,创始人的意图应仅作为合理预期分析中的证据因素,而不是用于约束继承股东。
{"title":"Shareholder Oppression and Reasonable Expectations: Of Change, Gifts, and Inheritances in Close Corporation Disputes","authors":"Douglas K. Moll","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.297503","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.297503","url":null,"abstract":"By identifying and protecting the \"reasonable expectations\" of close corporation stockholders, the doctrine of shareholder oppression attempts to safeguard the close corporation minority investor from the improper exercise of majority control. The leading formulation of the reasonable expectations inquiry focuses on the shareholder's expectations at the time he decided to invest in the business. For the disputes that characterize most of the published oppression decisions, this \"time of investment\" focus is suitable, as the aggrieved shareholder is usually complaining about expectations that were established around the time of the shareholder's actual commitment of capital to the business. In certain significant contexts, however, a time of investment focus is problematic. First, a strict time of investment standard seems to ignore the possibility that post-investment expectations may arise. Focusing on one point in time - the time of investment - to measure the shareholder's expectations fails to capture potentially valid and reasonable expectations that may develop well after a shareholder commits capital to the venture. Second, a strict time of investment framework fails to account for close corporation shareholders who have made no investment at all in the company. This group of \"non-investing shareholders\" includes, among others, stockholders who receive their shares as gifts or inheritances. Because these shareholders have committed no capital themselves, there is, literally-speaking, no \"time of investment\" peculiar to them. For this group, therefore, an assessment of reasonable expectations at the time of investment may lead to a conclusion that no specific reasonable expectations exist at all. This Article analyzes whether and how the reasonable expectations inquiry could be applied to these changing expectations and non-investing shareholder cases. By conceiving of oppression as a doctrine that protects the fair value of the shareholder's investment, this Article provides a context for thinking about the purpose of the shareholder oppression doctrine and its accompanying reasonable expectations inquiry. Using this \"investment model\" of oppression as a guide, the Article argues that the law should view a reasonable expectation as a bargain struck between majority and minority shareholders over a specific entitlement the minority is to receive in return for its investment in the company. Because majority and minority shareholders may strike these \"investment bargains\" throughout their participation in a close corporation, the Article contends that the oppression doctrine should look for evidence of such bargains during the entirety of the shareholders' relationship, rather than merely at the narrower time of investment. The reasonable expectations inquiry, therefore, should reflect this broader perspective. Moreover, although non-investing stockholders do not, by definition, commit any of their own capital to the company, they too may rea","PeriodicalId":106641,"journal":{"name":"Corporate Law: Corporate & Takeover Law","volume":"11 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2010-08-23","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"128399545","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 3
Valuation of Shares in Small and Medium-Sized Enterprises - A Legal Perspective on Valuation with a Special Emphasis on Shareholder Conflicts 中小企业股份估值——以股东冲突为重点的估值法律视角
Pub Date : 2010-01-01 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.1709952
Martin Christian Kruhl
Over time all close cooperative relationships will experience conflicts. Shareholders in small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) are no exception. The vast majority of such conflicts are solved through continuing dialogue and negotiations between the shareholders. However, in some cases a conflict can be so severe that an amicable solution is not possible. In such cases the only alternative to dissolution of the company will typically be one or more of the shareholders leaving the company by selling their shares – but the question is at what price? The paper discusses shareholder conflicts and valuation of shares in exit situations in a company law context. Emphasis is on the regulation in the Danish Companies Act, but also the regulations contained in the company law statutes of the other Scandinavian countries are discussed. The paper covers regulation, general legal issues involved in the valuation of shares, regulation laid down in contract (shareholders’ agreement) or articles of association, and valuation methods. The paper argues that there should be some form of statutory regulation regarding the basic legal assumptions involved in valuing shares.
随着时间的推移,所有亲密的合作关系都会经历冲突。中小企业的股东也不例外。绝大多数此类冲突都是通过股东之间的持续对话和谈判来解决的。然而,在某些情况下,冲突可能非常严重,以至于不可能以友好的方式解决。在这种情况下,公司解散的唯一选择通常是一个或多个股东通过出售他们的股票离开公司——但问题是以什么价格?本文从公司法的角度讨论了退出情况下的股东冲突和股票估值问题。重点是丹麦公司法中的规定,但也讨论了其他斯堪的纳维亚国家的公司法法规中包含的规定。本文涵盖了监管、涉及股票估值的一般法律问题、合同(股东协议)或公司章程中规定的监管以及估值方法。本文认为,对于股票估值所涉及的基本法律假设,应该有某种形式的法定监管。
{"title":"Valuation of Shares in Small and Medium-Sized Enterprises - A Legal Perspective on Valuation with a Special Emphasis on Shareholder Conflicts","authors":"Martin Christian Kruhl","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.1709952","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1709952","url":null,"abstract":"Over time all close cooperative relationships will experience conflicts. Shareholders in small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) are no exception. The vast majority of such conflicts are solved through continuing dialogue and negotiations between the shareholders. However, in some cases a conflict can be so severe that an amicable solution is not possible. In such cases the only alternative to dissolution of the company will typically be one or more of the shareholders leaving the company by selling their shares – but the question is at what price? The paper discusses shareholder conflicts and valuation of shares in exit situations in a company law context. Emphasis is on the regulation in the Danish Companies Act, but also the regulations contained in the company law statutes of the other Scandinavian countries are discussed. The paper covers regulation, general legal issues involved in the valuation of shares, regulation laid down in contract (shareholders’ agreement) or articles of association, and valuation methods. The paper argues that there should be some form of statutory regulation regarding the basic legal assumptions involved in valuing shares.","PeriodicalId":106641,"journal":{"name":"Corporate Law: Corporate & Takeover Law","volume":"3 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2010-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"134149496","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Informed Trading around Acquisitions: Evidence from Corporate Bonds 并购交易:来自公司债券的证据
Pub Date : 2009-02-04 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.1337803
Simi Kedia, Xing (Alex) Zhou
This paper examines the prevalence of informed trading in corporate bonds prior to takeover announcements. We find significant pre-announcement trading activities and price movements in target bonds, in directions consistent with the nature of pending information. Improved transparency in the bond markets achieved by the implementation of the Trade Reporting and Compliance Engine (TRACE) system reduces the incidence of informed trading. Further, there is some weak evidence that dealers affiliated with merger and acquisition advisors sell in anticipation of negative news, pointing to a possible channel of information leakage. Such negative news seems to be incorporated into bond prices no slower than into the target stocks.
本文考察了收购公告前公司债券知情交易的普遍程度。我们发现显著的公告前交易活动和目标债券的价格变动,方向与待决信息的性质一致。通过实施交易报告和合规引擎(TRACE)系统,提高了债券市场的透明度,减少了知情交易的发生。此外,有一些微弱的证据表明,与并购顾问公司有关联的经销商在预期负面消息的情况下出售股票,这表明可能存在信息泄露的渠道。这些负面消息被纳入债券价格的速度似乎并不比纳入目标股的速度慢。
{"title":"Informed Trading around Acquisitions: Evidence from Corporate Bonds","authors":"Simi Kedia, Xing (Alex) Zhou","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.1337803","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1337803","url":null,"abstract":"This paper examines the prevalence of informed trading in corporate bonds prior to takeover announcements. We find significant pre-announcement trading activities and price movements in target bonds, in directions consistent with the nature of pending information. Improved transparency in the bond markets achieved by the implementation of the Trade Reporting and Compliance Engine (TRACE) system reduces the incidence of informed trading. Further, there is some weak evidence that dealers affiliated with merger and acquisition advisors sell in anticipation of negative news, pointing to a possible channel of information leakage. Such negative news seems to be incorporated into bond prices no slower than into the target stocks.","PeriodicalId":106641,"journal":{"name":"Corporate Law: Corporate & Takeover Law","volume":"112 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2009-02-04","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"117278004","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 75
Primetime for Subprime: Evaluation of the Treasury's Proposal to Prevent Another Credit Crisis 次贷的黄金时期:对财政部防止另一场信贷危机提议的评估
Pub Date : 2008-12-09 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.1313694
David Schneider
The first part explains how the symbiotic relationship between subprime mortgages and the derivatives market, together with regulatory acquiescence caused the current credit crisis. The second part explains the Treasury's proposal to prevent another credit crisis by adopting an objectives-based regulatory structure. Finally, the third part offers a critique of the Treasury's proposed objectives-based regulatory structure and instead advocates in favor of a single consolidated regulator structure.
第一部分解释了次级抵押贷款与衍生品市场的共生关系以及监管默许是如何导致当前信贷危机的。第二部分解释了财政部通过采用基于目标的监管结构来防止另一场信贷危机的建议。最后,第三部分对财政部提出的基于目标的监管结构提出了批评,并主张支持单一的整合监管结构。
{"title":"Primetime for Subprime: Evaluation of the Treasury's Proposal to Prevent Another Credit Crisis","authors":"David Schneider","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.1313694","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1313694","url":null,"abstract":"The first part explains how the symbiotic relationship between subprime mortgages and the derivatives market, together with regulatory acquiescence caused the current credit crisis. The second part explains the Treasury's proposal to prevent another credit crisis by adopting an objectives-based regulatory structure. Finally, the third part offers a critique of the Treasury's proposed objectives-based regulatory structure and instead advocates in favor of a single consolidated regulator structure.","PeriodicalId":106641,"journal":{"name":"Corporate Law: Corporate & Takeover Law","volume":"151 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2008-12-09","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"133677213","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Blockholder Scarcity, Takeovers, and Ownership Structures 大股东稀缺性、收购和所有权结构
Pub Date : 2008-12-01 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.796784
Matthias Kahl, Gary B. Gorton
Agency problems in firms are prevalent because of a scarcity of wealthy principals with corporate governance ability, whom we call “restructuring specialists.” We investigate how this scarce resource, “agency cost-free capital,” is allocated. We show that the restructuring specialists may acquire blocks only in those states of the worls in which they can increase firm value the most, which corresponds to a takeover. Firms with dispersed ownership and firms with a financial intermediary as a blockholder can coexist, although they are otherwise identical. The moderl can explain differences in corporate ownership structures and restructuring mechanisms across economies.
代理问题在公司中很普遍,因为缺乏富有的具有公司治理能力的委托人,我们称之为“重组专家”。我们研究如何分配这种稀缺资源,“代理无成本资本”。我们表明,重组专家可能只在他们能够最大程度地增加公司价值的世界状态下收购区块,这对应于收购。分散所有权的公司和金融中介作为大股东的公司可以共存,尽管它们在其他方面是相同的。现代模型可以解释不同经济体之间公司所有权结构和重组机制的差异。
{"title":"Blockholder Scarcity, Takeovers, and Ownership Structures","authors":"Matthias Kahl, Gary B. Gorton","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.796784","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.796784","url":null,"abstract":"Agency problems in firms are prevalent because of a scarcity of wealthy principals with corporate governance ability, whom we call “restructuring specialists.” We investigate how this scarce resource, “agency cost-free capital,” is allocated. We show that the restructuring specialists may acquire blocks only in those states of the worls in which they can increase firm value the most, which corresponds to a takeover. Firms with dispersed ownership and firms with a financial intermediary as a blockholder can coexist, although they are otherwise identical. The moderl can explain differences in corporate ownership structures and restructuring mechanisms across economies.","PeriodicalId":106641,"journal":{"name":"Corporate Law: Corporate & Takeover Law","volume":"19 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2008-12-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"121891796","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 18
The Morally Distinct Corporation: Reclaiming the Relational Dimension of Conscience 道德上独特的公司:重拾良知的关系维度
Pub Date : 2008-10-01 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.1028881
Robert K. Vischer
The law has tended to deal with conscience at points of direct conflict between the individual and the state, but rights of conscience have also been invoked in a recent series of high-profile disputes between the individual and non-state associations. This trend is driven by a generally laudable commitment to minimize external interference with an individual's moral autonomy, but we must remember that the vibrancy of conscience depends in part on the vitality of the associations against which the right of conscience is currently being invoked. Missing from our conversation about conscience is a robust articulation of its relational dimension - i.e., the notion that the dictates of conscience are defined, articulated, and lived out in relationship with others. Conscience is shaped externally; our moral convictions have sources, and our sense of self comes into relief through interaction with others. Conscience, by its very nature, directs our gaze outward, to sources of formation, to communities of discernment, and to venues for expression. When the state closes down avenues by which persons live out their core beliefs - and admittedly, some avenues must be closed if peaceful co-existence is to be possible - there is a cost to the continued vitality of conscience. It is not just a vague allegiance to moral pluralism that should underlie our legal system's reluctance to restrict the independence of the myriad associations that make up the vast space between person and state; it is a commitment to freedom of conscience. Put simply, if our society is to facilitate an authentic and robust liberty of conscience, we cannot reflexively favor individual autonomy against group authority; we must also work to cultivate the spaces in which individuals come together to live out the shared dictates of conscience. This article is part of a bigger project outlining how the law can better support this relational dimension of conscience in a variety of areas. Here I explore the broad implications that conscience's relational dimension has for our understanding of corporations and their role in society. The exploration has three components: first, connecting liberty of conscience with the common good, explaining why institutional autonomy is an essential component of both; second, examining whether for-profit corporations may properly be considered venues for the communal expression and implementation of conscience, looking specifically at the capacity of corporations such as Wal-Mart to carve out moral identities as marketplace actors that diverge from the norms embraced by the broader society; and third, analyzing the tension between a corporation's moral identity and the exercise of conscience by dissenting community members, particularly employees.
法律倾向于在个人与国家之间的直接冲突中处理良心问题,但在最近一系列引人注目的个人与非国家组织之间的纠纷中,良心权利也被援引。推动这一趋势的是一种普遍值得称赞的承诺,即尽量减少对个人道德自主的外部干预,但我们必须记住,良心的活力部分取决于目前援引良心权利所反对的那些协会的活力。在我们关于良心的讨论中,缺失的是对其关系维度的强有力的阐述——也就是说,良心的指令是在与他人的关系中被定义、表达和实现的。良心是外在形成的;我们的道德信念是有来源的,我们的自我意识通过与他人的互动而得到缓解。良知,就其本质而言,引导我们的目光向外,到形成的来源,到辨别的社区,到表达的场所。当国家关闭人们实现其核心信仰的途径时——诚然,如果要实现和平共处,就必须关闭一些途径——良心的持续活力是有代价的。我们的法律体系不愿限制构成个人与国家之间广阔空间的无数社团的独立性,这不仅仅是对道德多元主义的模糊忠诚;这是对良心自由的承诺。简而言之,如果我们的社会要促进一种真实而强大的良心自由,我们就不能条件反射地赞成个人自治,反对群体权威;我们还必须努力培育让人们走到一起,共同践行良知的空间。本文是一个更大项目的一部分,该项目概述了法律如何在各种领域更好地支持良心的关系维度。在这里,我探讨了良心的关系维度对我们理解公司及其在社会中的角色的广泛影响。这一探索有三个组成部分:首先,将良心自由与共同利益联系起来,解释为什么机构自治是两者的重要组成部分;第二,研究营利性公司是否可以适当地被视为公众表达和实施良心的场所,具体考察沃尔玛等公司作为偏离广泛社会所接受的规范的市场参与者的道德身份的能力;第三,分析公司的道德认同与持不同意见的社区成员(尤其是员工)行使良知之间的紧张关系。
{"title":"The Morally Distinct Corporation: Reclaiming the Relational Dimension of Conscience","authors":"Robert K. Vischer","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.1028881","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.1028881","url":null,"abstract":"The law has tended to deal with conscience at points of direct conflict between the individual and the state, but rights of conscience have also been invoked in a recent series of high-profile disputes between the individual and non-state associations. This trend is driven by a generally laudable commitment to minimize external interference with an individual's moral autonomy, but we must remember that the vibrancy of conscience depends in part on the vitality of the associations against which the right of conscience is currently being invoked. Missing from our conversation about conscience is a robust articulation of its relational dimension - i.e., the notion that the dictates of conscience are defined, articulated, and lived out in relationship with others. Conscience is shaped externally; our moral convictions have sources, and our sense of self comes into relief through interaction with others. Conscience, by its very nature, directs our gaze outward, to sources of formation, to communities of discernment, and to venues for expression. When the state closes down avenues by which persons live out their core beliefs - and admittedly, some avenues must be closed if peaceful co-existence is to be possible - there is a cost to the continued vitality of conscience. It is not just a vague allegiance to moral pluralism that should underlie our legal system's reluctance to restrict the independence of the myriad associations that make up the vast space between person and state; it is a commitment to freedom of conscience. Put simply, if our society is to facilitate an authentic and robust liberty of conscience, we cannot reflexively favor individual autonomy against group authority; we must also work to cultivate the spaces in which individuals come together to live out the shared dictates of conscience. This article is part of a bigger project outlining how the law can better support this relational dimension of conscience in a variety of areas. Here I explore the broad implications that conscience's relational dimension has for our understanding of corporations and their role in society. The exploration has three components: first, connecting liberty of conscience with the common good, explaining why institutional autonomy is an essential component of both; second, examining whether for-profit corporations may properly be considered venues for the communal expression and implementation of conscience, looking specifically at the capacity of corporations such as Wal-Mart to carve out moral identities as marketplace actors that diverge from the norms embraced by the broader society; and third, analyzing the tension between a corporation's moral identity and the exercise of conscience by dissenting community members, particularly employees.","PeriodicalId":106641,"journal":{"name":"Corporate Law: Corporate & Takeover Law","volume":"20 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2008-10-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"123655394","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
China, Business Law, and Finance - Accession to the World Trade Organization 中国、商法与金融-加入世界贸易组织
Pub Date : 2008-09-01 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.1276348
Joseph Vining
China's entry into the world economy will affect not just how we act but how we think. It will affect especially what "business," "business law," and "business corporation" come to mean both in a transnational setting and in American law. The nature of American business law today still stands in the way of a wholly profit-maximizing approach to law or the world in general. But there is strong pressure, consistent with a general tendency in Western thought, to make business and corporate decision-making entirely manipulative and calculating and to eliminate the force of human value from it. This Youde Lecture traces the development of the business entity and the conception of its purpose in American business law - including late-twentieth century discussion in the American Law Institute - and describes contemporary efforts to change the legal statement of corporate purpose. It observes that the twentieth century struggle between "socialism" and "capitalism" did not end in utter elimination of the influence of the ideals that might be expressed in "socialism," including its Chinese form. The development of China's economic institutions and China's participation in world trade may have the surprising effect of blunting contemporary pressure to change American business law, and ultimately making the way we think fifty years hence more humane than it might otherwise have been.
中国加入世界经济不仅会影响我们的行为,也会影响我们的思维。它尤其会影响“商业”、“商业法”和“商业公司”在跨国环境和美国法律中的含义。今天,美国商业法的本质仍然阻碍着对法律或整个世界采取完全利润最大化的方法。但是有一种强大的压力,与西方思想的普遍趋势一致,使商业和公司决策完全被操纵和计算,并从中消除人类价值的力量。尤德讲座追溯了商业实体的发展及其在美国商法中宗旨的概念——包括20世纪后期美国法律研究所的讨论——并描述了当代改变公司宗旨法律声明的努力。文章指出,20世纪“社会主义”和“资本主义”之间的斗争并没有以“社会主义”(包括其中国形式)可能表达的理想的影响完全消除而告终。中国经济体制的发展和中国对世界贸易的参与可能会产生令人惊讶的效果,削弱当代要求改变美国商业法的压力,并最终使我们50年后的思维方式比原本可能的更人性化。
{"title":"China, Business Law, and Finance - Accession to the World Trade Organization","authors":"Joseph Vining","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.1276348","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.1276348","url":null,"abstract":"China's entry into the world economy will affect not just how we act but how we think. It will affect especially what \"business,\" \"business law,\" and \"business corporation\" come to mean both in a transnational setting and in American law. The nature of American business law today still stands in the way of a wholly profit-maximizing approach to law or the world in general. But there is strong pressure, consistent with a general tendency in Western thought, to make business and corporate decision-making entirely manipulative and calculating and to eliminate the force of human value from it. This Youde Lecture traces the development of the business entity and the conception of its purpose in American business law - including late-twentieth century discussion in the American Law Institute - and describes contemporary efforts to change the legal statement of corporate purpose. It observes that the twentieth century struggle between \"socialism\" and \"capitalism\" did not end in utter elimination of the influence of the ideals that might be expressed in \"socialism,\" including its Chinese form. The development of China's economic institutions and China's participation in world trade may have the surprising effect of blunting contemporary pressure to change American business law, and ultimately making the way we think fifty years hence more humane than it might otherwise have been.","PeriodicalId":106641,"journal":{"name":"Corporate Law: Corporate & Takeover Law","volume":"368 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2008-09-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"125696585","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Mapping Judicial Review: Sinclair Oil v. Levien 测绘司法审查:辛克莱石油诉利维恩案
Pub Date : 2008-07-16 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.1161299
R. Thompson
The defining issue of corporate law is the intensity of judicial review of director actions. Over the last four decades, Delaware has developed an elaborate array of judicial standards and defined (and then rearranged) the process by which such litigation plays out. This piece explores that development using the framework set out in Sinclair Oil v. Levien, a classic of Delaware corporate jurisprudence. The first part tells the story of this case, the parties and their lawyers, in a way that seeks to provide a context for the discussion of fiduciary duty within a parent/subsidiary corporate group. Subsequent parts develop, with a graphic aid, the judicial space defined by the Sinclair court and filled in by judges over the ensuing decades and then analyzes the fiduciary duty of controlling shareholders Sinclair provides room for "selfish" ownership for a majority shareholder, so long as the minority shareholders receive a proportional benefit, a standard that at the time seemed to expand the discretion for majority shareholders. Viewed from a point decades later, this part of Sinclair has not proved to be a template for broader applications and other doctrines have developed to constrain the actions of majority shareholders. The intensity of judicial review of corporate decisions is the central issue of corporate law. Sinclair Oil Corp. v. Levien, a foundational decision in Delaware corporate jurisprudence from 1971, defines the space within which judicial review occurs with a format that still guides courts today. Along one boundary is deference by judges to decisions of business managers that is reflected in the business judgment rule. Along the other boundary is an intrusive judicial involvement by which the court asks the corporation or other defendant to prove the intrinsic fairness of the transaction. Since Sinclair the Delaware courts have filled in the space defined within those boundaries with a host of other decision points and varying degrees of judicial review, but it was Sinclair that provided the landscape. The case remains in wide use today in classrooms (and courtrooms) because it presents an attractive pedagogical package. Three challenged actions were before the court; for two of those actions the court adopted deference and for the other, intrinsic fairness. Hence, the outcome provides a structure that directs students to address the differences between the two standards. At the same time, the case raises the difficult policy question of how far a parent corporation can go in directing the actions of the subsidiary for the parent's own purposes. The Sinclair court takes a rather narrow definition of self-dealing, requiring that the parent get something at the expense of the subsidiary before a court will interfere with the directors' decision. This story unfolds in three parts. Section I introduces the parties and frames the issues presented in the case. Section II develops, with a graphic aid, the judicial space defined by the
公司法的决定性问题是对董事行为的司法审查力度。在过去的四十年里,特拉华州制定了一系列详尽的司法标准,并定义(然后重新安排)了此类诉讼的程序。本文利用辛克莱石油诉利维恩案(Delaware corporate jurisprudence的经典案例)的框架探讨了这一发展。第一部分讲述了这个案例的故事,当事人和他们的律师,试图为母公司/子公司企业集团内部的信义义务的讨论提供一个背景。随后的部分以图表的形式展开了辛克莱法院定义的司法空间,并在随后的几十年里由法官填补,然后分析了控股股东的信托义务。辛克莱为大股东的“自私”所有权提供了空间,只要小股东获得一定比例的利益,这一标准在当时似乎扩大了大股东的自由裁量权。从几十年后的一个角度来看,辛克莱的这一部分并没有被证明是一个更广泛应用的模板,其他理论已经发展到限制大股东的行为。公司决定的司法审查力度是公司法的核心问题。辛克莱石油公司诉利维恩案(Sinclair Oil Corp. v. Levien)是特拉华州1971年公司法理的一项基础性裁决,它定义了司法审查的空间,其格式至今仍指导着法院。沿一个边界是法官对业务经理决策的服从,这反映在业务判断规则中。另一个边界是一种侵入性司法介入,法院要求公司或其他被告证明交易的内在公平性。自辛克莱以来,特拉华州的法院填补了在这些边界内定义的空间,用了许多其他的决定点和不同程度的司法审查,但辛克莱提供了景观。这个案例至今仍在课堂上(和法庭上)广泛使用,因为它提供了一个有吸引力的教学方案。法院审理了三项有争议的诉讼;对于其中两个行为,法院采用了尊重,而对于另一个行为,法院采用了内在的公平。因此,结果提供了一个结构,指导学生解决两个标准之间的差异。与此同时,该案件提出了一个棘手的政策问题,即母公司在指导子公司为自己的目的采取行动方面能走多远。辛克莱法院对自利交易的定义相当狭隘,要求母公司以牺牲子公司的利益为代价获得某些东西,然后法院才会干预董事的决定。这个故事分三部分展开。第一部分介绍了当事人,并阐述了案件中提出的问题。第二部分以图形的形式发展了辛克莱法庭所定义的司法空间,并在随后的几十年里由法官填充。第三部分分析了控股股东的信义义务(相对于非控股董事和经理的信义义务)。辛克莱为大股东提供了“自私”所有权的空间,只要小股东获得相应的利益,这一标准在当时似乎扩大了大股东的自由裁量权。从几十年后的一个角度来看,辛克莱的这一部分并没有被证明是一个更广泛应用的模板,其他理论已经发展到限制大股东的行为。
{"title":"Mapping Judicial Review: Sinclair Oil v. Levien","authors":"R. Thompson","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.1161299","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.1161299","url":null,"abstract":"The defining issue of corporate law is the intensity of judicial review of director actions. Over the last four decades, Delaware has developed an elaborate array of judicial standards and defined (and then rearranged) the process by which such litigation plays out. This piece explores that development using the framework set out in Sinclair Oil v. Levien, a classic of Delaware corporate jurisprudence. The first part tells the story of this case, the parties and their lawyers, in a way that seeks to provide a context for the discussion of fiduciary duty within a parent/subsidiary corporate group. Subsequent parts develop, with a graphic aid, the judicial space defined by the Sinclair court and filled in by judges over the ensuing decades and then analyzes the fiduciary duty of controlling shareholders Sinclair provides room for \"selfish\" ownership for a majority shareholder, so long as the minority shareholders receive a proportional benefit, a standard that at the time seemed to expand the discretion for majority shareholders. Viewed from a point decades later, this part of Sinclair has not proved to be a template for broader applications and other doctrines have developed to constrain the actions of majority shareholders. The intensity of judicial review of corporate decisions is the central issue of corporate law. Sinclair Oil Corp. v. Levien, a foundational decision in Delaware corporate jurisprudence from 1971, defines the space within which judicial review occurs with a format that still guides courts today. Along one boundary is deference by judges to decisions of business managers that is reflected in the business judgment rule. Along the other boundary is an intrusive judicial involvement by which the court asks the corporation or other defendant to prove the intrinsic fairness of the transaction. Since Sinclair the Delaware courts have filled in the space defined within those boundaries with a host of other decision points and varying degrees of judicial review, but it was Sinclair that provided the landscape. The case remains in wide use today in classrooms (and courtrooms) because it presents an attractive pedagogical package. Three challenged actions were before the court; for two of those actions the court adopted deference and for the other, intrinsic fairness. Hence, the outcome provides a structure that directs students to address the differences between the two standards. At the same time, the case raises the difficult policy question of how far a parent corporation can go in directing the actions of the subsidiary for the parent's own purposes. The Sinclair court takes a rather narrow definition of self-dealing, requiring that the parent get something at the expense of the subsidiary before a court will interfere with the directors' decision. This story unfolds in three parts. Section I introduces the parties and frames the issues presented in the case. Section II develops, with a graphic aid, the judicial space defined by the ","PeriodicalId":106641,"journal":{"name":"Corporate Law: Corporate & Takeover Law","volume":"30 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2008-07-16","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"123340297","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Corporate Entities and WTO Law 公司实体与WTO法律
Pub Date : 2008-06-26 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.1151810
M. Healy
WTO panels have not been called upon to resolve overly complex corporate law issues to date. However, the range of legal and economic relationships among corporate entities, and the varied situations in which such relationships may be relevant to the rights and obligations of Members under the WTO Agreements, suggest that such issues may one day arise squarely for consideration in WTO dispute settlement. This paper consists of a survey of selected WTO Agreements and jurisprudence examining the extent to which WTO law (i) gives effect to the existence of a corporate entity as a legal person that is separate from its owners; and (ii) takes into account the economic links that may exist between corporate entities which are "related" through various forms of ownership or control. We begin with a consideration of disputes involving Members' obligations under the GATT 1994, before turning to disputes involving obligations under the Agreement on Implementation of Article VI of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade 1994 and the Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures. Although these Agreements are generally not concerned with the legal identity of the "producer" of goods or the form of business organization or corporate structure of private parties involved in trade in goods, panels and the Appellate Body appear to have interpreted these Agreements in a manner that is sensitive to the economic realities of links of ownership and control among corporate entities, particularly where this is seen as necessary to prevent circumvention of Members' obligations. The final part of the paper considers the nature of Members' rights and obligations under the GATS as they apply to service suppliers that are corporate entities. In particular, we examine the rules for allocating service suppliers that are corporate entities to particular Members for purposes of the GATS.
迄今为止,还没有人请世贸组织专家组来解决过于复杂的公司法问题。然而,公司实体之间的法律和经济关系的范围,以及这种关系可能与WTO协定项下成员的权利和义务相关的各种情况,表明这些问题可能有一天会在WTO争端解决中直接考虑。本文包括对选定的WTO协议和判例的调查,以检验WTO法律在多大程度上(i)使公司实体作为与其所有者分离的法人存在生效;(ii)考虑到通过各种形式的所有权或控制权“相关”的公司实体之间可能存在的经济联系。我们首先审议涉及1994年关贸总协定下成员义务的争端,然后再审议涉及《关于实施1994年关税与贸易总协定第6条的协定》和《补贴与反补贴措施协定》项下义务的争端。虽然这些协定一般不涉及货物“生产者”的法律身份或涉及货物贸易的私人方的商业组织形式或公司结构,但专家组和上诉机构似乎对这些协定的解释方式对公司实体之间所有权和控制权联系的经济现实很敏感,特别是在这被视为防止规避成员义务所必需的情况下。文件的最后一部分考虑了成员在GATS下的权利和义务的性质,因为它们适用于作为公司实体的服务提供者。特别是,我们审查为服务贸易总协定的目的将作为公司实体的服务提供者分配给特定成员的规则。
{"title":"Corporate Entities and WTO Law","authors":"M. Healy","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.1151810","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1151810","url":null,"abstract":"WTO panels have not been called upon to resolve overly complex corporate law issues to date. However, the range of legal and economic relationships among corporate entities, and the varied situations in which such relationships may be relevant to the rights and obligations of Members under the WTO Agreements, suggest that such issues may one day arise squarely for consideration in WTO dispute settlement. This paper consists of a survey of selected WTO Agreements and jurisprudence examining the extent to which WTO law (i) gives effect to the existence of a corporate entity as a legal person that is separate from its owners; and (ii) takes into account the economic links that may exist between corporate entities which are \"related\" through various forms of ownership or control. We begin with a consideration of disputes involving Members' obligations under the GATT 1994, before turning to disputes involving obligations under the Agreement on Implementation of Article VI of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade 1994 and the Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures. Although these Agreements are generally not concerned with the legal identity of the \"producer\" of goods or the form of business organization or corporate structure of private parties involved in trade in goods, panels and the Appellate Body appear to have interpreted these Agreements in a manner that is sensitive to the economic realities of links of ownership and control among corporate entities, particularly where this is seen as necessary to prevent circumvention of Members' obligations. The final part of the paper considers the nature of Members' rights and obligations under the GATS as they apply to service suppliers that are corporate entities. In particular, we examine the rules for allocating service suppliers that are corporate entities to particular Members for purposes of the GATS.","PeriodicalId":106641,"journal":{"name":"Corporate Law: Corporate & Takeover Law","volume":"1 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2008-06-26","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"131007270","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
期刊
Corporate Law: Corporate & Takeover Law
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1