首页 > 最新文献

ERN: Other Econometrics: Applied Econometric Modeling in Forecasting (Topic)最新文献

英文 中文
Estimating Demand Uncertainty Using Dispersion of Team Forecasts or Distributions of Forecast Errors 利用团队预测的离散度或预测误差的分布估计需求不确定性
Christoph Diermann, Arnd Huchzermeier
In this paper, we compare two fundamentally different judgmental demand forecasting approaches used to estimate demand and their corresponding demand distributions. In the first approach, parameters are obtained from a linear regression and maximum likelihood estimation (MLE) based on team forecasts and dispersion within the judgmental forecasts. The second approach ignores dispersion and instead estimates the demand distribution based on the mean demand forecast and the historic relative forecast errors as measured by A/F ratios — that is, the ratio of actual to forecast outcomes. We show that accounting for forecast dispersion (as a timely indicator of anticipated demand risk) explains demand uncertainty sublinearly whereas the mean demand forecast most often explains demand uncertainty as being more than linear. We use actual company data from an online retailer to show that the A/F ratio approach dominates the MLE approach in terms of de-biasing the mean demand forecast, predicting total season demand, predicting the percentage of demand actually served at a target service level, and maximizing realized gross profit. However, the MLE approach more closely follows the assumed standard normally distributed demand and hence yields better-fitting demand distributions. Product segmentation can further improve the forecast accuracy of both approaches. In the application case study described here, we fit the data and analyze accuracy of forecasts. The results indicate that, in order to maximize accuracy, demand forecasts should always employ product segmentation and should favor the A/F ratio approach for order quantities “close” to the mean; otherwise, the MLE approach is preferred.
在本文中,我们比较了两种根本不同的判断需求预测方法,用于估计需求及其相应的需求分布。在第一种方法中,根据团队预测和判断预测内的离散度,通过线性回归和最大似然估计(MLE)获得参数。第二种方法忽略了分散,而是根据平均需求预测和历史相对预测误差(由A/F比率衡量)来估计需求分布,即实际结果与预测结果的比率。我们表明,考虑预测离散度(作为预期需求风险的及时指标)以次线性方式解释需求不确定性,而平均需求预测最常将需求不确定性解释为超过线性。我们使用来自在线零售商的实际公司数据来表明,在消除平均需求预测的偏倚、预测总季节需求、预测在目标服务水平上实际服务的需求百分比以及最大化实现毛利润方面,A/F比率方法优于MLE方法。然而,MLE方法更接近于假设的标准正态分布需求,因此产生更好的拟合需求分布。产品分割可以进一步提高两种方法的预测精度。在本文描述的应用案例研究中,我们拟合了数据并分析了预测的准确性。结果表明,为了最大限度地提高准确性,需求预测应始终采用产品细分,并应支持订单数量“接近”平均值的A/F比率方法;否则,首选MLE方法。
{"title":"Estimating Demand Uncertainty Using Dispersion of Team Forecasts or Distributions of Forecast Errors","authors":"Christoph Diermann, Arnd Huchzermeier","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.2782402","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2782402","url":null,"abstract":"In this paper, we compare two fundamentally different judgmental demand forecasting approaches used to estimate demand and their corresponding demand distributions. In the first approach, parameters are obtained from a linear regression and maximum likelihood estimation (MLE) based on team forecasts and dispersion within the judgmental forecasts. The second approach ignores dispersion and instead estimates the demand distribution based on the mean demand forecast and the historic relative forecast errors as measured by A/F ratios — that is, the ratio of actual to forecast outcomes. We show that accounting for forecast dispersion (as a timely indicator of anticipated demand risk) explains demand uncertainty sublinearly whereas the mean demand forecast most often explains demand uncertainty as being more than linear. We use actual company data from an online retailer to show that the A/F ratio approach dominates the MLE approach in terms of de-biasing the mean demand forecast, predicting total season demand, predicting the percentage of demand actually served at a target service level, and maximizing realized gross profit. However, the MLE approach more closely follows the assumed standard normally distributed demand and hence yields better-fitting demand distributions. Product segmentation can further improve the forecast accuracy of both approaches. In the application case study described here, we fit the data and analyze accuracy of forecasts. The results indicate that, in order to maximize accuracy, demand forecasts should always employ product segmentation and should favor the A/F ratio approach for order quantities “close” to the mean; otherwise, the MLE approach is preferred.","PeriodicalId":308524,"journal":{"name":"ERN: Other Econometrics: Applied Econometric Modeling in Forecasting (Topic)","volume":"35 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2016-07-26","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"127461709","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2
Improved Forecasting of Realized Variance Measures 已实现方差测度的改进预测
Jeremias Bekierman, H. Manner
We consider the problem of forecasting realized variance measures. These measures are highly persistent, but also noisy estimates of the underlying integrated variance. Recently, Bollerslev, Patton and Quaedvlieg (2016, Journal of Econometrics, 192, 1-18) exploited this fact to extend the commonly used Heterogeneous Autoregressive (HAR) by letting the model parameters vary over time depending on estimated measurement errors. We propose an alternative specification that allows the autoregressive parameter of the HAR model for volatilities to be driven by a latent Gaussian autoregressive process that may depend on the estimated measurement error. The model is estimated using the Kalman filter. Our analysis considers realized volatilities of 40 stocks from the S&P 500 for three different observation frequencies. Our preferred model provides a better model fit and generates superior forecasts. It consistently outperforms the competing models in terms of different loss functions and for various subsamples of the forecasting period.
我们考虑预测已实现方差的问题。这些措施是高度持久的,但也是对潜在综合方差的嘈杂估计。最近,Bollerslev, Patton和Quaedvlieg (2016, Journal of Econometrics, 192, 1-18)利用这一事实,通过让模型参数随估计测量误差随时间变化来扩展常用的异质性自回归(HAR)。我们提出了另一种规范,允许波动性的HAR模型的自回归参数由潜在的高斯自回归过程驱动,该过程可能取决于估计的测量误差。利用卡尔曼滤波对模型进行估计。我们的分析考虑了标准普尔500指数中40只股票在三种不同观察频率下的已实现波动率。我们的首选模型提供了更好的模型拟合,并产生了更好的预测。在不同的损失函数和预测周期的各种子样本方面,它始终优于竞争模型。
{"title":"Improved Forecasting of Realized Variance Measures","authors":"Jeremias Bekierman, H. Manner","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.2812586","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2812586","url":null,"abstract":"We consider the problem of forecasting realized variance measures. These measures are highly persistent, but also noisy estimates of the underlying integrated variance. Recently, Bollerslev, Patton and Quaedvlieg (2016, Journal of Econometrics, 192, 1-18) exploited this fact to extend the commonly used Heterogeneous Autoregressive (HAR) by letting the model parameters vary over time depending on estimated measurement errors. We propose an alternative specification that allows the autoregressive parameter of the HAR model for volatilities to be driven by a latent Gaussian autoregressive process that may depend on the estimated measurement error. The model is estimated using the Kalman filter. Our analysis considers realized volatilities of 40 stocks from the S&P 500 for three different observation frequencies. Our preferred model provides a better model fit and generates superior forecasts. It consistently outperforms the competing models in terms of different loss functions and for various subsamples of the forecasting period.","PeriodicalId":308524,"journal":{"name":"ERN: Other Econometrics: Applied Econometric Modeling in Forecasting (Topic)","volume":"1 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2016-07-21","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"131157625","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Leading Indicator Properties of Corporate Bond Spreads, Excess Bond Premia and Lending Spreads in the Euro Area 欧元区公司债券息差、超额债券溢价和贷款息差的领先指标属性
E. Krylova
This paper analyses leading indicator properties of a broad set of credit spreads, compiled on the basis of information from both corporate bonds and bank loans for forecasting of real activity, unemployment, inflation and lending volumes in the euro area and in five major European economies. It also introduces a set of indicators for excess bond premia, adjusting corporate bond spreads for credit risk of the issuer and the term, coupon and liquidity premia. I find that the majority of macroeconomic indicators can be better predicted by the excess bond premia compared to non-adjusted indices; the rating-adjustment and time-varying parameter estimates seem to be particularly important. Although the predictive power of lending spreads is inferior to the predictive power of the excess bond premia, the forecasting performance of models which use the information from both lending and corporate bond spreads is always superior to models using only information from one source of external funding. JEL Classification: G12, C21, C22, E37, E44
本文根据公司债券和银行贷款的信息,对欧元区和欧洲五大经济体的实际经济活动、失业率、通货膨胀和贷款额进行了预测,分析了一系列广泛信贷息差的领先指标属性。它还引入了一套超额债券溢价指标,根据发行人的信用风险以及期限、息票和流动性溢价来调整公司债券利差。研究发现,与未经调整的指标相比,绝大多数宏观经济指标可以通过超额债券溢价更好地预测;评级调整和时变参数估计似乎特别重要。尽管贷款息差的预测能力不如超额债券溢价的预测能力,但同时使用贷款和公司债券息差信息的模型的预测性能总是优于仅使用一种外部资金来源信息的模型。JEL分类:G12, C21, C22, E37, E44
{"title":"Leading Indicator Properties of Corporate Bond Spreads, Excess Bond Premia and Lending Spreads in the Euro Area","authors":"E. Krylova","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.2797178","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2797178","url":null,"abstract":"This paper analyses leading indicator properties of a broad set of credit spreads, compiled on the basis of information from both corporate bonds and bank loans for forecasting of real activity, unemployment, inflation and lending volumes in the euro area and in five major European economies. It also introduces a set of indicators for excess bond premia, adjusting corporate bond spreads for credit risk of the issuer and the term, coupon and liquidity premia. I find that the majority of macroeconomic indicators can be better predicted by the excess bond premia compared to non-adjusted indices; the rating-adjustment and time-varying parameter estimates seem to be particularly important. Although the predictive power of lending spreads is inferior to the predictive power of the excess bond premia, the forecasting performance of models which use the information from both lending and corporate bond spreads is always superior to models using only information from one source of external funding. JEL Classification: G12, C21, C22, E37, E44","PeriodicalId":308524,"journal":{"name":"ERN: Other Econometrics: Applied Econometric Modeling in Forecasting (Topic)","volume":"1 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2016-06-17","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"130777177","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 3
Measurement Without Theory: On the Extraordinary Abuse of Economic Models in the EU Referendum Debate 没有理论的衡量:论欧盟公投辩论中经济模型的异常滥用
D. Blake
The Treasury has published two reports on the economic consequences of a decision by the UK to vote to leave the European Union in the Referendum on 23 June. Together, the reports predict that each household in the UK will be worse off (in terms of a lower gross domestic product) by £4,300 or more by 2030. This prediction is grossly exaggerated for two main reasons. First, the Treasury assumes that the government will not respond to what it calls the ‘extreme shock’ of leaving the EU – a shock that is assumed to last for two years, which is longer than that caused by the Global Financial Crisis – and so will stand by while the economy dives into a recession with GDP falling by up to 6% over the next two years (relative to where the economy would be if the UK remained in the EU) – equivalent to losing 50% of our trade with the EU, even though we will still be in the Single Market during this period. This is simply not credible – had the government responded in the same way during the GFC, the consequences for the economy would have been catastrophic.Second, it assumes that the UK, the fifth largest economy in the world, will be unable to negotiate more favorable trading arrangements than currently exist with either the EU or the rest of the world – which has three times the GDP of the EU and nine times its population and is growing much faster than the stagnant EU economy. As a result of this assumption, GDP is predicted to be lower by up to 7.5% p.a. by 2030. This prediction comes from combining the outcome from a short-term model (called a vector autoregressive (VAR) model) which is used for the first two years after leaving with a long-term model (called a gravity model) which is used to project GDP between 2018 and 2030. The reason that the models are switched in 2018 is because this is the maximum time allowed to negotiate an exit from the EU under Article 50 of the Treaty on European Union. The specific gravity model used by the Treasury is centred on the EU: this model predicts that the UK would actually be better off not only staying in the EU but actually joining the euro – although the Treasury does not acknowledge this. Had the Treasury used a different gravity model centred on the rest of the world – which it certainly should have considered – it might well have found that the UK would be better off leaving the EU. Most of the other economic models that have examined the economic consequences of Brexit – and which have been entirely ignored by the Treasury – find that it will make little difference to the UK’s economy whether the UK stays in or leaves the EU. This is consistent with both Greenland’s experience of leaving the EU in 1985 and Ireland’s experience of ending currency union with the UK in 1979 – neither of which is considered in the Treasury reports.
英国财政部(Treasury)发布了两份关于英国在6月23日公投中决定退出欧盟(eu)的经济后果的报告。两份报告共同预测,到2030年,英国每个家庭的境况(以较低的国内生产总值(gdp)计算)将减少4300英镑或更多。这一预测被严重夸大了,主要有两个原因。首先,财政部认为政府不会回应所谓的极端冲击离开欧盟——假设冲击持续两年,这比全球金融危机造成的,所以会袖手旁观而经济深入衰退与GDP下降了6%在接下来的两年里(相对于经济如果英国留在欧盟)——相当于失去50%的贸易与欧盟,尽管在此期间我们仍将留在单一市场。这根本不可信——如果政府在全球金融危机期间以同样的方式做出回应,对经济的影响将是灾难性的。其次,它假设英国作为世界第五大经济体,将无法与欧盟或世界其他地区谈判出比目前更有利的贸易安排——英国的GDP是欧盟的三倍,人口是欧盟的九倍,增长速度远快于停滞的欧盟经济。根据这一假设,到2030年,GDP预计将以每年7.5%的速度下降。这一预测是将短期模型(称为向量自回归(VAR)模型)的结果与用于预测2018年至2030年之间GDP的长期模型(称为重力模型)相结合得出的。短期模型(称为向量自回归(VAR)模型)用于离开后的头两年。在2018年切换模式的原因是,根据《欧盟条约》第50条,这是谈判退出欧盟的最长时间。财政部使用的比重模型以欧盟为中心:该模型预测,英国不仅留在欧盟,而且实际上加入欧元区会更好——尽管财政部不承认这一点。如果财政部使用一种以世界其他地区为中心的不同的引力模型——它当然应该考虑到这一点——它很可能会发现,英国离开欧盟会更好。大多数考察过英国脱欧经济后果的其他经济模型——这些模型被财政部完全忽视了——发现,英国留在欧盟还是离开欧盟,对英国经济几乎没有什么影响。这与1985年格陵兰退出欧盟的经历,以及1979年爱尔兰结束与英国的货币联盟的经历都是一致的——这两种情况都没有出现在财政部的报告中。
{"title":"Measurement Without Theory: On the Extraordinary Abuse of Economic Models in the EU Referendum Debate","authors":"D. Blake","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.2819954","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.2819954","url":null,"abstract":"The Treasury has published two reports on the economic consequences of a decision by the UK to vote to leave the European Union in the Referendum on 23 June. Together, the reports predict that each household in the UK will be worse off (in terms of a lower gross domestic product) by £4,300 or more by 2030. This prediction is grossly exaggerated for two main reasons. First, the Treasury assumes that the government will not respond to what it calls the ‘extreme shock’ of leaving the EU – a shock that is assumed to last for two years, which is longer than that caused by the Global Financial Crisis – and so will stand by while the economy dives into a recession with GDP falling by up to 6% over the next two years (relative to where the economy would be if the UK remained in the EU) – equivalent to losing 50% of our trade with the EU, even though we will still be in the Single Market during this period. This is simply not credible – had the government responded in the same way during the GFC, the consequences for the economy would have been catastrophic.Second, it assumes that the UK, the fifth largest economy in the world, will be unable to negotiate more favorable trading arrangements than currently exist with either the EU or the rest of the world – which has three times the GDP of the EU and nine times its population and is growing much faster than the stagnant EU economy. As a result of this assumption, GDP is predicted to be lower by up to 7.5% p.a. by 2030. This prediction comes from combining the outcome from a short-term model (called a vector autoregressive (VAR) model) which is used for the first two years after leaving with a long-term model (called a gravity model) which is used to project GDP between 2018 and 2030. The reason that the models are switched in 2018 is because this is the maximum time allowed to negotiate an exit from the EU under Article 50 of the Treaty on European Union. The specific gravity model used by the Treasury is centred on the EU: this model predicts that the UK would actually be better off not only staying in the EU but actually joining the euro – although the Treasury does not acknowledge this. Had the Treasury used a different gravity model centred on the rest of the world – which it certainly should have considered – it might well have found that the UK would be better off leaving the EU. Most of the other economic models that have examined the economic consequences of Brexit – and which have been entirely ignored by the Treasury – find that it will make little difference to the UK’s economy whether the UK stays in or leaves the EU. This is consistent with both Greenland’s experience of leaving the EU in 1985 and Ireland’s experience of ending currency union with the UK in 1979 – neither of which is considered in the Treasury reports.","PeriodicalId":308524,"journal":{"name":"ERN: Other Econometrics: Applied Econometric Modeling in Forecasting (Topic)","volume":"89 3","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2016-06-08","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"134005690","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 4
The Future of Illusions or the Illusions of the Future: FOMC Economic Projections 2008-2015 幻想的未来还是未来的幻想:联邦公开市场委员会2008-2015年经济预测
Sebastian Herrador, Jaime R. Marquez
Monetary policy is forward looking and, in its pursuit of transparency, it communicates its economic outlook to the public at large. As a result, there is great interest in the FOMC's projections and its determinants. Indeed, do these projections converge to the actual values and at what pace? To what extent predictions for a given year are determined jointly with predictions for other years? To what extent FOMC participants differ in their outlook? Are their differences related to the state of the economy? To the Chair of the FOMC? What information is being used for revising these projections and is it possible to anticipate what the FOMC will anticipate? Is it possible to extract a narrative about the functioning of the economy? And is that narrative consistent with existing theories? To address these questions, we assemble FOMC forecasts from 2008 to 2015, examine their statistical properties, and assess the extent to which these forecasts can be predicted using publicly available data at the time the forecasts are made.
货币政策是前瞻性的,在追求透明度的过程中,它向公众传达了其经济前景。因此,人们对FOMC的预测及其决定因素非常感兴趣。事实上,这些预测是否会收敛于实际值,以及收敛的速度如何?某一年的预测在多大程度上是与其他年份的预测共同决定的?联邦公开市场委员会(FOMC)成员对前景的看法有多大差异?他们的差异与经济状况有关吗?给联邦公开市场委员会主席?哪些信息被用于修改这些预测,是否有可能预测联邦公开市场委员会的预期?有可能提取出一种关于经济运行的叙述吗?这种叙述与现有的理论一致吗?为了解决这些问题,我们收集了联邦公开市场委员会从2008年到2015年的预测,检查了它们的统计属性,并评估了这些预测在多大程度上可以使用预测时的公开数据进行预测。
{"title":"The Future of Illusions or the Illusions of the Future: FOMC Economic Projections 2008-2015","authors":"Sebastian Herrador, Jaime R. Marquez","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.2769817","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2769817","url":null,"abstract":"Monetary policy is forward looking and, in its pursuit of transparency, it communicates its economic outlook to the public at large. As a result, there is great interest in the FOMC's projections and its determinants. Indeed, do these projections converge to the actual values and at what pace? To what extent predictions for a given year are determined jointly with predictions for other years? To what extent FOMC participants differ in their outlook? Are their differences related to the state of the economy? To the Chair of the FOMC? What information is being used for revising these projections and is it possible to anticipate what the FOMC will anticipate? Is it possible to extract a narrative about the functioning of the economy? And is that narrative consistent with existing theories? To address these questions, we assemble FOMC forecasts from 2008 to 2015, examine their statistical properties, and assess the extent to which these forecasts can be predicted using publicly available data at the time the forecasts are made.","PeriodicalId":308524,"journal":{"name":"ERN: Other Econometrics: Applied Econometric Modeling in Forecasting (Topic)","volume":"189 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2016-04-25","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"133137136","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Topographic Finance 地形金融
P. Cottrell
This paper will provide information on topographic finance and how it can be used in econometric and financial analysis. First we will cover what topographic finance means. Secondly, a discussion of what problems can be visualized will be but forth. Thirdly, a high level description of the concept of a surface will be advanced. Then a discussion on the theoretical framework will be articulated using chaos theory and emergence concepts. Fifthly, a mythological history of Poseidon will be explored and coupled with the development of the Poseidon software that is development by my company called Reykjavik. Finally, the future development in topographical finance will be proposed.
本文将提供有关地形金融的信息,以及如何将其用于计量经济和金融分析。首先,我们将介绍地形金融的含义。其次,关于哪些问题可以可视化的讨论将很快展开。第三,对曲面的概念进行高层次的描述。然后将运用混沌理论和涌现概念对理论框架进行讨论。第五,将探讨波塞冬的神话历史,并结合波塞冬软件的开发,该软件是由我的公司Reykjavik开发的。最后,对地形金融的未来发展进行了展望。
{"title":"Topographic Finance","authors":"P. Cottrell","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.2769250","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2769250","url":null,"abstract":"This paper will provide information on topographic finance and how it can be used in econometric and financial analysis. First we will cover what topographic finance means. Secondly, a discussion of what problems can be visualized will be but forth. Thirdly, a high level description of the concept of a surface will be advanced. Then a discussion on the theoretical framework will be articulated using chaos theory and emergence concepts. Fifthly, a mythological history of Poseidon will be explored and coupled with the development of the Poseidon software that is development by my company called Reykjavik. Finally, the future development in topographical finance will be proposed.","PeriodicalId":308524,"journal":{"name":"ERN: Other Econometrics: Applied Econometric Modeling in Forecasting (Topic)","volume":"105 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2016-04-22","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"128599673","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Finding Common Characteristics Among NBA Playoff and Championship Teams: A Machine Learning Approach 寻找NBA季后赛和总冠军球队的共同特征:一种机器学习方法
I. S. Kohli
In this paper, we employ machine learning techniques to analyze fifteen seasons of NBA regular season data from every team to determine the common characteristics among NBA playoff teams. Each team was characterized by 44 predictor variables and one binary response variable taking on a value of "TRUE" if a team had made the playoffs, and value of "FALSE" if a team had missed the playoffs. After fitting an initial classification tree to this problem, this tree was then pruned which decrease the test error rate. Further to this, a random forest of classification trees was grown which provided a very accurate model from which a variable importance plot was generated to determine which predictor variables had the greatest influence on the response variable. The result of this work was the conclusion that the most important factors in characterizing a team’s playoff eligibility are the opponent field goal percentage and the opponent points per game. This seems to suggest that defensive factors as opposed to offensive factors are the most important characteristics shared among NBA playoff teams.
在本文中,我们采用机器学习技术分析了来自每支球队的15个赛季的NBA常规赛数据,以确定NBA季后赛球队的共同特征。每支球队都有44个预测变量和一个二元响应变量,如果球队进入季后赛,则值为“TRUE”,如果球队错过季后赛,则值为“FALSE”。对该问题拟合初始分类树后,对该树进行剪枝,降低了测试错误率。除此之外,我们还建立了一个由分类树组成的随机森林,它提供了一个非常精确的模型,从中生成了一个变量重要性图,以确定哪些预测变量对响应变量的影响最大。这项工作的结果是得出这样的结论:衡量一支球队是否有资格进入季后赛的最重要因素是对手的投篮命中率和对手的场均得分。这似乎表明,防守因素而不是进攻因素是NBA季后赛球队最重要的共同特征。
{"title":"Finding Common Characteristics Among NBA Playoff and Championship Teams: A Machine Learning Approach","authors":"I. S. Kohli","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.2764396","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2764396","url":null,"abstract":"In this paper, we employ machine learning techniques to analyze fifteen seasons of NBA regular season data from every team to determine the common characteristics among NBA playoff teams. Each team was characterized by 44 predictor variables and one binary response variable taking on a value of \"TRUE\" if a team had made the playoffs, and value of \"FALSE\" if a team had missed the playoffs. After fitting an initial classification tree to this problem, this tree was then pruned which decrease the test error rate. Further to this, a random forest of classification trees was grown which provided a very accurate model from which a variable importance plot was generated to determine which predictor variables had the greatest influence on the response variable. The result of this work was the conclusion that the most important factors in characterizing a team’s playoff eligibility are the opponent field goal percentage and the opponent points per game. This seems to suggest that defensive factors as opposed to offensive factors are the most important characteristics shared among NBA playoff teams.","PeriodicalId":308524,"journal":{"name":"ERN: Other Econometrics: Applied Econometric Modeling in Forecasting (Topic)","volume":"17 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2016-04-08","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"127009108","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
An Impact Measure for News: Its Use in (Daily) Trading Strategies 新闻的影响度量:它在(每日)交易策略中的使用
Xiang Yu, G. Mitra, Cristiano Arbex-Valle, Tilman Sayer
We investigate how “news sentiment” in general and the “impact of news” in particular can be utilized in designing equity trading strategies. News is an event that moves the market in a small way or a big way. We have introduced a derived measure of news impact score which takes into consideration news flow and decay of sentiment. Since asset behavior is characterized by return, volatility and liquidity we first consider a predictive analytic model in which market data and impact scores are the inputs and also the independent variables of the model. We finally describe the trading strategies which take into consideration the three important characteristics of an asset, namely, return, volatility and liquidity. The minute-bar market data as well as intraday news sentiment metadata have been provided by Thomson Reuters.
我们调查如何“新闻情绪”一般和“新闻的影响”,特别是可以在设计股票交易策略。新闻是影响市场或大或小的事件。我们引入了一种衍生的新闻影响评分方法,该方法考虑了新闻流量和情绪衰减。由于资产行为的特征是回报、波动性和流动性,我们首先考虑一个预测分析模型,其中市场数据和影响分数是模型的输入和自变量。最后,我们描述了考虑到资产的三个重要特征的交易策略,即收益、波动性和流动性。分栏市场数据以及盘中新闻情绪元数据由汤森路透提供。
{"title":"An Impact Measure for News: Its Use in (Daily) Trading Strategies","authors":"Xiang Yu, G. Mitra, Cristiano Arbex-Valle, Tilman Sayer","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3706827","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3706827","url":null,"abstract":"We investigate how “news sentiment” in general and the “impact of news” in particular can be utilized in designing equity trading strategies. News is an event that moves the market in a small way or a big way. We have introduced a derived measure of news impact score which takes into consideration news flow and decay of sentiment. Since asset behavior is characterized by return, volatility and liquidity we first consider a predictive analytic model in which market data and impact scores are the inputs and also the independent variables of the model. We finally describe the trading strategies which take into consideration the three important characteristics of an asset, namely, return, volatility and liquidity. The minute-bar market data as well as intraday news sentiment metadata have been provided by Thomson Reuters.","PeriodicalId":308524,"journal":{"name":"ERN: Other Econometrics: Applied Econometric Modeling in Forecasting (Topic)","volume":"16 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2016-04-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"115358272","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Analysts’ Long-Horizon Earnings Forecast Properties and Long-Horizon Macroeconomic Forecast Optimism 分析师的长期盈利预测属性和长期宏观经济预测乐观
Mikhail Pevzner, S. Radhakrishnan, Chandra Seethamraju
We examine whether the properties of earnings forecasts – bias and dispersion are different across periods when macroeconomic forecasts are optimistic than non-optimistic, and whether this difference in analyst forecast optimism is stronger during recessionary periods. We find that the long-horizon earnings forecasts are more optimistically biased in periods when the macroeconomic forecasts are optimistically biased as well, and the bias is more pronounced during periods of recession. We also find that the long-horizon earnings forecast dispersion is lower in periods when the long-horizon macroeconomic forecasts are optimistic than in other periods. These results suggest that firms that meet or beat earnings forecasts when there is no recession and macroeconomic forecast is optimistic are likely to have opportunistically biased their long-term forecasts and walked them down, i.e. opportunistic; and that firms that meet or beat earnings forecasts when there is recession and macroeconomic forecast is optimistic are likely to be the ones that are positioned to perform well when the economy recovers. Consistent with this we find that premium for meeting or beating the analysts’ earnings forecasts is highest in periods when there is recession and macroeconomic forecasts are optimistic; and there is no premium when there is no recession and macroeconomic forecast is optimistic. Collectively, the results show the interaction between the macroeconomic outlook and firm-level forecast properties.
我们研究了当宏观经济预测是乐观的,而不是不乐观的时候,收益预测的属性偏差和分散性是否在不同的时期有所不同,以及分析师预测乐观的这种差异是否在经济衰退时期更强。我们发现,当宏观经济预测出现乐观偏差时,长期收益预测也会出现乐观偏差,而在经济衰退期间,这种偏差更为明显。我们还发现,在长期宏观经济预测乐观的时期,长期收益预测的分散性比其他时期要低。这些结果表明,在没有经济衰退和宏观经济预测乐观的情况下,达到或超过盈利预测的公司可能会对其长期预测有机会主义偏见,并将其下调,即机会主义;在经济衰退和宏观经济预测乐观的情况下,那些达到或超过盈利预期的公司,很可能在经济复苏时表现良好。与此一致的是,我们发现,在经济衰退和宏观经济预测乐观的时期,达到或超过分析师盈利预测的溢价最高;而且,在没有衰退、宏观经济预测乐观的情况下,没有溢价。总体而言,结果显示了宏观经济前景与企业层面预测属性之间的相互作用。
{"title":"Analysts’ Long-Horizon Earnings Forecast Properties and Long-Horizon Macroeconomic Forecast Optimism","authors":"Mikhail Pevzner, S. Radhakrishnan, Chandra Seethamraju","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.2744069","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2744069","url":null,"abstract":"We examine whether the properties of earnings forecasts – bias and dispersion are different across periods when macroeconomic forecasts are optimistic than non-optimistic, and whether this difference in analyst forecast optimism is stronger during recessionary periods. We find that the long-horizon earnings forecasts are more optimistically biased in periods when the macroeconomic forecasts are optimistically biased as well, and the bias is more pronounced during periods of recession. We also find that the long-horizon earnings forecast dispersion is lower in periods when the long-horizon macroeconomic forecasts are optimistic than in other periods. These results suggest that firms that meet or beat earnings forecasts when there is no recession and macroeconomic forecast is optimistic are likely to have opportunistically biased their long-term forecasts and walked them down, i.e. opportunistic; and that firms that meet or beat earnings forecasts when there is recession and macroeconomic forecast is optimistic are likely to be the ones that are positioned to perform well when the economy recovers. Consistent with this we find that premium for meeting or beating the analysts’ earnings forecasts is highest in periods when there is recession and macroeconomic forecasts are optimistic; and there is no premium when there is no recession and macroeconomic forecast is optimistic. Collectively, the results show the interaction between the macroeconomic outlook and firm-level forecast properties.","PeriodicalId":308524,"journal":{"name":"ERN: Other Econometrics: Applied Econometric Modeling in Forecasting (Topic)","volume":"118 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2016-03-07","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"115768740","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
The Monetary Policy Risk Premium and Expected Bond Returns 货币政策风险溢价与债券预期收益
Steven Sabol
This brief note builds on Sabol (2015) by describing ways to account for forecasting errors made about the expected path of short-term interest rates in a model of expected bond returns. I consider the Cieslak and Povala (2014) model of monetary policy expectations frictions as one such measure of unexpected returns. I conduct a real time out-of-sample forecasting exercise and provide figures to easily show the validity of these models. Adding the predictable changes in Fed Policy, or the monetary policy risk premium, to measures of expected returns leads to improved forecasts. Much of this gain accrues to forecasts of shorter duration bonds.
本文以Sabol(2015)为基础,描述了在预期债券回报模型中对短期利率预期路径的预测错误的解释方法。我认为Cieslak和Povala(2014)的货币政策预期摩擦模型是衡量意外回报的一种方法。我进行了一个实时的样本外预测练习,并提供了很容易显示这些模型有效性的数据。将美联储政策的可预测变化,或货币政策风险溢价,加入预期回报的衡量标准,可以改善预测。大部分收益来自于对期限较短债券的预测。
{"title":"The Monetary Policy Risk Premium and Expected Bond Returns","authors":"Steven Sabol","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.2708336","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2708336","url":null,"abstract":"This brief note builds on Sabol (2015) by describing ways to account for forecasting errors made about the expected path of short-term interest rates in a model of expected bond returns. I consider the Cieslak and Povala (2014) model of monetary policy expectations frictions as one such measure of unexpected returns. I conduct a real time out-of-sample forecasting exercise and provide figures to easily show the validity of these models. Adding the predictable changes in Fed Policy, or the monetary policy risk premium, to measures of expected returns leads to improved forecasts. Much of this gain accrues to forecasts of shorter duration bonds.","PeriodicalId":308524,"journal":{"name":"ERN: Other Econometrics: Applied Econometric Modeling in Forecasting (Topic)","volume":"1 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2015-12-26","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"130394699","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
期刊
ERN: Other Econometrics: Applied Econometric Modeling in Forecasting (Topic)
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1