首页 > 最新文献

LSN: Antitrust (Topic)最新文献

英文 中文
Discovering the Miracle of Large Numbers of Antitrust Investigations in Russia: The Role of Competition Authority Incentives 发现俄罗斯大量反垄断调查的奇迹:竞争管理机构激励的作用
Pub Date : 2015-04-02 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.2588989
S. Avdasheva, D. Tsytsulina, S. Golovanova, E. Sidorova
Many antitrust investigations in Russia continue to present a challenge for the assessment of competition policy and international enforcement ratings. On the one hand, many infringement decisions may be interpreted as an indicator of high enforcement efforts in the context of rigid competition restrictions and the significant related harm to social welfare. On the other hand, many investigations proceed under poor legal and economic standards; therefore, the impact of decisions and remedies on competition is questionable. In fact, large number of investigations may indicate the ineffectiveness of antitrust enforcement. The article explains the possible effects of antitrust enforcement in Russia. Using a unique dataset of the appeals of infringement decisions from 2008-2012, we classify the investigated cases according to their potential impact on competition. A case-level analysis reveals that the majority of cases would never be investigated under an appropriate understanding of the goals of antitrust enforcement, restrictions on competition and basic cost-benefit assessments of agency activity. There are diverse explanations for the distorted structure of enforcement, including the incompleteness and imperfection of sector-specific regulations, rules concerning citizen complaints against the executive authorities and the incentives of competition authorities. Our analysis shows that competition agencies tend to pay more attention to the investigation of cases, which requires less input and, at the same time, results in infringement decisions with a lower probability of being annulled
俄罗斯的许多反垄断调查继续对竞争政策和国际执法评级的评估提出挑战。一方面,在严格的竞争限制和对社会福利的重大相关损害的背景下,许多侵权判决可能被解释为高度执法力度的指标。另一方面,许多调查是在糟糕的法律和经济标准下进行的;因此,决定和救济对竞争的影响是值得怀疑的。事实上,大量的调查可能表明反垄断执法的无效。这篇文章解释了俄罗斯反垄断执法可能产生的影响。利用2008年至2012年的侵权裁决上诉的独特数据集,我们根据其对竞争的潜在影响对调查案件进行了分类。个案层面的分析表明,如果对反垄断执法的目标、对竞争的限制和对机构活动的基本成本效益评估有适当的了解,大多数案件永远不会得到调查。对执法结构扭曲的解释多种多样,包括部门特定规定的不完整和不完善、有关公民对行政当局投诉的规则以及竞争当局的激励措施。我们的分析表明,竞争机构往往更关注案件的调查,这需要较少的投入,同时也导致侵权判决被撤销的可能性较低
{"title":"Discovering the Miracle of Large Numbers of Antitrust Investigations in Russia: The Role of Competition Authority Incentives","authors":"S. Avdasheva, D. Tsytsulina, S. Golovanova, E. Sidorova","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.2588989","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2588989","url":null,"abstract":"Many antitrust investigations in Russia continue to present a challenge for the assessment of competition policy and international enforcement ratings. On the one hand, many infringement decisions may be interpreted as an indicator of high enforcement efforts in the context of rigid competition restrictions and the significant related harm to social welfare. On the other hand, many investigations proceed under poor legal and economic standards; therefore, the impact of decisions and remedies on competition is questionable. In fact, large number of investigations may indicate the ineffectiveness of antitrust enforcement. The article explains the possible effects of antitrust enforcement in Russia. Using a unique dataset of the appeals of infringement decisions from 2008-2012, we classify the investigated cases according to their potential impact on competition. A case-level analysis reveals that the majority of cases would never be investigated under an appropriate understanding of the goals of antitrust enforcement, restrictions on competition and basic cost-benefit assessments of agency activity. There are diverse explanations for the distorted structure of enforcement, including the incompleteness and imperfection of sector-specific regulations, rules concerning citizen complaints against the executive authorities and the incentives of competition authorities. Our analysis shows that competition agencies tend to pay more attention to the investigation of cases, which requires less input and, at the same time, results in infringement decisions with a lower probability of being annulled","PeriodicalId":345107,"journal":{"name":"LSN: Antitrust (Topic)","volume":"3 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2015-04-02","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"126836479","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 7
Cliff Discounts by a Dominant Producer Threatened by Partial Entry 占主导地位的生产商受到部分进入威胁的悬崖折扣
Pub Date : 2015-03-25 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.2585023
M. Salinger
I analyze cliff discounts when an incumbent monopolist faces competition from a competitor that can compete for a portion (but not all) of the market, and compare them with both simple pricing and pricing formulas in which the incumbent can cut prices just in the competitive portion of the market. The optimal cliff discount does not require exclusivity by the buyer. By leaving a portion of the market to the competitor, the incumbent gives it the choice between accepting its allocated share at a high price and offering deep discounts for any increase in market share. The optimal contract allows the competitor to earn higher profits by charging a high price for its allocated share, which in turn allows the incumbent to charge a high price. Average prices are higher with the cliff discount than with pricing that targets price cuts to the competitive segment. The model can apply to bundled discounts for multiple products as well as all-units discounts on a single product.
我分析了现有垄断者面临竞争对手时的悬崖折扣,该对手可以竞争一部分(但不是全部)市场,并将其与简单定价和定价公式进行比较,其中现有垄断者只能在市场的竞争部分降价。最优的悬崖折扣并不要求买家独占。通过将一部分市场留给竞争对手,在位者给了竞争对手一个选择,要么以高价接受其分配的份额,要么为市场份额的增加提供大幅折扣。最优契约允许竞争者通过对其分配的份额收取较高的价格来获得更高的利润,这反过来又允许在位者收取较高的价格。与针对竞争细分市场的降价定价相比,悬崖折扣的平均价格更高。该模型既可以应用于多个产品的捆绑折扣,也可以应用于单个产品的全单位折扣。
{"title":"Cliff Discounts by a Dominant Producer Threatened by Partial Entry","authors":"M. Salinger","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.2585023","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2585023","url":null,"abstract":"I analyze cliff discounts when an incumbent monopolist faces competition from a competitor that can compete for a portion (but not all) of the market, and compare them with both simple pricing and pricing formulas in which the incumbent can cut prices just in the competitive portion of the market. The optimal cliff discount does not require exclusivity by the buyer. By leaving a portion of the market to the competitor, the incumbent gives it the choice between accepting its allocated share at a high price and offering deep discounts for any increase in market share. The optimal contract allows the competitor to earn higher profits by charging a high price for its allocated share, which in turn allows the incumbent to charge a high price. Average prices are higher with the cliff discount than with pricing that targets price cuts to the competitive segment. The model can apply to bundled discounts for multiple products as well as all-units discounts on a single product.","PeriodicalId":345107,"journal":{"name":"LSN: Antitrust (Topic)","volume":"59 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2015-03-25","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"126726588","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Partners in Crime: The Effects of Diversity on the Longevity of Cartels 犯罪伙伴:多样性对卡特尔寿命的影响
Pub Date : 2015-03-01 DOI: 10.5465/AMJ.2013.1209
O. Bertrand, Fabrice Lumineau
Despite the importance of organizational misconduct, we still do not know much about coordinated misconduct between firms. In this study, we get a better understanding of how the profile of the partners involved in cartels affects the longevity of their joint misconduct activities. Drawing upon diversity theory, we leverage a distinction between three types of diversity — i.e., variety of age-based experience, separation in uncertainty avoidance, and power disparity — in collective organizational misconduct between firms and we study their respective influence on the longevity of cartels. Our empirical analysis gives support to our main arguments: the longevity of cartels tends to be increased by the level of variety of age-based experience and power disparity between partners but reduced by their level of separation in uncertainty avoidance. Implications for the literature on organizational misconduct are discussed.
尽管组织不当行为的重要性,我们仍然不知道很多关于企业之间的协调不当行为。在这项研究中,我们更好地了解了参与卡特尔的合作伙伴的概况如何影响其共同不当行为的持续时间。在多样性理论的基础上,我们利用了企业集体组织不当行为中三种类型多样性的区别——即基于年龄的经验多样性、不确定性规避中的分离和权力差异,并研究了它们各自对卡特尔寿命的影响。我们的实证分析支持了我们的主要论点:卡特尔的寿命往往会因合伙人之间基于年龄的经验多样性和权力差距的水平而增加,但会因他们在不确定性规避中的分离程度而减少。讨论了对组织不当行为文献的影响。
{"title":"Partners in Crime: The Effects of Diversity on the Longevity of Cartels","authors":"O. Bertrand, Fabrice Lumineau","doi":"10.5465/AMJ.2013.1209","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.5465/AMJ.2013.1209","url":null,"abstract":"Despite the importance of organizational misconduct, we still do not know much about coordinated misconduct between firms. In this study, we get a better understanding of how the profile of the partners involved in cartels affects the longevity of their joint misconduct activities. Drawing upon diversity theory, we leverage a distinction between three types of diversity — i.e., variety of age-based experience, separation in uncertainty avoidance, and power disparity — in collective organizational misconduct between firms and we study their respective influence on the longevity of cartels. Our empirical analysis gives support to our main arguments: the longevity of cartels tends to be increased by the level of variety of age-based experience and power disparity between partners but reduced by their level of separation in uncertainty avoidance. Implications for the literature on organizational misconduct are discussed.","PeriodicalId":345107,"journal":{"name":"LSN: Antitrust (Topic)","volume":"25 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2015-03-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"125236685","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 36
Genesis of Competition Law in India 印度竞争法的起源
Pub Date : 2015-01-20 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.2552486
A. Singh, Anil Kumar
After the advent of Independence in 1947, India, for the better part of half a century thereafter, adopted and followed policies comprising what are known as “Command-and-Control” laws, rules, regulations and executive orders.The Competition law of India, namely, the Monopolies and Restrictive Trade Practices Act, 1969 (MRTP Act) was one such. It was in 1991 that widespread economic reforms were undertaken and consequently the march from “Command-and-Control” economy to an economy based more on free market principles commenced its stride. As is true of many countries, economic liberalisation has taken root in India and the need for an effective competition regime has also been recognized.In the context of the new economic policy paradigm, India has enacted a new competition law called the Competition Act, 2002 (Act, for brief). The MRTP Act has converted into the new law, Competition Act, 2002. The new law has repealed the extant MRTP Act. This paper, therefore, addresses both the enactments and also outlines the logic behind the development.
1947年独立后,印度在此后的大半个世纪里,采取并遵循了由所谓的“命令与控制”(Command-and-Control)法律、法规、规章和行政命令组成的政策。印度的竞争法,即1969年的《垄断和限制性贸易行为法》(MRTP Act)就是其中之一。1991年进行了广泛的经济改革,从而开始从“命令和控制”经济向更以自由市场原则为基础的经济大步迈进。与许多国家一样,经济自由化已在印度扎根,人们也认识到建立有效竞争机制的必要性。在新的经济政策范式的背景下,印度颁布了一项新的竞争法,称为2002年竞争法(简称该法)。MRTP法案已经转化为新的法律,2002年竞争法。新法律废除了现行的MRTP法案。因此,本文既讨论了制定,也概述了开发背后的逻辑。
{"title":"Genesis of Competition Law in India","authors":"A. Singh, Anil Kumar","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.2552486","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.2552486","url":null,"abstract":"After the advent of Independence in 1947, India, for the better part of half a century thereafter, adopted and followed policies comprising what are known as “Command-and-Control” laws, rules, regulations and executive orders.The Competition law of India, namely, the Monopolies and Restrictive Trade Practices Act, 1969 (MRTP Act) was one such. It was in 1991 that widespread economic reforms were undertaken and consequently the march from “Command-and-Control” economy to an economy based more on free market principles commenced its stride. As is true of many countries, economic liberalisation has taken root in India and the need for an effective competition regime has also been recognized.In the context of the new economic policy paradigm, India has enacted a new competition law called the Competition Act, 2002 (Act, for brief). The MRTP Act has converted into the new law, Competition Act, 2002. The new law has repealed the extant MRTP Act. This paper, therefore, addresses both the enactments and also outlines the logic behind the development.","PeriodicalId":345107,"journal":{"name":"LSN: Antitrust (Topic)","volume":"21 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2015-01-20","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"115386363","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Competition in Motor Racing: A New Formula One Antitrust Case? 赛车竞争:一个新的一级方程式反垄断案例?
Pub Date : 2014-12-24 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.2671315
Oliver Budzinski
The European Commission appears to be considering to open a new antitrust case against the owners of the FIA Formula One World Championship (F1), which by some accounts represents the second biggest sports business in the world. Specifically, two interrelated concerns are raised: (i) a violation of a former settlement between F1 organizers and the EC’s competition division by re-mixing regulatory authority and commercial rights through the Federation Internationale l’Automobile (FIA) and (ii) an unfair treatment of smaller teams by excluding them from regulatory decision procedures and by a grossly uneven distribution of revenues among teams. These two concerns, however, do not only point to a violation of the former settlement, they also reveal a major flaw in the 2001 agreement. Instead of restoring competition, the power may just have been leveraged from the FIA to the commercial rights holder.
欧盟委员会(European Commission)似乎正在考虑对国际汽联一级方程式世界锦标赛(F1)的所有者提起新的反垄断诉讼。有人说,F1代表着世界上第二大体育产业。具体来说,提出了两个相互关联的问题:(i)违反了F1组织者和欧共体竞争部门之间的协议,通过国际汽车联合会(FIA)重新混合监管权力和商业权利;(ii)不公平对待小车队,将他们排除在监管决策程序之外,并在车队之间严重不公平地分配收入。然而,这两个问题不仅表明违反了以前的协议,而且还暴露了2001年协议的一个重大缺陷。而不是恢复竞争,权力可能只是杠杆从国际汽联到商业权利持有人。
{"title":"Competition in Motor Racing: A New Formula One Antitrust Case?","authors":"Oliver Budzinski","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.2671315","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2671315","url":null,"abstract":"The European Commission appears to be considering to open a new antitrust case against the owners of the FIA Formula One World Championship (F1), which by some accounts represents the second biggest sports business in the world. Specifically, two interrelated concerns are raised: (i) a violation of a former settlement between F1 organizers and the EC’s competition division by re-mixing regulatory authority and commercial rights through the Federation Internationale l’Automobile (FIA) and (ii) an unfair treatment of smaller teams by excluding them from regulatory decision procedures and by a grossly uneven distribution of revenues among teams. These two concerns, however, do not only point to a violation of the former settlement, they also reveal a major flaw in the 2001 agreement. Instead of restoring competition, the power may just have been leveraged from the FIA to the commercial rights holder.","PeriodicalId":345107,"journal":{"name":"LSN: Antitrust (Topic)","volume":"431 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2014-12-24","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"133338225","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Registered Cartels in Austria – Coding Protocol 奥地利的注册卡特尔-编码协议
Pub Date : 2014-11-25 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.2555458
Nikolaus Fink, Philipp Schmidt-Dengler, K. Stahl, Christine Zulehner
In the period following WW II. until the country accessed the European Union, cartels were legalized in Austria, upon registration with the Austrian Cartel Court. We obtained access to the registration data, and scanned them all towards a microeconomic analysis of contracting behavior between firms competing, in principle, in their respective markets. In this paper, we give a detailed account of our procedure of coding the data from the scanned documents.
在第二次世界大战之后的时期。在该国加入欧盟之前,卡特尔在奥地利向奥地利卡特尔法院登记后才被合法化。我们获得了注册数据的访问权限,并对它们进行了扫描,以便对原则上在各自市场上竞争的企业之间的契约行为进行微观经济分析。本文详细介绍了对扫描文件数据进行编码的过程。
{"title":"Registered Cartels in Austria – Coding Protocol","authors":"Nikolaus Fink, Philipp Schmidt-Dengler, K. Stahl, Christine Zulehner","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.2555458","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.2555458","url":null,"abstract":"In the period following WW II. until the country accessed the European Union, cartels were legalized in Austria, upon registration with the Austrian Cartel Court. We obtained access to the registration data, and scanned them all towards a microeconomic analysis of contracting behavior between firms competing, in principle, in their respective markets. In this paper, we give a detailed account of our procedure of coding the data from the scanned documents.","PeriodicalId":345107,"journal":{"name":"LSN: Antitrust (Topic)","volume":"1 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2014-11-25","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"130605057","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 4
Fixing the Fix: Governance, Culture, Ethics, and the Extending Perimeter of Financial Regulation 解决问题:治理、文化、伦理和金融监管的延伸范围
Pub Date : 2014-11-24 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.2529073
J. O'Brien
The bourgeoning investigation into the manipulation of key financial benchmarks, such as the London Interbank Offered Rate (Libor), has seen the imposition of an escalating range of fines by regulatory and law enforcement agencies. While primarily focused in the United Kingdom and the United States, the misconduct spans the globe. It has also prompted the exit of a number of financial institutions from the setting of benchmark rates. This has posed a range of practical and conceptual problems, which apply at national, regional and global levels. At a practical level, the credibility of the benchmarks, which are a public good, has been undermined, prompting an incremental but observable erosion of public confidence in market integrity. Exit has the effect of reducing pricing transparency and thus liquidity. Secondly, the investigation of collusion has brought the arrival of competition regulators into the arcane world of financial regulation. Their focus on breaking up cartels changes the dynamics, prompting a rapid expansion of the regulatory perimeter. It also facilitates a fundamental rethinking of capital market purpose. This paper evaluates how the confluence of regulatory and criminal investigation offers a time-limited opportunity to transcend the incremental and flawed nature of technical reform. It assesses the conceptual coherence of attempts, driven by the United Kingdom, but with significant support from both the Financial Stability Board and the International Monetary Fund, to create “fair and effective” markets by articulating a new vision of “inclusive capitalism” and whether this addresses the observed institutional corruption.
针对操纵伦敦银行间同业拆借利率(Libor)等关键金融基准的调查愈演愈烈,监管和执法机构开出的罚单也越来越多。虽然主要集中在英国和美国,但这种不当行为遍及全球。它还促使一些金融机构退出基准利率的制定。这造成了一系列实际和概念上的问题,这些问题在国家、区域和全球各级都适用。在实际层面上,作为一种公共产品的基准的可信度受到了损害,促使公众对市场诚信的信心逐渐受到明显的侵蚀。退出会降低定价透明度,从而降低流动性。其次,对串通案的调查将竞争监管机构带入了金融监管的神秘世界。他们对打破卡特尔的关注改变了形势,促使监管范围迅速扩大。它还有助于从根本上重新思考资本市场的目的。本文评估了监管和刑事调查的融合如何提供了一个有限的机会,以超越技术改革的增量和缺陷性质。它评估了在英国的推动下,在金融稳定委员会和国际货币基金组织的大力支持下,通过阐明“包容性资本主义”的新愿景来创建“公平有效”市场的尝试的概念一致性,以及这是否解决了观察到的制度腐败问题。
{"title":"Fixing the Fix: Governance, Culture, Ethics, and the Extending Perimeter of Financial Regulation","authors":"J. O'Brien","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.2529073","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.2529073","url":null,"abstract":"The bourgeoning investigation into the manipulation of key financial benchmarks, such as the London Interbank Offered Rate (Libor), has seen the imposition of an escalating range of fines by regulatory and law enforcement agencies. While primarily focused in the United Kingdom and the United States, the misconduct spans the globe. It has also prompted the exit of a number of financial institutions from the setting of benchmark rates. This has posed a range of practical and conceptual problems, which apply at national, regional and global levels. At a practical level, the credibility of the benchmarks, which are a public good, has been undermined, prompting an incremental but observable erosion of public confidence in market integrity. Exit has the effect of reducing pricing transparency and thus liquidity. Secondly, the investigation of collusion has brought the arrival of competition regulators into the arcane world of financial regulation. Their focus on breaking up cartels changes the dynamics, prompting a rapid expansion of the regulatory perimeter. It also facilitates a fundamental rethinking of capital market purpose. This paper evaluates how the confluence of regulatory and criminal investigation offers a time-limited opportunity to transcend the incremental and flawed nature of technical reform. It assesses the conceptual coherence of attempts, driven by the United Kingdom, but with significant support from both the Financial Stability Board and the International Monetary Fund, to create “fair and effective” markets by articulating a new vision of “inclusive capitalism” and whether this addresses the observed institutional corruption.","PeriodicalId":345107,"journal":{"name":"LSN: Antitrust (Topic)","volume":"33 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2014-11-24","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"127328523","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 5
Networks, Cartels, and Antitrust Policy 网络、卡特尔和反垄断政策
Pub Date : 2014-10-30 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.2518988
Miguel Cuerdo Mir, Pilar Grau-Carles
Despite multiple applications of network theory in different fields of social and legal sciences in general, the possibility of applying this theory to the economic analysis of the antitrust law and, more specifically, to the study of cartels has not yet been considered. This paper develops a set of distances, clustering and centrality measures, taken from network theory, and applies them to the specific case of a cartel sanctioned as such by the European Commission. This approach has enabled us to quantify some characteristic elements of the cartel, such as, for instance, a remarkable asymmetry between operators (nodes in the network), its different degree of influence (study of links), as well as the critical importance of some operators versus other cartelized agents, such that their elimination from the organization would not enable them to create their own cartel. This leads the authors to reconsider the antitrust policy based on leniency programmes.
尽管网络理论在一般的社会和法律科学的不同领域有多种应用,但将这一理论应用于反托拉斯法的经济分析,更具体地说,应用于卡特尔研究的可能性尚未得到考虑。本文从网络理论出发,发展了一套距离、聚类和中心性度量,并将其应用于欧盟委员会批准的卡特尔的具体案例。这种方法使我们能够量化卡特尔的一些特征要素,例如,运营商(网络中的节点)之间的显著不对称,其不同程度的影响(对链接的研究),以及一些运营商相对于其他卡特尔化代理的关键重要性,这样,将他们从组织中清除将使他们无法创建自己的卡特尔。这促使作者重新考虑基于宽大计划的反垄断政策。
{"title":"Networks, Cartels, and Antitrust Policy","authors":"Miguel Cuerdo Mir, Pilar Grau-Carles","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.2518988","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2518988","url":null,"abstract":"Despite multiple applications of network theory in different fields of social and legal sciences in general, the possibility of applying this theory to the economic analysis of the antitrust law and, more specifically, to the study of cartels has not yet been considered. This paper develops a set of distances, clustering and centrality measures, taken from network theory, and applies them to the specific case of a cartel sanctioned as such by the European Commission. This approach has enabled us to quantify some characteristic elements of the cartel, such as, for instance, a remarkable asymmetry between operators (nodes in the network), its different degree of influence (study of links), as well as the critical importance of some operators versus other cartelized agents, such that their elimination from the organization would not enable them to create their own cartel. This leads the authors to reconsider the antitrust policy based on leniency programmes.","PeriodicalId":345107,"journal":{"name":"LSN: Antitrust (Topic)","volume":"128 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2014-10-30","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"114886063","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Justice Story, Bankruptcy Injunctions, and the Anti-Injunction Act of 1793 司法故事,破产禁令和1793年的反禁令法案
Pub Date : 2014-07-21 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.2469339
R. Brubaker
This article explores how the courts of the early Republic interpreted the Anti-Injunction Act ("AIA") of 1793 as applied to federal bankruptcy injunctions restraining state-court proceedings — a common and indeed intrinsic constitutional feature of federal bankruptcy proceedings pursuant to any "uniform Law on the subject of Bankruptcies." The early-Republic bankruptcy injunction cases provide indirect support for James Pfander's and Nassim Nazemi's novel original-ancillary theory positing a much more limited scope for the 1793 AIA than do conventional accounts of that statute's bar. According to Pfander and Nazemi, the 1793 AIA's prohibition against "writs of injunctions" to stay state-court proceedings (sought via an original bill through a suit in equity) did not prohibit ancillary relief in the nature of an injunction (sought via a motion or petition) granted in an equitable proceeding principally seeking relief other than or independent of such an injunction, but for which an injunctive decree (not via a "writ of injunction") might nonetheless be necessary or appropriate. The original-ancillary distinction identified by Pfander and Nazemi is reflected in one of the most prominent, fundamental, and longstanding jurisdictional and procedural divides with respect to bankruptcy proceedings — the dichotomy between plenary assignee/trustee suits at law or in equity via an original complaint or bill, as distinguished from so-called summary bankruptcy proceedings in equity on motion or petition. Early, influential decisions of Justice Story established that federal bankruptcy injunctions properly issue in ancillary summary proceedings and (consistent with the Pfander-Nazemi original-ancillary theory) found no obstacle in the 1793 AIA to enjoining state-court proceedings thereby.The bankruptcy cases not only help illustrate that the 1793 AIA had a much more limited scope than has generally been acknowledged (consistent with both the Pfander-Nazemi original-ancillary interpretation and William Mayton’s single-justice interpretation), they also illuminate the central importance of the AIA, nonetheless, in assuaging federalism sensitivities that were easily aroused in the early Republic. Indeed, the federal courts' administration of nineteenth century bankruptcy laws produced a very acrimonious standoff involving U.S. Supreme Court Justice Joseph Story, New Hampshire Supreme Court Justice Joel Parker, and the New Hampshire legislature, and bearing striking similarities to the Morris v. Allen controversy that many posit as the impetus for enactment of the 1793 AIA. Tellingly, the U.S. Supreme Court ultimately diffused that bankruptcy controversy through a very nuanced invocation of the 1793 AIA that neither broadened its reach (beyond that posited by Pfander and Nazemi) nor posed any enduring obstacle to the effectiveness of federal bankruptcy laws.
本文探讨了共和早期的法院如何解释1793年的《反禁令法》(“AIA”),以适用于限制州法院程序的联邦破产禁令——根据任何“关于破产主题的统一法律”,这是联邦破产程序的一个共同的、实际上是内在的宪法特征。共和早期的破产禁令案例间接支持了James Pfander和Nassim Nazemi新颖的原始辅助理论,该理论认为1793年AIA的适用范围比该法规的常规描述要有限得多。根据Pfander和Nazemi的观点,1793年AIA禁止“禁令令状”来阻止州法院的诉讼程序(通过原始法案通过衡平法诉讼寻求),但并未禁止在衡平法程序中授予的禁令性质的辅助救济(通过动议或请愿寻求),主要是寻求除此类禁令之外或独立于此类禁令之外的救济。但对于这一点,禁令(不是通过“禁令令状”)可能是必要的或适当的。Pfander和Nazemi确定的原始-辅助区别反映在破产程序中最突出、最基本、最长期的司法和程序分歧之一中——法定的全体受让人/受托人诉讼或通过原始诉讼或法案的衡平法诉讼之间的二分法,与所谓的衡平法动议或请愿中的简易破产程序不同。早期,Justice Story有影响力的判决确立了在辅助简易程序中适当发布联邦破产禁令,并且(与Pfander-Nazemi原始性辅助理论一致)在1793年AIA中没有发现因此禁止州法院程序的障碍。破产案件不仅有助于说明1793年AIA的范围比一般认为的要有限得多(与Pfander-Nazemi的原始辅助解释和William Mayton的单一正义解释一致),而且还阐明了AIA在缓和共和早期容易引起的联邦制敏感性方面的核心重要性。事实上,联邦法院对19世纪破产法的管理产生了一个非常激烈的僵局,涉及美国最高法院大法官约瑟夫·斯托里、新罕布什尔州最高法院大法官乔尔·帕克和新罕布什尔州立法机构,这与莫里斯诉艾伦案的争议有着惊人的相似之处,许多人认为这是1793年AIA颁布的动力。引人注目的是,美国最高法院最终通过非常微妙地援引1793年的《美国破产法》(AIA)来平息这场破产争议,这既没有扩大其影响范围(超出了Pfander和Nazemi的假设范围),也没有对联邦破产法的有效性构成任何持久的障碍。
{"title":"Justice Story, Bankruptcy Injunctions, and the Anti-Injunction Act of 1793","authors":"R. Brubaker","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.2469339","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.2469339","url":null,"abstract":"This article explores how the courts of the early Republic interpreted the Anti-Injunction Act (\"AIA\") of 1793 as applied to federal bankruptcy injunctions restraining state-court proceedings — a common and indeed intrinsic constitutional feature of federal bankruptcy proceedings pursuant to any \"uniform Law on the subject of Bankruptcies.\" The early-Republic bankruptcy injunction cases provide indirect support for James Pfander's and Nassim Nazemi's novel original-ancillary theory positing a much more limited scope for the 1793 AIA than do conventional accounts of that statute's bar. According to Pfander and Nazemi, the 1793 AIA's prohibition against \"writs of injunctions\" to stay state-court proceedings (sought via an original bill through a suit in equity) did not prohibit ancillary relief in the nature of an injunction (sought via a motion or petition) granted in an equitable proceeding principally seeking relief other than or independent of such an injunction, but for which an injunctive decree (not via a \"writ of injunction\") might nonetheless be necessary or appropriate. The original-ancillary distinction identified by Pfander and Nazemi is reflected in one of the most prominent, fundamental, and longstanding jurisdictional and procedural divides with respect to bankruptcy proceedings — the dichotomy between plenary assignee/trustee suits at law or in equity via an original complaint or bill, as distinguished from so-called summary bankruptcy proceedings in equity on motion or petition. Early, influential decisions of Justice Story established that federal bankruptcy injunctions properly issue in ancillary summary proceedings and (consistent with the Pfander-Nazemi original-ancillary theory) found no obstacle in the 1793 AIA to enjoining state-court proceedings thereby.The bankruptcy cases not only help illustrate that the 1793 AIA had a much more limited scope than has generally been acknowledged (consistent with both the Pfander-Nazemi original-ancillary interpretation and William Mayton’s single-justice interpretation), they also illuminate the central importance of the AIA, nonetheless, in assuaging federalism sensitivities that were easily aroused in the early Republic. Indeed, the federal courts' administration of nineteenth century bankruptcy laws produced a very acrimonious standoff involving U.S. Supreme Court Justice Joseph Story, New Hampshire Supreme Court Justice Joel Parker, and the New Hampshire legislature, and bearing striking similarities to the Morris v. Allen controversy that many posit as the impetus for enactment of the 1793 AIA. Tellingly, the U.S. Supreme Court ultimately diffused that bankruptcy controversy through a very nuanced invocation of the 1793 AIA that neither broadened its reach (beyond that posited by Pfander and Nazemi) nor posed any enduring obstacle to the effectiveness of federal bankruptcy laws.","PeriodicalId":345107,"journal":{"name":"LSN: Antitrust (Topic)","volume":"27 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2014-07-21","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"129243916","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Classical Competition and Freedom of Contract in American Laissez Faire Constitutionalism 美国自由放任宪政中的古典竞争与契约自由
Pub Date : 2014-06-10 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.2448419
N. Giocoli
It is impossible to tell the history of American antitrust law and economics during the so-called formative era (1890-1915) without a preliminary understanding of the economic rationale underlying that major phase of American constitutional law commonly called laissez faire constitutionalism, or Lochner era. The essay is a preliminary effort to locate such a rationale in the almost perfect overlap between classical political economy, especially the notion of competition as the supreme organizing principle of thriving societies, and classical liberalism, in particular the notion of liberty of contract. It is argued that the well-known Progressive interpretation of the Lochner era fails to recognize the true meaning and extent of this overlap. The protagonists of our story are economists Adam Smith, John Stuart Mill and Francis Wayland, and Supreme Court Justices James Wilson, Oliver Wendell Holmes and Rufus Peckham.
在所谓的形成时代(1890-1915),如果不初步了解美国宪法的主要阶段(通常称为自由放任宪政主义或洛克纳时代)背后的经济原理,就不可能讲述美国反托拉斯法和经济学的历史。这篇文章是在古典政治经济学(特别是竞争作为繁荣社会的最高组织原则的概念)和古典自由主义(特别是契约自由的概念)之间几乎完美的重叠中找到这样一个基本原理的初步努力。有人认为,众所周知的洛克纳时代的进步解释未能认识到这种重叠的真正含义和程度。我们故事的主角是经济学家亚当·斯密、约翰·斯图亚特·密尔和弗朗西斯·韦兰,以及最高法院法官詹姆斯·威尔逊、奥利弗·温德尔·霍姆斯和鲁弗斯·佩克汉姆。
{"title":"Classical Competition and Freedom of Contract in American Laissez Faire Constitutionalism","authors":"N. Giocoli","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.2448419","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2448419","url":null,"abstract":"It is impossible to tell the history of American antitrust law and economics during the so-called formative era (1890-1915) without a preliminary understanding of the economic rationale underlying that major phase of American constitutional law commonly called laissez faire constitutionalism, or Lochner era. The essay is a preliminary effort to locate such a rationale in the almost perfect overlap between classical political economy, especially the notion of competition as the supreme organizing principle of thriving societies, and classical liberalism, in particular the notion of liberty of contract. It is argued that the well-known Progressive interpretation of the Lochner era fails to recognize the true meaning and extent of this overlap. The protagonists of our story are economists Adam Smith, John Stuart Mill and Francis Wayland, and Supreme Court Justices James Wilson, Oliver Wendell Holmes and Rufus Peckham.","PeriodicalId":345107,"journal":{"name":"LSN: Antitrust (Topic)","volume":"6 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2014-06-10","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"128643797","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
期刊
LSN: Antitrust (Topic)
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1