首页 > 最新文献

Theoretical Inquiries in Law最新文献

英文 中文
Frontmatter
Q1 Social Sciences Pub Date : 2021-07-01 DOI: 10.1515/til-2021-frontmatter2
{"title":"Frontmatter","authors":"","doi":"10.1515/til-2021-frontmatter2","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1515/til-2021-frontmatter2","url":null,"abstract":"","PeriodicalId":39577,"journal":{"name":"Theoretical Inquiries in Law","volume":"36 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2021-07-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"86505442","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Preference Change and Behavioral Ethics: Can States Create Ethical People? 偏好变化与行为伦理:国家能造就道德人吗?
Q1 Social Sciences Pub Date : 2021-07-01 DOI: 10.1515/til-2021-0018
Y. Feldman, Yotam Kaplan
Abstract Law and economics scholarship suggests that, in appropriate cases, the law can improve people’s behavior by changing their preferences. For example, the law can curb discriminatory hiring practices by providing employers with information that might change their discriminatory preference. Supposedly, if employers no longer prefer one class of employees to another, they will simply stop discriminating, with no need for further legal intervention. The current Article aims to add some depth to this familiar analysis by introducing the insights of behavioral ethics into the law and economics literature on preference change. Behavioral ethics research shows that wrongdoing often originates from semi-deliberative or non-deliberative cognitive processes. These findings suggest that the process of preference change through the use of the law is markedly more complicated and nuanced than previously appreciated. For instance, even if an employer’s explicit discriminatory stance is changed, and the employer no longer consciously prefers one class of employees over another, discriminatory behavior might persist if it originates from semi-conscious, habitual, or non-deliberative decision-making mechanisms. Therefore, actual change in behavior might necessitate a close engagement with people’s level of moral awareness. We discuss the institutional and normative implications of these insights and evaluate their significance for the attempt to improve preferences through the different functions of the legal system.
法学和经济学研究表明,在适当的情况下,法律可以通过改变人们的偏好来改善人们的行为。例如,法律可以通过向雇主提供可能改变其歧视性偏好的信息来遏制歧视性雇用做法。据推测,如果雇主不再偏爱某一类雇员而不偏爱另一类雇员,他们就会停止歧视,不需要进一步的法律干预。本文旨在通过将行为伦理学的见解引入有关偏好变化的法律和经济学文献,为这一熟悉的分析增加一些深度。行为伦理学研究表明,不法行为往往源于半深思熟虑或非深思熟虑的认知过程。这些发现表明,通过使用法律来改变偏好的过程比以前所认识到的要复杂和微妙得多。例如,即使雇主明确的歧视立场发生了改变,雇主不再有意识地偏爱某一类雇员,但如果歧视行为源于半意识的、习惯性的或非审议性的决策机制,它可能会持续存在。因此,行为的实际改变可能需要密切关注人们的道德意识水平。我们讨论了这些见解的制度和规范含义,并评估了它们对试图通过法律体系的不同功能改善偏好的意义。
{"title":"Preference Change and Behavioral Ethics: Can States Create Ethical People?","authors":"Y. Feldman, Yotam Kaplan","doi":"10.1515/til-2021-0018","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1515/til-2021-0018","url":null,"abstract":"Abstract Law and economics scholarship suggests that, in appropriate cases, the law can improve people’s behavior by changing their preferences. For example, the law can curb discriminatory hiring practices by providing employers with information that might change their discriminatory preference. Supposedly, if employers no longer prefer one class of employees to another, they will simply stop discriminating, with no need for further legal intervention. The current Article aims to add some depth to this familiar analysis by introducing the insights of behavioral ethics into the law and economics literature on preference change. Behavioral ethics research shows that wrongdoing often originates from semi-deliberative or non-deliberative cognitive processes. These findings suggest that the process of preference change through the use of the law is markedly more complicated and nuanced than previously appreciated. For instance, even if an employer’s explicit discriminatory stance is changed, and the employer no longer consciously prefers one class of employees over another, discriminatory behavior might persist if it originates from semi-conscious, habitual, or non-deliberative decision-making mechanisms. Therefore, actual change in behavior might necessitate a close engagement with people’s level of moral awareness. We discuss the institutional and normative implications of these insights and evaluate their significance for the attempt to improve preferences through the different functions of the legal system.","PeriodicalId":39577,"journal":{"name":"Theoretical Inquiries in Law","volume":"3 1","pages":"85 - 110"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2021-07-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"88295718","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Does the Law Change Preferences? 法律会改变人们的偏好吗?
Q1 Social Sciences Pub Date : 2021-07-01 DOI: 10.1515/til-2021-0021
Jennifer H. Arlen, L. Kornhauser
Abstract “I would prefer not” HERMAN MELVILLE, BARTLEBY THE SCRIVENER: A STORY OF WALL STREET (1853), reprinted in THE PIAZZA TALES 32, 48 (London, Sampson Low, Son & Co. 1856). Scholars have recently challenged the claim in classical deterrence theory that law influences behavior only through the expected sanction imposed. Some go further and argue that law may also “shape preferences,” changing people’s wants and values. In this Article, we analyze existing claims that criminal and civil law alter preferences and conclude that none suggest that the law shapes preferences. We first clarify this preference-shaping claim by elaborating the structure of rational choice theory generally and “preference” in particular. We then investigate three mechanisms of legal influence suggested by the preference-shaping literature: (1) the “serious harm” mechanism; (2) the “social norm” mechanism; and (3) the “self-improvement” mechanism. We then show that each of these mechanisms operates by changing the agent’s beliefs about the attributes or consequences of her choice options rather than by changing her preferences.
“我宁愿不要”赫尔曼·梅尔维尔,《誊写员巴特比:华尔街的故事》(1853),转载于《广场故事》第32、48期(伦敦,桑普森·洛,儿子&公司,1856)。学者们最近对经典威慑理论的主张提出了质疑,即法律仅通过预期的制裁来影响行为。有些人更进一步,认为法律也可能“塑造偏好”,改变人们的需求和价值观。在这篇文章中,我们分析了现有的关于刑法和民法改变偏好的说法,并得出结论,没有人认为法律塑造了偏好。我们首先通过阐述理性选择理论的总体结构,特别是“偏好”来澄清这种偏好塑造的主张。然后,我们研究了偏好塑造文献提出的三种法律影响机制:(1)“严重伤害”机制;(2)“社会规范”机制;(3)“自我完善”机制。然后我们表明,这些机制中的每一种都是通过改变代理对其选择选项的属性或结果的信念而不是通过改变她的偏好来运作的。
{"title":"Does the Law Change Preferences?","authors":"Jennifer H. Arlen, L. Kornhauser","doi":"10.1515/til-2021-0021","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1515/til-2021-0021","url":null,"abstract":"Abstract “I would prefer not” HERMAN MELVILLE, BARTLEBY THE SCRIVENER: A STORY OF WALL STREET (1853), reprinted in THE PIAZZA TALES 32, 48 (London, Sampson Low, Son & Co. 1856). Scholars have recently challenged the claim in classical deterrence theory that law influences behavior only through the expected sanction imposed. Some go further and argue that law may also “shape preferences,” changing people’s wants and values. In this Article, we analyze existing claims that criminal and civil law alter preferences and conclude that none suggest that the law shapes preferences. We first clarify this preference-shaping claim by elaborating the structure of rational choice theory generally and “preference” in particular. We then investigate three mechanisms of legal influence suggested by the preference-shaping literature: (1) the “serious harm” mechanism; (2) the “social norm” mechanism; and (3) the “self-improvement” mechanism. We then show that each of these mechanisms operates by changing the agent’s beliefs about the attributes or consequences of her choice options rather than by changing her preferences.","PeriodicalId":39577,"journal":{"name":"Theoretical Inquiries in Law","volume":"101 1","pages":"175 - 213"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2021-07-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"72908174","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
The Data Privacy Law of Brexit: Theories of Preference Change 英国脱欧的数据隐私法:偏好变化理论
Q1 Social Sciences Pub Date : 2021-07-01 DOI: 10.1515/til-2021-0019
P. Schwartz
Abstract Upon Brexit, the United Kingdom chose to follow the path of EU data protection and remain tied to the requirements of the General Data Protection Regulation (GDPR). It even enacted the GDPR into its domestic law. This Article evaluates five models relating to preference change, demonstrating how they identify different dimensions of Brexit while providing a rich explanation of why a legal system may or may not reject an established transnational legal order. While market forces and a “Brussels Effect” played the most significant role in the decision of the UK government to accept the GDPR, important nonmarket factors were also present in this choice. This Article’s models of preference change are also useful in thinking about the likely extent of the UK’s future divergence from EU data protection.
脱欧后,英国选择遵循欧盟数据保护的道路,继续遵守《通用数据保护条例》(GDPR)的要求。它甚至将GDPR制定为国内法。本文评估了与偏好变化相关的五种模型,展示了它们如何识别英国脱欧的不同维度,同时提供了一个丰富的解释,说明为什么一个法律体系可能会或可能不会拒绝既定的跨国法律秩序。虽然市场力量和“布鲁塞尔效应”在英国政府接受GDPR的决定中发挥了最重要的作用,但重要的非市场因素也存在于这一选择中。本文的偏好变化模型在思考英国未来与欧盟数据保护分歧的可能程度时也很有用。
{"title":"The Data Privacy Law of Brexit: Theories of Preference Change","authors":"P. Schwartz","doi":"10.1515/til-2021-0019","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1515/til-2021-0019","url":null,"abstract":"Abstract Upon Brexit, the United Kingdom chose to follow the path of EU data protection and remain tied to the requirements of the General Data Protection Regulation (GDPR). It even enacted the GDPR into its domestic law. This Article evaluates five models relating to preference change, demonstrating how they identify different dimensions of Brexit while providing a rich explanation of why a legal system may or may not reject an established transnational legal order. While market forces and a “Brussels Effect” played the most significant role in the decision of the UK government to accept the GDPR, important nonmarket factors were also present in this choice. This Article’s models of preference change are also useful in thinking about the likely extent of the UK’s future divergence from EU data protection.","PeriodicalId":39577,"journal":{"name":"Theoretical Inquiries in Law","volume":"8 1","pages":"111 - 152"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2021-07-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"74470120","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
The puzzle and persistence of biglaw clustering 大律聚类的困惑与持久性
Q1 Social Sciences Pub Date : 2021-05-05 DOI: 10.1515/til-2022-0008
Gregory H. Shill
Abstract Elite U.S.-based global law firms (“Biglaw” firms) concentrate in the costliest districts of superstar cities, especially two neighborhoods in Manhattan. This pattern has persisted despite both the dispersal of Biglaw clients across less-dense, lower-cost U.S. geographies and the development of telework capacity. It suggests a puzzle: law is among the occupations most conducive to remote work, yet Biglaw prior to the coronavirus pandemic required in-person work in the priciest places—meaning it paid (and continues to pay) a premium on both of its biggest expenses, wages and real estate. How might this equilibrium be explained, and what might lead it to change? This Article contends that Biglaw clustering reflects a management preference for the exploitation of proven strategies over the exploration of novel and uncertain ones—but that the pandemic telework experience is eroding this dichotomy. This analysis has direct implications for private international law (“PIL”) practice, where large-scale transactions and disputes are handled by Biglaw firms and involve significant international travel. This Article contributes to a growing literature on telework’s impacts on cities, labor markets, and industries, and is the first to extend that focus to Biglaw and PIL. A post-pandemic Biglaw embrace of dispersal via telework would destabilize standard accounts of collaboration in agglomeration economies. While the Article expresses skepticism about that outcome, it identifies a mechanism by which it might plausibly come about. Crucially, this mechanism—the replacement of an exploit vs. explore choice with two different exploit options—posits as the key driver not technology but management learning and innovation that quickened during the pandemic.
总部位于美国的精英全球律师事务所(“Biglaw”)集中在超级巨星城市最昂贵的地区,尤其是曼哈顿的两个社区。尽管Biglaw的客户分散在人口密度较低、成本较低的美国地区,而且远程办公能力得到了发展,但这种模式仍然存在。这表明了一个难题:法律是最有利于远程工作的职业之一,但在冠状病毒大流行之前,Biglaw要求在最昂贵的地方亲自工作,这意味着它在工资和房地产这两项最大的支出上都支付了(并继续支付)溢价。如何解释这种平衡,是什么导致了它的改变?本文认为,比格劳聚类反映了管理层倾向于利用已证实的策略,而不是探索新的和不确定的策略,但大流行的远程工作经验正在侵蚀这种二分法。这一分析对国际私法(“PIL”)实践有直接影响,其中大规模交易和争议由大律师事务所处理,并涉及大量的国际旅行。本文对越来越多的关于远程办公对城市、劳动力市场和行业的影响的文献做出了贡献,并且是第一个将重点扩展到Biglaw和PIL的文献。大流行后的比格劳(Biglaw)对通过远程工作进行传播的拥抱,将破坏聚集经济中协作的标准描述。虽然这篇文章对这种结果表示怀疑,但它确定了一种可能实现这种结果的机制。至关重要的是,这种机制——用两种不同的利用选项取代利用与探索的选择——被认为是疫情期间加速的管理学习和创新的关键驱动力,而不是技术。
{"title":"The puzzle and persistence of biglaw clustering","authors":"Gregory H. Shill","doi":"10.1515/til-2022-0008","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1515/til-2022-0008","url":null,"abstract":"Abstract Elite U.S.-based global law firms (“Biglaw” firms) concentrate in the costliest districts of superstar cities, especially two neighborhoods in Manhattan. This pattern has persisted despite both the dispersal of Biglaw clients across less-dense, lower-cost U.S. geographies and the development of telework capacity. It suggests a puzzle: law is among the occupations most conducive to remote work, yet Biglaw prior to the coronavirus pandemic required in-person work in the priciest places—meaning it paid (and continues to pay) a premium on both of its biggest expenses, wages and real estate. How might this equilibrium be explained, and what might lead it to change? This Article contends that Biglaw clustering reflects a management preference for the exploitation of proven strategies over the exploration of novel and uncertain ones—but that the pandemic telework experience is eroding this dichotomy. This analysis has direct implications for private international law (“PIL”) practice, where large-scale transactions and disputes are handled by Biglaw firms and involve significant international travel. This Article contributes to a growing literature on telework’s impacts on cities, labor markets, and industries, and is the first to extend that focus to Biglaw and PIL. A post-pandemic Biglaw embrace of dispersal via telework would destabilize standard accounts of collaboration in agglomeration economies. While the Article expresses skepticism about that outcome, it identifies a mechanism by which it might plausibly come about. Crucially, this mechanism—the replacement of an exploit vs. explore choice with two different exploit options—posits as the key driver not technology but management learning and innovation that quickened during the pandemic.","PeriodicalId":39577,"journal":{"name":"Theoretical Inquiries in Law","volume":"6 1","pages":"191 - 218"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2021-05-05","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"87209867","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Half the Guilt 一半的内疚
Q1 Social Sciences Pub Date : 2021-01-01 DOI: 10.1515/til-2021-0005
Talia Fisher
Abstract Criminal law conceptualizes guilt and the finding of guilt as purely categorical phenomena. At the end of trial, the defendant is pronounced either “guilty” or “not guilty” of the charges made against her, excluding the possibility of judgment of degree. Judges or juries cannot calibrate findings of guilt to various degrees of epistemic certainty by pronouncing the defendant “probably guilty,” “most certainly guilty,” or “guilty by preponderance of the evidence.” Nor can decision makers qualify the verdict to reflect normative or legal ambiguities. Findings of guilt are construed as asserting factual and legal truths. The penal results of conviction assume similar “all or nothing” properties: punishment can be calibrated, but not with the established probability of guilt. The prevailing decision-making model, with its ‘on-off’ formulation of guilt, is so broadly established that it is considered an axiom— but there is nothing natural or pre-political about it, nor about the derivative distribution of punishment. This Article attempts to expose the hidden potential rooted in the construal of criminal verdicts as judgments of degree, by drawing three hypothetical manifestations of a linear conceptualization of conviction and punishment in the criminal trial and plea-bargaining arena. It also offers a normative assessment of converting criminal verdicts from categorical decisions to continuities.
刑法将犯罪及其认定视为纯粹的范畴现象。在审判结束时,被告被宣布对她的指控“有罪”或“无罪”,排除了判断程度的可能性。法官或陪审团不能通过宣布被告“可能有罪”、“肯定有罪”或“证据优势有罪”来根据不同程度的认知确定性来校准有罪的发现。决策者也不能限定判决以反映规范或法律上的模糊性。有罪的发现被解释为主张事实和法律真相。定罪的刑罚结果也具有类似的“要么全有,要么全无”的性质:惩罚可以被校准,但不能以既定的有罪概率为标准。盛行的决策模型,其罪责的“开-关”公式,是如此广泛地建立,以至于它被认为是一个公理——但它没有任何自然或前政治的东西,也没有惩罚的衍生分布。本文试图通过绘制刑事审判和辩诉交易领域中定罪和惩罚线性概念化的三种假设表现,揭示植根于刑事判决作为程度判断的解释的隐藏潜力。它还提供了将刑事判决从绝对决定转变为连续性的规范性评估。
{"title":"Half the Guilt","authors":"Talia Fisher","doi":"10.1515/til-2021-0005","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1515/til-2021-0005","url":null,"abstract":"Abstract Criminal law conceptualizes guilt and the finding of guilt as purely categorical phenomena. At the end of trial, the defendant is pronounced either “guilty” or “not guilty” of the charges made against her, excluding the possibility of judgment of degree. Judges or juries cannot calibrate findings of guilt to various degrees of epistemic certainty by pronouncing the defendant “probably guilty,” “most certainly guilty,” or “guilty by preponderance of the evidence.” Nor can decision makers qualify the verdict to reflect normative or legal ambiguities. Findings of guilt are construed as asserting factual and legal truths. The penal results of conviction assume similar “all or nothing” properties: punishment can be calibrated, but not with the established probability of guilt. The prevailing decision-making model, with its ‘on-off’ formulation of guilt, is so broadly established that it is considered an axiom— but there is nothing natural or pre-political about it, nor about the derivative distribution of punishment. This Article attempts to expose the hidden potential rooted in the construal of criminal verdicts as judgments of degree, by drawing three hypothetical manifestations of a linear conceptualization of conviction and punishment in the criminal trial and plea-bargaining arena. It also offers a normative assessment of converting criminal verdicts from categorical decisions to continuities.","PeriodicalId":39577,"journal":{"name":"Theoretical Inquiries in Law","volume":"13 1","pages":"87 - 109"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2021-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"87511008","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2
All-or-Nothing, or Something – Proportional Liability in Private Law 要么全有,要么全无——私法中的比例责任
Q1 Social Sciences Pub Date : 2021-01-01 DOI: 10.1515/til-2021-0008
Omer Pelled
Abstract Judges and juries often make factual decisions even if the facts are disputed and there is no clear-cut evidence available. Despite this common state of uncertainty, verdicts are thought of as having clear winners and losers––either the plaintiff wins and receives a full remedy, or the defendant wins and the plaintiff gets nothing. In private disputes, factfinders base their binary factual determinations on the preponderance of the evidence. There are, however, several doctrines that allow for partial remedy, discounted by the probability that the facts support the plaintiff’s case, given the available evidence (proportional liability). This Article offers a general theory for proportional liability in private law. It identifies three types of factual uncertainty—mutual uncertainty, unilateral uncertainty, and institutional uncertainty—and shows that legal economists should support proportional liability when the state of uncertainty is shared by the parties and the court (mutual uncertainty), and they should adopt an all-or-nothing rule whenever the information is observable but unverifiable (institutional uncertainty). In cases where one party holds private information (unilateral uncertainty), proportional liability is sometimes, but not always, superior to an all-or-nothing rule.
法官和陪审团通常会在事实存在争议且没有明确证据的情况下做出事实性裁决。尽管存在这种普遍的不确定性,但判决被认为有明确的赢家和输家——要么原告获胜并获得全额赔偿,要么被告获胜而原告一无所获。在私人纠纷中,事实发现者根据证据的优势来确定他们的二元事实。然而,有几个理论允许部分补救,由于事实支持原告案件的可能性,鉴于现有的证据(比例责任)。本文提出了私法比例责任的一般理论。它确定了三种类型的事实不确定性——相互不确定性、单边不确定性和制度不确定性,并表明法律经济学家应该支持比例责任,当不确定性状态由当事人和法院共享(相互不确定性)时,他们应该采用全有或全无的规则,无论信息是可观察的,但无法验证(制度不确定性)。在一方拥有私人信息(单边不确定性)的情况下,比例责任有时(但并非总是)优于全有或全无规则。
{"title":"All-or-Nothing, or Something – Proportional Liability in Private Law","authors":"Omer Pelled","doi":"10.1515/til-2021-0008","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1515/til-2021-0008","url":null,"abstract":"Abstract Judges and juries often make factual decisions even if the facts are disputed and there is no clear-cut evidence available. Despite this common state of uncertainty, verdicts are thought of as having clear winners and losers––either the plaintiff wins and receives a full remedy, or the defendant wins and the plaintiff gets nothing. In private disputes, factfinders base their binary factual determinations on the preponderance of the evidence. There are, however, several doctrines that allow for partial remedy, discounted by the probability that the facts support the plaintiff’s case, given the available evidence (proportional liability). This Article offers a general theory for proportional liability in private law. It identifies three types of factual uncertainty—mutual uncertainty, unilateral uncertainty, and institutional uncertainty—and shows that legal economists should support proportional liability when the state of uncertainty is shared by the parties and the court (mutual uncertainty), and they should adopt an all-or-nothing rule whenever the information is observable but unverifiable (institutional uncertainty). In cases where one party holds private information (unilateral uncertainty), proportional liability is sometimes, but not always, superior to an all-or-nothing rule.","PeriodicalId":39577,"journal":{"name":"Theoretical Inquiries in Law","volume":"20 1","pages":"159 - 199"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2021-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"79300776","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 3
Frontmatter
Q1 Social Sciences Pub Date : 2021-01-01 DOI: 10.1515/til-2021-frontmatter1
{"title":"Frontmatter","authors":"","doi":"10.1515/til-2021-frontmatter1","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1515/til-2021-frontmatter1","url":null,"abstract":"","PeriodicalId":39577,"journal":{"name":"Theoretical Inquiries in Law","volume":"3 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2021-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"79235186","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Discontinuities in Criminal Law 刑法中的不连续性
Q1 Social Sciences Pub Date : 2021-01-01 DOI: 10.1515/til-2021-0007
Avlana K. Eisenberg
Abstract The law values fairness, proportionality, and predictability. Accordingly, in the context of criminal law, punishments should be carefully calibrated to reflect the harm caused by an offense and the culpability of the offender. Yet, while this would suggest the dominance of “smooth” input/output relationships—for example, such that a minuscule increase in culpability would result in a correspondingly small increase in punishment—in fact, the law is laden with “bumpy” input/output relationships. Indeed, a minuscule change in input (be it of harm, culpability, or any number of other measures) may result in a drastic change in output, creating significant discontinuities. Leading scholars have argued that smooth input/output relationships, which feature careful gradation and calibration, better accord with dominant theories of punishment than do bumpy relationships, which lack fine-tuning. Accepting as a starting premise that smooth input/ output relationships are to be preferred in the criminal law, this Article focuses on the significant doctrinal and practical impediments to smoothing out these relationships. This analysis reveals challenges to smoothing out relationships between inputs and outputs, as well as the difficulties associated with addressing discontinuous relationships among inputs and outputs. Specifically, it exposes the law’s classification of inputs and outputs itself as contestable and responsible for a range of hard-to-resolve discontinuities. In doing so, this Article begins the task of laying the groundwork for further analysis and possible reforms.
法律重视公平、相称性和可预见性。因此,在刑法的范围内,应仔细调整刑罚,以反映一项罪行所造成的损害和罪犯的罪责。然而,尽管这表明“平稳”的投入/产出关系占主导地位——例如,罪责的微小增加将导致相应的惩罚的小幅增加——事实上,法律充满了“颠簸”的投入/产出关系。事实上,投入的微小变化(无论是危害、罪责或任何其他措施)都可能导致产出的急剧变化,造成重大的不连续。知名学者认为,平滑的输入/输出关系(具有仔细的分级和校准)比凹凸不平的关系(缺乏微调)更符合主流的惩罚理论。接受平滑的输入/输出关系是刑法中首选的前提,本文侧重于平滑这些关系的重要理论和实践障碍。这一分析揭示了平滑投入和产出之间关系的挑战,以及与处理投入和产出之间不连续关系相关的困难。具体来说,它暴露了法律对输入和输出的分类本身是有争议的,并对一系列难以解决的不连续负责。在此过程中,本文开始了为进一步分析和可能的改革奠定基础的任务。
{"title":"Discontinuities in Criminal Law","authors":"Avlana K. Eisenberg","doi":"10.1515/til-2021-0007","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1515/til-2021-0007","url":null,"abstract":"Abstract The law values fairness, proportionality, and predictability. Accordingly, in the context of criminal law, punishments should be carefully calibrated to reflect the harm caused by an offense and the culpability of the offender. Yet, while this would suggest the dominance of “smooth” input/output relationships—for example, such that a minuscule increase in culpability would result in a correspondingly small increase in punishment—in fact, the law is laden with “bumpy” input/output relationships. Indeed, a minuscule change in input (be it of harm, culpability, or any number of other measures) may result in a drastic change in output, creating significant discontinuities. Leading scholars have argued that smooth input/output relationships, which feature careful gradation and calibration, better accord with dominant theories of punishment than do bumpy relationships, which lack fine-tuning. Accepting as a starting premise that smooth input/ output relationships are to be preferred in the criminal law, this Article focuses on the significant doctrinal and practical impediments to smoothing out these relationships. This analysis reveals challenges to smoothing out relationships between inputs and outputs, as well as the difficulties associated with addressing discontinuous relationships among inputs and outputs. Specifically, it exposes the law’s classification of inputs and outputs itself as contestable and responsible for a range of hard-to-resolve discontinuities. In doing so, this Article begins the task of laying the groundwork for further analysis and possible reforms.","PeriodicalId":39577,"journal":{"name":"Theoretical Inquiries in Law","volume":"45 1","pages":"137 - 157"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2021-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"75725521","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Probabilistic Disclosures for Corporate and other Law 公司法和其他法律的概率披露
Q1 Social Sciences Pub Date : 2021-01-01 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3442607
Saul Levmore
Abstract This Article explores the costs and benefits of one subset of continuous and discontinuous rules. These expressions are shown to be distinct from the familiar dichotomy expressed as standards versus rules, but they share the difficulty of dividing the world of law in two. Still, regulatory approaches that focus on discontinuities can often be made more continuous, and vice versa. A speed limit is discontinuous in the sense that one drives above or below (or within) the announced limit. But it is often made more continuous—even with more discontinuities— as when the stated limit is different for various kinds of vehicles. This Article works around these definitional problems to show that law often discourages useful disclosures by encouraging parties with information to offer continuous information in order to avoid after-the-fact lawsuits when specific disclosures prove to have inaccuracies. For example, it is common to hear or be warned that a medical procedure poses the risk of death, when a better-informed doctor or hospital could have given the precise percentages attached to various outcomes. Similarly, a corporation is on safe ground when it follows “generally accepted accounting principles,” when investors would have learned more from information about good and bad outcomes put in probabilistic terms. The Article works toward the suggestion that law might create a safe harbor in which probabilistic disclosures are protected when they are, or are certified to be, more useful than the ready alternative of fairly general disclosures.
摘要本文探讨了连续规则和不连续规则的一个子集的成本和收益。这些表达方式不同于我们所熟悉的标准与规则的二分法,但它们同样难以将法律世界一分为二。尽管如此,专注于不连续性的监管方法往往可以变得更加连续,反之亦然。从某种意义上说,速度限制是不连续的,即一个人在宣布的限制之上或之下(或之内)行驶。但它往往是更连续的-甚至有更多的不连续-当规定的限制是不同种类的车辆。本文围绕这些定义问题展开工作,以表明当具体披露被证明有不准确性时,法律往往鼓励拥有信息的各方提供连续信息,以避免事后诉讼,从而阻碍有用的披露。例如,经常听到或被警告说某种医疗程序有死亡风险,而如果医生或医院更了解情况,就可以给出各种结果的精确百分比。同样,当一家公司遵循“公认会计原则”时,它是安全的,因为投资者本可以从以概率形式呈现的好坏结果信息中了解到更多信息。该条旨在提出这样一种建议,即法律可以建立一个安全港,当概率性披露比相当普遍的披露更有用或被证明更有用时,它们就受到保护。
{"title":"Probabilistic Disclosures for Corporate and other Law","authors":"Saul Levmore","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3442607","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3442607","url":null,"abstract":"Abstract This Article explores the costs and benefits of one subset of continuous and discontinuous rules. These expressions are shown to be distinct from the familiar dichotomy expressed as standards versus rules, but they share the difficulty of dividing the world of law in two. Still, regulatory approaches that focus on discontinuities can often be made more continuous, and vice versa. A speed limit is discontinuous in the sense that one drives above or below (or within) the announced limit. But it is often made more continuous—even with more discontinuities— as when the stated limit is different for various kinds of vehicles. This Article works around these definitional problems to show that law often discourages useful disclosures by encouraging parties with information to offer continuous information in order to avoid after-the-fact lawsuits when specific disclosures prove to have inaccuracies. For example, it is common to hear or be warned that a medical procedure poses the risk of death, when a better-informed doctor or hospital could have given the precise percentages attached to various outcomes. Similarly, a corporation is on safe ground when it follows “generally accepted accounting principles,” when investors would have learned more from information about good and bad outcomes put in probabilistic terms. The Article works toward the suggestion that law might create a safe harbor in which probabilistic disclosures are protected when they are, or are certified to be, more useful than the ready alternative of fairly general disclosures.","PeriodicalId":39577,"journal":{"name":"Theoretical Inquiries in Law","volume":"18 1","pages":"263 - 284"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2021-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"75794819","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
期刊
Theoretical Inquiries in Law
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1