首页 > 最新文献

Journal of Economics and Political Economy最新文献

英文 中文
Economic and Political Cooperation between India and East Asia: The Emerging Perspective 印度与东亚的经济与政治合作:新兴视角
Pub Date : 2017-04-20 DOI: 10.1453/JEPE.V4I2.1273
A. Chakraborty, D. Chakraborty
After initiating the economic liberalization policies in 1991, India adopted a ‘Look East Policy’ (LEP) with the dual objective of securing economic growth and maintaining maritime security. Cooperation with East Asia received further boost, when the ‘Act East Policy’ (AEP) came into effect during the maiden visit of Prime Minister Mr. Narendra Modi at the ASEAN-India Summit in 2014, which emphasizes on practicing more action-oriented policy towards ASEAN and the wider East Asia. As a result of the policy shift and through the other initiatives like Make-in-India, India’s trade and investment linkages with East Asia is on the rise. In 2015, the Prime Minister visited five East Asian countries at various occasions. There have been other high level diplomatic visits to the East, followed by the appropriate diplomatic channels. Therefore, AEP has brought a great sense of speed and priority in engaging with the East and Southeast Asian countries. On maritime front, China’s nine-dash line doctrine generated strategic concerns both in East and Southeast Asia and India has emerged as a strategic player in the region through joint naval exercises and capacity buildings with partner countries. Given the recent reservations expressed by Beijing against the ruling by the international tribunal in The Hague, India’s maritime security initiatives in East Asia is likely stay relevant in coming days. The current paper examines the future for India-East Asia relations in days to come, especially in the current geo-political set-up.
在1991年启动经济自由化政策后,印度采取了“向东看政策”(LEP),其双重目标是确保经济增长和维护海上安全。2014年莫迪总理首次访问东盟-印度领导人会议期间,“东向行动政策”正式生效,强调对东盟和更广泛的东亚地区实施更加以行动为导向的政策,进一步推动了与东亚的合作。由于政策的转变,以及通过“印度制造”等其他倡议,印度与东亚的贸易和投资联系正在上升。2015年,总理多次访问东亚五国。此外,还通过适当的外交渠道对东方进行了其他高层外交访问。因此,亚太经济伙伴关系给中国与东亚和东南亚国家的交往带来了极大的速度感和优先感。在海上,中国的九段线主张引起了东亚和东南亚的战略关注,而印度通过联合海军演习和与伙伴国的能力建设,已成为该地区的战略参与者。鉴于北京方面最近对海牙国际法庭的裁决表达了保留意见,印度在东亚的海上安全倡议在未来几天可能会保持相关性。本文探讨了未来印度-东亚关系的未来,特别是在当前的地缘政治格局下。
{"title":"Economic and Political Cooperation between India and East Asia: The Emerging Perspective","authors":"A. Chakraborty, D. Chakraborty","doi":"10.1453/JEPE.V4I2.1273","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1453/JEPE.V4I2.1273","url":null,"abstract":"After initiating the economic liberalization policies in 1991, India adopted a ‘Look East Policy’ (LEP) with the dual objective of securing economic growth and maintaining maritime security. Cooperation with East Asia received further boost, when the ‘Act East Policy’ (AEP) came into effect during the maiden visit of Prime Minister Mr. Narendra Modi at the ASEAN-India Summit in 2014, which emphasizes on practicing more action-oriented policy towards ASEAN and the wider East Asia. As a result of the policy shift and through the other initiatives like Make-in-India, India’s trade and investment linkages with East Asia is on the rise. In 2015, the Prime Minister visited five East Asian countries at various occasions. There have been other high level diplomatic visits to the East, followed by the appropriate diplomatic channels. Therefore, AEP has brought a great sense of speed and priority in engaging with the East and Southeast Asian countries. On maritime front, China’s nine-dash line doctrine generated strategic concerns both in East and Southeast Asia and India has emerged as a strategic player in the region through joint naval exercises and capacity buildings with partner countries. Given the recent reservations expressed by Beijing against the ruling by the international tribunal in The Hague, India’s maritime security initiatives in East Asia is likely stay relevant in coming days. The current paper examines the future for India-East Asia relations in days to come, especially in the current geo-political set-up.","PeriodicalId":432468,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Economics and Political Economy","volume":"3 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2017-04-20","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"114623786","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 5
Igglesis Nikos, The Revolution of Grexit: The Plan Igglesis Nikos,《希腊退欧革命:计划》
Pub Date : 2017-04-08 DOI: 10.1453/JEPE.V4I1.1189
Dionysios Solomos, D. Koumparoulis
Abstract. On July 5, 2015, Greece held a referendum for deciding on the blackmailing proposal submitted by the Institutions of the Eurogroup on 25th of June 2015. On the threshold of the credit suffocation, the Greek people did not relent and they expressed through their vote (a percentage of 61, 31% and 3.558.450 votes) their objection; one more “NO” in their history, similar to this of 28th October of 1940. However, the Greek leaders flinched to express this “NO” using tangible policies even if the short term consequences would be painful. Instead, the foreign partners, allies and friends to Greece “which belongs to the West”, still follow a strict austerity policy which has resulted in poverty of the majority of the Greek people, and in the stagflation. Igglesis Nikos, in his book “The Revolution of GREXIT: The Plan”, makes an attempt to present in a detailed way what the Greek people decided…an alternative and sustainable solution. Keywords. Grexit. JEL. A10.
摘要2015年7月5日,希腊就欧元集团机构于2015年6月25日提交的勒索提案举行全民公投。在信贷窒息的门槛上,希腊人民没有放松,他们通过投票(61,31%和3.558.450票的百分比)表达了他们的反对;他们历史上又一个“不”,类似于1940年10月28日。然而,即使短期后果将是痛苦的,希腊领导人也不敢用切实的政策来表达这种“不”。相反,“属于西方”的希腊的外国伙伴、盟友和朋友,仍然奉行严格的紧缩政策,这导致了大多数希腊人民的贫困和滞胀。Igglesis Nikos在他的书《GREXIT的革命:计划》中,试图以详细的方式呈现希腊人民的决定…一个替代的和可持续的解决方案。关键词。Grexit。冻胶。A10。
{"title":"Igglesis Nikos, The Revolution of Grexit: The Plan","authors":"Dionysios Solomos, D. Koumparoulis","doi":"10.1453/JEPE.V4I1.1189","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1453/JEPE.V4I1.1189","url":null,"abstract":"Abstract. On July 5, 2015, Greece held a referendum for deciding on the blackmailing proposal submitted by the Institutions of the Eurogroup on 25th of June 2015. On the threshold of the credit suffocation, the Greek people did not relent and they expressed through their vote (a percentage of 61, 31% and 3.558.450 votes) their objection; one more “NO” in their history, similar to this of 28th October of 1940. However, the Greek leaders flinched to express this “NO” using tangible policies even if the short term consequences would be painful. Instead, the foreign partners, allies and friends to Greece “which belongs to the West”, still follow a strict austerity policy which has resulted in poverty of the majority of the Greek people, and in the stagflation. Igglesis Nikos, in his book “The Revolution of GREXIT: The Plan”, makes an attempt to present in a detailed way what the Greek people decided…an alternative and sustainable solution. Keywords. Grexit. JEL. A10.","PeriodicalId":432468,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Economics and Political Economy","volume":"132 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2017-04-08","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"133116067","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Employment Generation among Women in NREGS: A Synthesis on the basis of Micro Level Field Investigation 新农村地区妇女就业:基于微观层面实地调查的综合研究
Pub Date : 2017-04-07 DOI: 10.1453/JEPE.V4I1.1182
A. Kundu, Sanjib Talukdar
Government of India has initiated the Mahatma Gandhi National Rural Employment Guarantee Scheme (MGNREGS) or N REGS in 2006 where the basic objective is to provide 100 full man-days of employment to each willing rural household. The adjoining act (NREG Act of 2005) that guarantees employment of every rural household for 100 days has different provisions to incentivize participation of women in the programme. The programme indeed has both direct and indirect aspects towards favoring the participation of women in order to fulfill a larger objective of women empowerment. Thus it becomes imperative to focus on the extent to which the programme is inclusive of women. Official data suggest that 47% of all NREGS workers are women. However, in this regard, there is substantial variation not only across states but also across different regions within a state. The present paper based on a primary survey made in Birbhum district of West Bengal, attempts to investigate whether expansion of NREGS has been able to help the female job-card holders to get employment through NREGS where we have considered ratio of female man days to total man days of a household as the outcome variable. It is observed that the heterogeneity in the value of the stated outcome variable is significantly caused by nature of works the female job card holders have to carry out under NREGS and family parameters faced by them which somehow emanate from socio-cultural factor(s) in general and binding in particular. Apart from this, although there is inevitability of the influence of total number of NREGS man- days received in the entire reference period by the household to which the female member(s) belongs, yet, there seems no one to one correspondence between the outcome variable and the same.
印度政府于2006年启动了圣雄甘地全国农村就业保障计划,其基本目标是为每个有意愿的农村家庭提供100个完整工作日的就业机会。保障每个农村家庭就业100天的毗连法(2005年《农村家庭就业法》)有不同的条款鼓励妇女参与该方案。该方案确实在直接和间接方面有利于妇女参与,以便实现赋予妇女权力的更大目标。因此,必须集中注意方案在多大程度上包括妇女。官方数据显示47%的NREGS员工是女性。然而,在这方面,不仅在各州之间,而且在一个州内的不同地区之间,都存在着很大的差异。本文基于在西孟加拉邦Birbhum地区进行的一项初步调查,试图调查NREGS的扩大是否能够帮助女性工作卡持有者通过NREGS获得就业,我们将女性男性工作天数与家庭总男性工作天数的比例作为结果变量。可以观察到,所述结果变量的价值的异质性在很大程度上是由女性工作卡持有者在全国就业登记制度下必须从事的工作性质和她们所面临的家庭参数造成的,这些因素在某种程度上源于一般的社会文化因素,特别是具有约束力的因素。除此之外,尽管女性成员所属的家庭在整个参考期间所获得的NREGS男-日总数不可避免地会产生影响,但结果变量之间似乎没有一一对应的关系。
{"title":"Employment Generation among Women in NREGS: A Synthesis on the basis of Micro Level Field Investigation","authors":"A. Kundu, Sanjib Talukdar","doi":"10.1453/JEPE.V4I1.1182","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1453/JEPE.V4I1.1182","url":null,"abstract":"Government of India has initiated the Mahatma Gandhi National Rural Employment Guarantee Scheme (MGNREGS) or N REGS in 2006 where the basic objective is to provide 100 full man-days of employment to each willing rural household. The adjoining act (NREG Act of 2005) that guarantees employment of every rural household for 100 days has different provisions to incentivize participation of women in the programme. The programme indeed has both direct and indirect aspects towards favoring the participation of women in order to fulfill a larger objective of women empowerment. Thus it becomes imperative to focus on the extent to which the programme is inclusive of women. Official data suggest that 47% of all NREGS workers are women. However, in this regard, there is substantial variation not only across states but also across different regions within a state. The present paper based on a primary survey made in Birbhum district of West Bengal, attempts to investigate whether expansion of NREGS has been able to help the female job-card holders to get employment through NREGS where we have considered ratio of female man days to total man days of a household as the outcome variable. It is observed that the heterogeneity in the value of the stated outcome variable is significantly caused by nature of works the female job card holders have to carry out under NREGS and family parameters faced by them which somehow emanate from socio-cultural factor(s) in general and binding in particular. Apart from this, although there is inevitability of the influence of total number of NREGS man- days received in the entire reference period by the household to which the female member(s) belongs, yet, there seems no one to one correspondence between the outcome variable and the same.","PeriodicalId":432468,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Economics and Political Economy","volume":"21 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2017-04-07","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"131193481","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2
An Employer of Last Resort Scheme which Resembles a Free Labour Market 类似于自由劳动力市场的最后雇主计划
Pub Date : 2017-03-20 DOI: 10.1453/JEPE.V4I1.1237
R. Musgrave
Abstract. The idea that government should act as employer of last resort (ELR) is an old one. That idea is often referred to nowadays as “job guarantee”. Many ELR schemes to date have been confined to the public sector. There is no good reason for that limitation: i.e. the private sector should use ELR labour as well.  A second common characteristic of ELR schemes has been that (like the WPA in the US in the 1930s) they involve specially set up projects or schemes as distinct from subsidising temporary employees into work with EXISTING employers. The “existing employer” option is preferable. Once those two common defects in ELR are removed, the result is a system where the unemployed are subsidised into temporary and relatively unproductive jobs with existing employers till better jobs appear. And that in turn is what the unemployed tend to do in a totally free market: a scenario where there are no minimum wage laws and unemployment benefit, and where the unemployed tend to get temporary low paid jobs in both public and private sectors pending the appearance of better jobs. In contrast to a free market, under ELR, take home pay is maintained at socially acceptable levels. Assuming that free markets maximise GDP, it follows that the sort of ELR system advocated here will also maximize GDP. That free market style ELR system actually resembles the ELR system that the UK has at the time of writing, namely the Work Programme. The latter “free market” / Work Programme system is not free of faults, but as long as ELR employees do not displace regular employees to too great an extent, that “free market” ELR system is better than traditional ELR. Keywords. Employer of last resort, Job guarantee, Work project admistration. JEL. J60, J63, J64, J68.
摘要政府应充当最后雇主(ELR)的想法由来已久。这种想法现在通常被称为“工作保障”。迄今为止,许多ELR计划仅限于公共部门。这种限制没有充分的理由:即私营部门也应该使用ELR劳动力。ELR计划的第二个共同特征是(就像20世纪30年代美国的WPA一样),它们涉及专门设立的项目或计划,而不是补贴临时雇员为现有雇主工作。“现有雇主”选项更可取。一旦消除了ELR的这两个常见缺陷,其结果是失业人员得到补贴,在现有雇主那里从事临时的、相对没有生产力的工作,直到更好的工作出现。而这正是失业者在完全自由的市场中倾向于做的事情:在没有最低工资法和失业救济金的情况下,失业者倾向于在公共和私营部门找到临时的低薪工作,等待更好的工作出现。与自由市场相比,在最低工资制度下,实得工资维持在社会可接受的水平。假设自由市场使GDP最大化,那么这里所提倡的ELR体系也将使GDP最大化。这种自由市场风格的ELR系统实际上类似于英国在撰写本文时的ELR系统,即工作计划。后一种“自由市场”/工作计划制度并非没有缺点,但只要ELR雇员不太严重地取代正式雇员,这种“自由市场”ELR制度就比传统的ELR制度好。关键词。最后用人单位,就业保障,工程项目管理。冻胶。J60, j63, j64, j68。
{"title":"An Employer of Last Resort Scheme which Resembles a Free Labour Market","authors":"R. Musgrave","doi":"10.1453/JEPE.V4I1.1237","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1453/JEPE.V4I1.1237","url":null,"abstract":"Abstract. The idea that government should act as employer of last resort (ELR) is an old one. That idea is often referred to nowadays as “job guarantee”. Many ELR schemes to date have been confined to the public sector. There is no good reason for that limitation: i.e. the private sector should use ELR labour as well.  A second common characteristic of ELR schemes has been that (like the WPA in the US in the 1930s) they involve specially set up projects or schemes as distinct from subsidising temporary employees into work with EXISTING employers. The “existing employer” option is preferable. Once those two common defects in ELR are removed, the result is a system where the unemployed are subsidised into temporary and relatively unproductive jobs with existing employers till better jobs appear. And that in turn is what the unemployed tend to do in a totally free market: a scenario where there are no minimum wage laws and unemployment benefit, and where the unemployed tend to get temporary low paid jobs in both public and private sectors pending the appearance of better jobs. In contrast to a free market, under ELR, take home pay is maintained at socially acceptable levels. Assuming that free markets maximise GDP, it follows that the sort of ELR system advocated here will also maximize GDP. That free market style ELR system actually resembles the ELR system that the UK has at the time of writing, namely the Work Programme. The latter “free market” / Work Programme system is not free of faults, but as long as ELR employees do not displace regular employees to too great an extent, that “free market” ELR system is better than traditional ELR. Keywords. Employer of last resort, Job guarantee, Work project admistration. JEL. J60, J63, J64, J68.","PeriodicalId":432468,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Economics and Political Economy","volume":"104 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2017-03-20","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"127145646","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2
Transnational Entrepreneurship: An Interview with Investment Banker Jose Goldner 跨国创业:采访投资银行家何塞·戈德纳
Pub Date : 2017-03-18 DOI: 10.1453/JEPE.V4I1.1250
J. M. Munoz
Abstract. Interest in transnational entrepreneurship has expanded in recent years. However, there are limited qualitative surveys that shed light on the mindset of the contemporary transnational entrepreneur. This article contributes to academic and business literature by presenting the views of a Panama-born investment banker Jose Goldner. Jose Goldner is a partner at Briggs Capital based in Massachusetts, USA. Through an interview conducted by Dr. J. Mark Munoz of Millikin University, with the assistance of business student Haley Hogenkamp, Goldner shares his viewpoints on transnational entrepreneurship and its business implications. Keywords. Transnational entrepreneurship, Entrepreneurship, International business. JEL. L26, M16.
摘要近年来,人们对跨国创业的兴趣日益浓厚。然而,能够揭示当代跨国企业家心态的定性调查有限。本文介绍了巴拿马出生的投资银行家何塞•戈德纳(Jose Goldner)的观点,为学术和商业文献做出了贡献。乔斯·戈尔德纳是美国马萨诸塞州布里格斯资本公司的合伙人。通过米利金大学J. Mark Munoz博士的访谈,在商学院学生Haley Hogenkamp的协助下,Goldner分享了他对跨国创业及其商业含义的看法。关键词。跨国创业,企业家精神,国际商业。冻胶。L26 M16。
{"title":"Transnational Entrepreneurship: An Interview with Investment Banker Jose Goldner","authors":"J. M. Munoz","doi":"10.1453/JEPE.V4I1.1250","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1453/JEPE.V4I1.1250","url":null,"abstract":"Abstract. Interest in transnational entrepreneurship has expanded in recent years. However, there are limited qualitative surveys that shed light on the mindset of the contemporary transnational entrepreneur. This article contributes to academic and business literature by presenting the views of a Panama-born investment banker Jose Goldner. Jose Goldner is a partner at Briggs Capital based in Massachusetts, USA. Through an interview conducted by Dr. J. Mark Munoz of Millikin University, with the assistance of business student Haley Hogenkamp, Goldner shares his viewpoints on transnational entrepreneurship and its business implications. Keywords. Transnational entrepreneurship, Entrepreneurship, International business. JEL. L26, M16.","PeriodicalId":432468,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Economics and Political Economy","volume":"3 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2017-03-18","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"128050407","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Capital Liberalisation and Economic Instability 资本自由化与经济不稳定
Pub Date : 2017-03-05 DOI: 10.1453/JEPE.V4I1.1210
Kalim Siddiqui
This study intends to examine the larger issues related to capital liberalisation and also to analyse the reasons for recent support of capital mobility and its repercussions for the future prospects of the economies of developing countries. The objective is to critically examine relevant empirical and theoretical studies in order to answer these questions and address the objectives of this study. The methodology adopted in this study relies on secondary information, reports and published studies to address the research questions. The study finds that following the adoption of capital liberalisation and neoliberalism, the economies of most developing countries have become more vulnerable. If China is excluded, we find that most developing economies have been unable to expand employment opportunities or reduce levels of poverty. In recent years capital liberalisation policy has encouraged capital flight from their economies.
本研究旨在研究与资本自由化有关的更大问题,并分析最近支持资本流动的原因及其对发展中国家经济未来前景的影响。目的是批判性地检查相关的实证和理论研究,以回答这些问题,并解决本研究的目标。本研究采用的方法依赖于二手信息、报告和已发表的研究来解决研究问题。研究发现,在实行资本自由化和新自由主义之后,大多数发展中国家的经济变得更加脆弱。如果把中国排除在外,我们发现大多数发展中经济体都无法扩大就业机会或降低贫困水平。近年来,资本自由化政策鼓励资本从这些经济体外逃。
{"title":"Capital Liberalisation and Economic Instability","authors":"Kalim Siddiqui","doi":"10.1453/JEPE.V4I1.1210","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1453/JEPE.V4I1.1210","url":null,"abstract":"This study intends to examine the larger issues related to capital liberalisation and also to analyse the reasons for recent support of capital mobility and its repercussions for the future prospects of the economies of developing countries. The objective is to critically examine relevant empirical and theoretical studies in order to answer these questions and address the objectives of this study. The methodology adopted in this study relies on secondary information, reports and published studies to address the research questions. The study finds that following the adoption of capital liberalisation and neoliberalism, the economies of most developing countries have become more vulnerable. If China is excluded, we find that most developing economies have been unable to expand employment opportunities or reduce levels of poverty. In recent years capital liberalisation policy has encouraged capital flight from their economies.","PeriodicalId":432468,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Economics and Political Economy","volume":"24 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2017-03-05","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"127552130","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 5
Artificial Intelligence and Urbanization: The Rise of the Elysium City 人工智能与城市化:极乐城市的兴起
Pub Date : 2017-03-01 DOI: 10.1453/JEPE.V4I1.1202
J. M. Munoz, Al Naqvi
From ancient times, Greek religion introduced Elysium as a heavenly place to which admission was exclusively reserved for mortals related to gods, heroes, and those blessed by gods. We argue that the rise of artificial intelligence technology will lead to the creation of Elysium cities. Elysium cities agents will be technologists, technocrats, intelligent machines, and wealthy capitalists. These cities will be the first embracers of the artificial intelligence technology and will do so by incorporating five capabilities: physical, intellectual, information, governance, and socio-economic. As early adopters, these cities will acquire tremendous political and economic power and will turn into self-governing city-states. During the early stages of the AI revolution, these Elysium cities will shed millions of unemployed via a process we call De-tech Migration. De-tech cities will be the recipients of the labor migration from the Elysium cities and will rapidly become and remain impoverished. This article presents key policy suggestions that can be adopted by companies and governments to avoid potential decline and find new pathways towards growth and prosperity in an artificial intelligence economy.
从古代开始,希腊宗教就把极乐世界介绍为一个天堂,只有与神、英雄和神所祝福的人才能进入。我们认为,人工智能技术的兴起将导致极乐城市的诞生。极乐世界城市的代理人将是技术专家、技术官僚、智能机器和富有的资本家。这些城市将成为人工智能技术的首批拥抱者,并将通过整合五种能力来实现这一目标:物理、智能、信息、治理和社会经济。作为早期的采用者,这些城市将获得巨大的政治和经济力量,并将成为自治的城邦。在人工智能革命的早期阶段,这些极乐空间城市将通过一个我们称之为“去技术迁移”的过程,摆脱数百万失业者。低科技城市将成为极乐城市劳动力迁移的接受者,并将迅速成为并保持贫困。本文提出了企业和政府可以采用的关键政策建议,以避免潜在的衰退,并在人工智能经济中找到通往增长和繁荣的新途径。
{"title":"Artificial Intelligence and Urbanization: The Rise of the Elysium City","authors":"J. M. Munoz, Al Naqvi","doi":"10.1453/JEPE.V4I1.1202","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1453/JEPE.V4I1.1202","url":null,"abstract":"From ancient times, Greek religion introduced Elysium as a heavenly place to which admission was exclusively reserved for mortals related to gods, heroes, and those blessed by gods. We argue that the rise of artificial intelligence technology will lead to the creation of Elysium cities. Elysium cities agents will be technologists, technocrats, intelligent machines, and wealthy capitalists. These cities will be the first embracers of the artificial intelligence technology and will do so by incorporating five capabilities: physical, intellectual, information, governance, and socio-economic. As early adopters, these cities will acquire tremendous political and economic power and will turn into self-governing city-states. During the early stages of the AI revolution, these Elysium cities will shed millions of unemployed via a process we call De-tech Migration. De-tech cities will be the recipients of the labor migration from the Elysium cities and will rapidly become and remain impoverished. This article presents key policy suggestions that can be adopted by companies and governments to avoid potential decline and find new pathways towards growth and prosperity in an artificial intelligence economy.","PeriodicalId":432468,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Economics and Political Economy","volume":"90 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2017-03-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"127110122","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 7
Metropolitan Business Cycle Analysis for Lubbock 拉伯克都市经济周期分析
Pub Date : 2017-03-01 DOI: 10.1453/JEPE.V4I1.1204
T. Fullerton, Macie Z. Subia
Abstract. This study develops a business cycle index (BCI) for Lubbock Metropolitan Statistical Area (MSA). The Stock & Watson ( 1989 ; 1991 ; 1993 ) methodology is used to develop the BCI and assumes that the co-movements of key economic indicators have a single underlying, unobservable factor. This factor is extracted from the indicators and used to calculate an index that represents economic conditions through an econometric approach.  The model uses the Kalman filter smoothing approach which smooths across variables and over time. This results in an index that is smoother with less pronounced expansions and recessions. Indicator series used for the study are: establishment employment, unemployment, real retail sales and real wages that begin in 1990 and include complete data through the end of 2015. Results indicate that the Lubbock business cycle has peaks and troughs that occur later than those for the national economy. Keywords. Regional Economics; Business Cycles; Economic Indicators. JEL. R15, E32.
摘要本研究发展了拉伯克都市统计区(MSA)的经济周期指数(BCI)。The Stock & Watson (1989;1991;1993)的方法被用来发展BCI,并假设关键经济指标的共同运动有一个单一的潜在的,不可观察的因素。这个因子是从指标中提取出来的,通过计量经济学的方法来计算一个代表经济状况的指数。该模型使用卡尔曼滤波平滑方法,平滑跨变量和随时间的变化。这导致该指数在扩张和衰退不那么明显的情况下更为平稳。该研究使用的指标系列是:企业就业、失业率、实际零售额和实际工资,从1990年开始,包括截至2015年底的完整数据。结果表明,拉伯克经济周期的高峰和低谷出现的时间晚于国民经济的高峰和低谷。关键词。区域经济学;商业周期;经济指标。冻胶。R15 E32。
{"title":"Metropolitan Business Cycle Analysis for Lubbock","authors":"T. Fullerton, Macie Z. Subia","doi":"10.1453/JEPE.V4I1.1204","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1453/JEPE.V4I1.1204","url":null,"abstract":"Abstract. This study develops a business cycle index (BCI) for Lubbock Metropolitan Statistical Area (MSA). The Stock & Watson ( 1989 ; 1991 ; 1993 ) methodology is used to develop the BCI and assumes that the co-movements of key economic indicators have a single underlying, unobservable factor. This factor is extracted from the indicators and used to calculate an index that represents economic conditions through an econometric approach.  The model uses the Kalman filter smoothing approach which smooths across variables and over time. This results in an index that is smoother with less pronounced expansions and recessions. Indicator series used for the study are: establishment employment, unemployment, real retail sales and real wages that begin in 1990 and include complete data through the end of 2015. Results indicate that the Lubbock business cycle has peaks and troughs that occur later than those for the national economy. Keywords. Regional Economics; Business Cycles; Economic Indicators. JEL. R15, E32.","PeriodicalId":432468,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Economics and Political Economy","volume":"26 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2017-03-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"122913770","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 3
Oil Price and Real GDP Growth of Ecuador: A Vector Autoregressive Approach 石油价格与厄瓜多尔实际GDP增长:一个向量自回归方法
Pub Date : 2017-02-25 DOI: 10.1453/jepe.v4i1.1153
Jesser Paladines
Abstract. Ecuador is an oil exporter country but it is also an importer of oil derivatives products, in this research the relationship between the world average price of oil and the GDP per capital of Ecuador is studied, taking annual data of both from 1980 to 2015 and using the methodology of Vector Autoregressive (VAR), it is concluded according to the Impulse Response Function that a positive shock on the price of oil affects positively the GDP growth of Ecuador for 2 unit times and then returns to its natural state later. This must be explained because Ecuador is a net exporter of oil, the VAR model showed itself stable, in addition it was demonstrated that there is a causal relationship of GDP to the Price according to methodology of Toda-Yamamoto. Keywords. Average Oil price, GDP, VAR, Ecuador. JEL. C32, 040, F20.
摘要厄瓜多尔是一个石油出口国,但它也是石油衍生产品的进口国,在本研究中,世界平均石油价格和厄瓜多尔人均国内生产总值之间的关系进行了研究,采取从1980年到2015年的年度数据,并使用向量自回归(VAR)的方法,根据脉冲响应函数可以得出,石油价格的正冲击对厄瓜多尔GDP增长的正向影响为2个单位次,之后恢复到自然状态。这必须得到解释,因为厄瓜多尔是石油净出口国,VAR模型表明自己是稳定的,此外,根据Toda-Yamamoto的方法,它证明了GDP与价格之间存在因果关系。关键词。平均油价,GDP, VAR,厄瓜多尔。冻胶。C32, 040, f20。
{"title":"Oil Price and Real GDP Growth of Ecuador: A Vector Autoregressive Approach","authors":"Jesser Paladines","doi":"10.1453/jepe.v4i1.1153","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1453/jepe.v4i1.1153","url":null,"abstract":"Abstract. Ecuador is an oil exporter country but it is also an importer of oil derivatives products, in this research the relationship between the world average price of oil and the GDP per capital of Ecuador is studied, taking annual data of both from 1980 to 2015 and using the methodology of Vector Autoregressive (VAR), it is concluded according to the Impulse Response Function that a positive shock on the price of oil affects positively the GDP growth of Ecuador for 2 unit times and then returns to its natural state later. This must be explained because Ecuador is a net exporter of oil, the VAR model showed itself stable, in addition it was demonstrated that there is a causal relationship of GDP to the Price according to methodology of Toda-Yamamoto. Keywords. Average Oil price, GDP, VAR, Ecuador. JEL. C32, 040, F20.","PeriodicalId":432468,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Economics and Political Economy","volume":"22 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2017-02-25","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"133178084","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Analysis of Asymmetries in the Tax-Spending Nexus in Burundi 布隆迪税收-支出关系的不对称性分析
Pub Date : 2017-02-24 DOI: 10.1453/JEPE.V4I1.1160
A. Ndoricimpa
This study examines the asymmetries in the tax-spending nexus for Burundi using a three-variable model. The study employs a threshold cointegration test with asymmetric adjustment advanced by Enders & Siklos (2001). The findings indicate that government spending, taxes and grants are cointegrated with asymmetric adjustment. Causality tests from the estimated asymmetric error correction model suggest that in the short run there is an independent relationship between government spending and taxes in Burundi. Pertaining to the impact of grants, the results show that grants encourage the government of Burundi to spend more, but, conversely, they also discourage tax revenue, which is known as the tax displacement hypothesis. The findings further show that only government spending responds to budgetary disequilibrium, and this occurs when the budget situation is worsening. This implies that in Burundi, to restore the equilibrium when the budget situation is worsening, the adjustment is made by reducing spending. A policy intuition arising from this study is that, to reduce budget deficits, Burundi should reduce its grant-dependence and improve its tax collection system as well as cut its spending in sectors where it is not productive and reallocate it to more productive sectors.
本研究使用三变量模型考察了布隆迪税收支出关系的不对称性。本研究采用Enders & Siklos(2001)提出的非对称调整阈值协整检验。研究结果表明,政府支出、税收和补助与非对称调整是协整的。根据估计的不对称误差修正模型进行的因果关系检验表明,在短期内,布隆迪政府支出与税收之间存在独立的关系。关于赠款的影响,研究结果表明,赠款鼓励布隆迪政府增加支出,但相反,它们也阻碍了税收收入,这被称为税收置换假说。研究结果进一步表明,只有政府支出对预算失衡有反应,而这种情况发生在预算状况恶化时。这意味着在布隆迪,为了在预算情况恶化时恢复平衡,必须通过减少开支来进行调整。从这项研究中得出的政策直觉是,为了减少预算赤字,布隆迪应减少对赠款的依赖,改善其税收制度,并削减其在非生产性部门的支出,并将其重新分配给生产性较强的部门。
{"title":"Analysis of Asymmetries in the Tax-Spending Nexus in Burundi","authors":"A. Ndoricimpa","doi":"10.1453/JEPE.V4I1.1160","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1453/JEPE.V4I1.1160","url":null,"abstract":"This study examines the asymmetries in the tax-spending nexus for Burundi using a three-variable model. The study employs a threshold cointegration test with asymmetric adjustment advanced by Enders & Siklos (2001). The findings indicate that government spending, taxes and grants are cointegrated with asymmetric adjustment. Causality tests from the estimated asymmetric error correction model suggest that in the short run there is an independent relationship between government spending and taxes in Burundi. Pertaining to the impact of grants, the results show that grants encourage the government of Burundi to spend more, but, conversely, they also discourage tax revenue, which is known as the tax displacement hypothesis. The findings further show that only government spending responds to budgetary disequilibrium, and this occurs when the budget situation is worsening. This implies that in Burundi, to restore the equilibrium when the budget situation is worsening, the adjustment is made by reducing spending. A policy intuition arising from this study is that, to reduce budget deficits, Burundi should reduce its grant-dependence and improve its tax collection system as well as cut its spending in sectors where it is not productive and reallocate it to more productive sectors.","PeriodicalId":432468,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Economics and Political Economy","volume":"7 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2017-02-24","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"125371228","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 6
期刊
Journal of Economics and Political Economy
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1