首页 > 最新文献

Yale Journal on Regulation最新文献

英文 中文
Fact or Fiction: The Legal Construction of Immigration Removal for Crimes 事实还是虚构:犯罪驱逐移民的法律建构
IF 2.8 1区 社会学 Q1 Social Sciences Pub Date : 2010-05-12 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.1361670
M. A. Sweeney
Thousands of long-term legal permanent residents are deported from the United States each year because they have been convicted of criminal offenses, many quite minor. These deportations occur without any of the constitutional safeguards that generally protect criminal defendants. Immigration authorities rely on cases asserting that such deportations are not punishment for the crime, but merely collateral consequences of the conviction. This article challenges that reasoning. It argues that its factual and doctrinal foundation has completely disintegrated over the last 20 years. Far-reaching changes in immigration law and enforcement have rendered deportation for aggravated felonies a "definite, immediate and largely automatic effect on the range of the defendant's punishment," that is, the direct consequence of a conviction. As such, the state should impose it only subject to the same constitutional protections that apply to criminal prosecutions. One key implication is that non-citizen criminal defendants should be fully and accurately advised of the immigration consequences of any plea agreement. Finally, this article argues that, while deportation has essentially become an additional criminal sanction for non-citizens, it is not a particularly effective or appropriate one. The article thus advocates a deep revision of immigration laws to restore deportation as a sanction imposed in the exercise of discretion on those whose criminal offenses outweigh their ties to the United States community and the hardship they and their community would suffer if they were deported.
每年都有成千上万的长期合法永久居民被驱逐出美国,因为他们被判犯有刑事罪行,其中许多是相当轻微的罪行。这些驱逐没有任何宪法保障,而宪法保障一般是保护刑事被告的。移民当局根据案例断言,这种驱逐不是对犯罪的惩罚,而只是定罪的附带后果。本文对这种推理提出了挑战。它认为,在过去的20年里,它的事实和教义基础已经完全瓦解。移民法和执法方面的深远变化使得对严重重罪的驱逐出境“对被告的惩罚范围产生了明确、直接和很大程度上自动的影响”,也就是说,这是定罪的直接后果。因此,国家应该只在适用于刑事起诉的宪法保护下实施它。一个关键的含义是,非公民刑事被告应该被充分和准确地告知任何认罪协议的移民后果。最后,本文认为,虽然驱逐出境实质上已成为对非公民的一种额外的刑事制裁,但它不是一种特别有效或适当的制裁。因此,该条主张对移民法进行深入修订,以恢复将驱逐出境作为行使自由裁量权时对那些其刑事罪行超过其与美国社会的关系以及他们及其社区如果被驱逐将遭受的苦难的人施加的一种制裁。
{"title":"Fact or Fiction: The Legal Construction of Immigration Removal for Crimes","authors":"M. A. Sweeney","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.1361670","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1361670","url":null,"abstract":"Thousands of long-term legal permanent residents are deported from the United States each year because they have been convicted of criminal offenses, many quite minor. These deportations occur without any of the constitutional safeguards that generally protect criminal defendants. Immigration authorities rely on cases asserting that such deportations are not punishment for the crime, but merely collateral consequences of the conviction. This article challenges that reasoning. It argues that its factual and doctrinal foundation has completely disintegrated over the last 20 years. Far-reaching changes in immigration law and enforcement have rendered deportation for aggravated felonies a \"definite, immediate and largely automatic effect on the range of the defendant's punishment,\" that is, the direct consequence of a conviction. As such, the state should impose it only subject to the same constitutional protections that apply to criminal prosecutions. One key implication is that non-citizen criminal defendants should be fully and accurately advised of the immigration consequences of any plea agreement. Finally, this article argues that, while deportation has essentially become an additional criminal sanction for non-citizens, it is not a particularly effective or appropriate one. The article thus advocates a deep revision of immigration laws to restore deportation as a sanction imposed in the exercise of discretion on those whose criminal offenses outweigh their ties to the United States community and the hardship they and their community would suffer if they were deported.","PeriodicalId":46196,"journal":{"name":"Yale Journal on Regulation","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":2.8,"publicationDate":"2010-05-12","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.2139/ssrn.1361670","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"68169706","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 3
Hedging the IRS - A Policy Justification for Excluding Liability and Tax Insurance Proceeds 对冲美国国税局-排除责任和税收保险收益的政策理由
IF 2.8 1区 社会学 Q1 Social Sciences Pub Date : 2008-03-14 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.1106343
J. Kahn
Uncertainty as to tax results is an ever present obstacle to business transaction despite the extensive number of Code sections that exist. Private insurance companies have seen an opportunity to enter the market and provide a useful service which can reduce tax uncertainty obstruction to engaging in promising endeavors. Some insurance companies now provide an insurance product to protect the insured against adverse tax consequences from proposed transactions.Ironically, this new insurance product, labeled tax insurance, poses uncertain tax consequences itself. If the adverse tax consequences arise (that is, the taxpayer has additional tax liability) and the insurance company is contractually required to cover that liability, are the insurance proceeds that reimburse the insured for the additional tax liability included in the insured's gross income? If so, the insured might need to purchase additional coverage to pay for the tax incurred on receiving the proceeds.Commentators have concluded that the proceeds are taxable, and insurance companies also appear to adopt that view since tax insurance generally includes gross-up provisions to cover the tax that might be imposed on the disbursement of the proceeds. Contrary to that general opinion, this article argues that the tax insurance proceeds are not includable in the insured's gross income.The proceeds of general liability insurance have not been treated as taxable to the insured when paid to satisfy a liability of the insured. Some commentators have questioned whether there is a justification for that treatment under tax policy. As part of the reasoning that underlies the author's conclusion concerning tax insurance, the article examines that question and develops a novel approach that provides a tax policy justification for excluding those proceeds from the insured's income. The article concludes that the same justification also applies to exclude tax insurance proceeds from the insured's gross income.
尽管存在大量的法典章节,但税收结果的不确定性始终是商业交易的障碍。私营保险公司看到了进入市场的机会,并提供了一种有用的服务,可以减少税收不确定性,阻碍从事有前途的事业。一些保险公司现在提供一种保险产品,以保护被保险人免受拟议交易的不利税收后果。具有讽刺意味的是,这种被称为税收保险的新保险产品本身就带来了不确定的税收后果。如果产生了不利的税收后果(即纳税人有额外的纳税义务),保险公司根据合同要求承担该责任,那么用于偿还被保险人额外纳税义务的保险收益是否包括在被保险人的总收入中?如果是这样,被保险人可能需要购买额外的保险来支付收到收益时产生的税收。评论人士的结论是,这些收益是应纳税的,保险公司似乎也采纳了这一观点,因为税务保险通常包括毛额准备金,以支付可能在支付收益时征收的税款。与一般观点相反,本文认为税收保险收益不包括在被保险人的总收入中。一般责任保险的收益在支付以清偿被保险人的责任时,未被视为应纳税。一些评论人士质疑,在税收政策下,这种待遇是否合理。作为作者关于税收保险结论的推理的一部分,本文研究了这个问题,并开发了一种新的方法,为从被保险人的收入中排除这些收益提供了税收政策的理由。本文的结论是,同样的理由也适用于从被保险人总收入中排除税收保险收益。
{"title":"Hedging the IRS - A Policy Justification for Excluding Liability and Tax Insurance Proceeds","authors":"J. Kahn","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.1106343","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.1106343","url":null,"abstract":"Uncertainty as to tax results is an ever present obstacle to business transaction despite the extensive number of Code sections that exist. Private insurance companies have seen an opportunity to enter the market and provide a useful service which can reduce tax uncertainty obstruction to engaging in promising endeavors. Some insurance companies now provide an insurance product to protect the insured against adverse tax consequences from proposed transactions.Ironically, this new insurance product, labeled tax insurance, poses uncertain tax consequences itself. If the adverse tax consequences arise (that is, the taxpayer has additional tax liability) and the insurance company is contractually required to cover that liability, are the insurance proceeds that reimburse the insured for the additional tax liability included in the insured's gross income? If so, the insured might need to purchase additional coverage to pay for the tax incurred on receiving the proceeds.Commentators have concluded that the proceeds are taxable, and insurance companies also appear to adopt that view since tax insurance generally includes gross-up provisions to cover the tax that might be imposed on the disbursement of the proceeds. Contrary to that general opinion, this article argues that the tax insurance proceeds are not includable in the insured's gross income.The proceeds of general liability insurance have not been treated as taxable to the insured when paid to satisfy a liability of the insured. Some commentators have questioned whether there is a justification for that treatment under tax policy. As part of the reasoning that underlies the author's conclusion concerning tax insurance, the article examines that question and develops a novel approach that provides a tax policy justification for excluding those proceeds from the insured's income. The article concludes that the same justification also applies to exclude tax insurance proceeds from the insured's gross income.","PeriodicalId":46196,"journal":{"name":"Yale Journal on Regulation","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":2.8,"publicationDate":"2008-03-14","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"68140673","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Sheltering Lawyers: The Organized Tax Bar and the Tax Shelter Industry 庇护律师:有组织的税务律师和避税行业
IF 2.8 1区 社会学 Q1 Social Sciences Pub Date : 2005-04-01 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.696704
Tanina Rostain
This Article considers the role of tax lawyers in the corporate tax shelter controversy. In the mid-1990s, a large market emerged in abusive tax shelters, which cost the treasury tens of billions of dollars in lost tax revenue a year. Although individual tax lawyers were deeply involved in abusive tax shelters, the organized tax bar supported law reforms intended to rein in the tax shelter market. The bar's initiatives included due diligence obligations for opinion letters issued in connection with tax shelters and other proposals intended to strengthen practice standards. The tax bar's positions in the tax shelter debate cannot be adequately explained by conventional accounts of the organized bar, which assume that bar groups act to further lawyers' or clients' economic interests or to improve the reputation of the bar. Nor, however, should the bar's positions be taken as pure expressions of public-mindedness. A more nuanced conception of professionalism is required to account for the bar's initiatives. This Article argues that the bar's positions reflect a specific professional ideology of tax practice in which tax lawyers, by virtue of their expertise, serve as gatekeepers for the tax system. While not conferring immediate economic benefits to tax lawyers, the bar's reforms further tax lawyers' long-term reputational and other interests, even as they serve to bind lawyers to higher practice standards and protect the integrity of the tax system.
本文探讨了税务律师在企业避税争议中的作用。上世纪90年代中期,滥用避税手段形成了一个巨大的市场,导致美国财政部每年损失数百亿美元的税收收入。尽管个别税务律师深深卷入了滥用避税的行为,但有组织的税务律师协会支持旨在控制避税市场的法律改革。律师公会的举措包括对与避税和其他旨在加强执业标准的建议有关的意见书进行尽职调查。税务律师在避税辩论中的立场不能用有组织的律师协会的传统说法来充分解释,这些说法认为律师协会的行为是为了促进律师或客户的经济利益,或提高律师协会的声誉。然而,律师公会的立场也不应被视为纯粹的公众意识的表达。我们需要一个更细致入微的专业概念来解释酒吧的举措。本文认为,律师的立场反映了一种特定的税务实践专业意识形态,在这种意识形态中,税务律师凭借其专业知识,充当了税收系统的守门人。虽然没有给税务律师带来直接的经济利益,但律师协会的改革进一步提高了税务律师的长期声誉和其他利益,甚至可以约束律师遵守更高的执业标准,保护税收制度的完整性。
{"title":"Sheltering Lawyers: The Organized Tax Bar and the Tax Shelter Industry","authors":"Tanina Rostain","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.696704","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.696704","url":null,"abstract":"This Article considers the role of tax lawyers in the corporate tax shelter controversy. In the mid-1990s, a large market emerged in abusive tax shelters, which cost the treasury tens of billions of dollars in lost tax revenue a year. Although individual tax lawyers were deeply involved in abusive tax shelters, the organized tax bar supported law reforms intended to rein in the tax shelter market. The bar's initiatives included due diligence obligations for opinion letters issued in connection with tax shelters and other proposals intended to strengthen practice standards. The tax bar's positions in the tax shelter debate cannot be adequately explained by conventional accounts of the organized bar, which assume that bar groups act to further lawyers' or clients' economic interests or to improve the reputation of the bar. Nor, however, should the bar's positions be taken as pure expressions of public-mindedness. A more nuanced conception of professionalism is required to account for the bar's initiatives. This Article argues that the bar's positions reflect a specific professional ideology of tax practice in which tax lawyers, by virtue of their expertise, serve as gatekeepers for the tax system. While not conferring immediate economic benefits to tax lawyers, the bar's reforms further tax lawyers' long-term reputational and other interests, even as they serve to bind lawyers to higher practice standards and protect the integrity of the tax system.","PeriodicalId":46196,"journal":{"name":"Yale Journal on Regulation","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":2.8,"publicationDate":"2005-04-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"67804517","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 13
Reexamining the Market for Judicial Clerks and Other Assortative Matching Markets 重新审视司法书记员市场和其他分类匹配市场
IF 2.8 1区 社会学 Q1 Social Sciences Pub Date : 2003-09-08 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.444220
G. Priest
For many decades, scholars have puzzled over why the market for judicial clerks has been characterized by increasingly early bidding, with interviews and offers extended at progressively early points in a student's law school career. An important article published recently by Jolls, Avery, Judge Posner and Alvin Roth reported the results of a study the authors conducted of judges and clerks documenting the many ways in which the market operated inefficiently. In their view, the clerk market corresponds to other markets studied chiefly by Roth that show timing disturbances claimed to be market failures. The authors recommended adoption of a modified matching program, similar to the program that matches medical residents with hospitals. This paper reanalyzes the clerkship market and the other markets studied by Professor Roth from the standpoint of the costs and benefits of information acquisition. It shows that, far from market failure, the use of time as a currency in the market, represents the working out of market forces where other, more traditional terms of trade - in particular, price - are unavailable. The paper also shows that virtually all of the other markets studied by Roth that show timing peculiarities are characterized by restraints on the use of price to clear the market.
几十年来,学者们一直困惑的是,为什么司法书记员市场的特点是越来越早的竞标,面试和offer在学生法学院生涯的早期就开始了。乔尔斯、艾弗里、波斯纳法官和阿尔文·罗斯最近发表了一篇重要的文章,报告了他们对法官和书记员进行的一项研究的结果,该研究记录了市场低效运作的许多方式。在他们看来,职员市场与罗斯主要研究的其他市场相对应,这些市场表明时间干扰被认为是市场失灵。作者建议采用一种改进的匹配方案,类似于将住院医生与医院匹配的方案。本文从信息获取的成本和收益的角度重新分析了职员市场和罗斯教授研究的其他市场。它表明,在没有其他更传统的贸易条件,特别是价格条件的情况下,使用时间作为市场货币,远不是市场失灵,而是市场力量的发挥。这篇论文还表明,罗斯研究的几乎所有其他表现出时机特殊性的市场,都以限制使用价格出清市场为特征。
{"title":"Reexamining the Market for Judicial Clerks and Other Assortative Matching Markets","authors":"G. Priest","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.444220","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.444220","url":null,"abstract":"For many decades, scholars have puzzled over why the market for judicial clerks has been characterized by increasingly early bidding, with interviews and offers extended at progressively early points in a student's law school career. An important article published recently by Jolls, Avery, Judge Posner and Alvin Roth reported the results of a study the authors conducted of judges and clerks documenting the many ways in which the market operated inefficiently. In their view, the clerk market corresponds to other markets studied chiefly by Roth that show timing disturbances claimed to be market failures. The authors recommended adoption of a modified matching program, similar to the program that matches medical residents with hospitals. This paper reanalyzes the clerkship market and the other markets studied by Professor Roth from the standpoint of the costs and benefits of information acquisition. It shows that, far from market failure, the use of time as a currency in the market, represents the working out of market forces where other, more traditional terms of trade - in particular, price - are unavailable. The paper also shows that virtually all of the other markets studied by Roth that show timing peculiarities are characterized by restraints on the use of price to clear the market.","PeriodicalId":46196,"journal":{"name":"Yale Journal on Regulation","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":2.8,"publicationDate":"2003-09-08","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"68789466","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 7
Is Structural Separation of Incumbent Local Exchange Carriers Necessary for Competition 现有地方交换运营商的结构性分离是竞争的必要条件吗
IF 2.8 1区 社会学 Q1 Social Sciences Pub Date : 2002-03-01 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.302846
R. Crandall, J. Sidak
Although competitive local exchange carriers (CLECs) collectively have gained considerable market share since the passage of the Telecommunications Act of 1996, many entrants into local telecommunications have stumbled or failed. Some argue that competitive local telephony will eventuate only if the incumbent local exchange carriers (ILECs) place their wholesale and retail operations in structurally separate subsidiaries. By mid-2001, several states began proceedings on mandatory structural separation, and influential members of Congress introduced legislation mandating structural separation. In this Article, we analyze, and reject as unpersuasive, the putative benefits of mandatory structural separation. Such regulatory intervention is unnecessary to prevent discrimination against unaffiliated retailers of telecommunications services. Nor would mandatory structural separation lower wholesale discounts or increase the CLECs' market share. Plausible hypotheses for the CLECs' problems do not require the assumption of anticompetitive behavior by the ILECs. Apart from producing no discernable benefits to consumers, mandatory structural separation would entail a substantial social cost in terms of forgone coordination of investment and production and forgone economies of scope. Moreover, mandatory structural separation would harm consumer welfare and reduce resources for investment by facilitating an anticompetitive strategy by the ILECs' largest rivals to raise the ILECs' costs of providing local telecommunications services. Policy makers should reject proposals for mandatory structural separation of the ILECs.
尽管自1996年《电信法》通过以来,竞争性的本地交换运营商(clec)共同获得了相当大的市场份额,但许多进入本地电信行业的企业都遭遇了挫折或失败。一些人认为,只有当现有的本地交换运营商(ILECs)将其批发和零售业务置于结构上独立的子公司时,竞争激烈的本地电话才会最终出现。到2001年年中,几个州开始了强制结构分离的程序,有影响力的国会议员提出了强制结构分离的立法。在本文中,我们分析了强制性结构分离的假定好处,并以缺乏说服力的理由予以拒绝。为了防止对无关联的电信服务零售商的歧视,这种监管干预是不必要的。强制性的结构性分离也不会降低批发折扣或增加clec的市场份额。对clec问题的合理假设不需要假设ilec存在反竞争行为。除了对消费者没有明显的好处外,强制性的结构分离还会在放弃投资和生产的协调以及放弃范围经济方面造成巨大的社会成本。此外,强制性的结构性分离会损害消费者福利,减少投资资源,因为它会促进国际电信公司最大的竞争对手采取反竞争战略,以提高国际电信公司提供本地电信服务的成本。政策制定者应该拒绝强制性结构分离ilec的建议。
{"title":"Is Structural Separation of Incumbent Local Exchange Carriers Necessary for Competition","authors":"R. Crandall, J. Sidak","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.302846","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.302846","url":null,"abstract":"Although competitive local exchange carriers (CLECs) collectively have gained considerable market share since the passage of the Telecommunications Act of 1996, many entrants into local telecommunications have stumbled or failed. Some argue that competitive local telephony will eventuate only if the incumbent local exchange carriers (ILECs) place their wholesale and retail operations in structurally separate subsidiaries. By mid-2001, several states began proceedings on mandatory structural separation, and influential members of Congress introduced legislation mandating structural separation. In this Article, we analyze, and reject as unpersuasive, the putative benefits of mandatory structural separation. Such regulatory intervention is unnecessary to prevent discrimination against unaffiliated retailers of telecommunications services. Nor would mandatory structural separation lower wholesale discounts or increase the CLECs' market share. Plausible hypotheses for the CLECs' problems do not require the assumption of anticompetitive behavior by the ILECs. Apart from producing no discernable benefits to consumers, mandatory structural separation would entail a substantial social cost in terms of forgone coordination of investment and production and forgone economies of scope. Moreover, mandatory structural separation would harm consumer welfare and reduce resources for investment by facilitating an anticompetitive strategy by the ILECs' largest rivals to raise the ILECs' costs of providing local telecommunications services. Policy makers should reject proposals for mandatory structural separation of the ILECs.","PeriodicalId":46196,"journal":{"name":"Yale Journal on Regulation","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":2.8,"publicationDate":"2002-03-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"68492818","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 67
The Failure of Good Intentions: The WorldCom Fraud and the Collapse of American Telecommunications After Deregulation 善意的失败:世界通信诈骗和美国电信在放松管制后的崩溃
IF 2.8 1区 社会学 Q1 Social Sciences Pub Date : 2002-01-01 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.335180
J., Gregory Sidakt
This paper was substantially revised in March 2003 to analyze WorldCom's fraud and bankruptcy and the FCC's February 20, 2003 decision its Triennial Review of mandatory unbundling. To date, policymakers and scholars have failed to recognize how those topics are interrelated. The United States has spent seven years trying to deregulate telecommunications. We are not in the transition any longer. It is time to take stock. In this essay, I address three topics. The first, addressed in Part I, is the administrative cost of deregulation, which has grown substantially under the Telecommunications Act of 1996.Part II addresses the consequences of the FCC's use of a competitor-welfare standard when formulating its policies for local competition, rather than a consumer-welfare standard. I evaluate the reported features of the FCC's decision in its Triennial Review. Press releases and statements concerning that decision suggest that the FCC may have finally embraced a consumer-welfare approach to mandatory unbundling at TELRIC prices. The haphazard administrative process surrounding the FCC's decision, however, increases the likelihood of reversal on appeal.Beginning in Part III, I address at greater length the WorldCom fraud and bankruptcy. I offer an early assessment of the harm to the telecommunications industry from WorldCom's fraud and bankruptcy. I explain how WorldCom's misconduct caused collateral damage to other telecommunications firms, government, workers, and the capital markets. WorldCom's false Internet traffic reports and accounting fraud encouraged overinvestment in long-distance capacity and Internet backbone capacity. Because Internet traffic data are proprietary and WorldCom dominated Internet backbone services, and because WorldCom was subject to regulatory oversight, it was reasonable for rival carriers to believe WorldCom's misrepresentation of Internet traffic growth. Event study analysis suggests that the harm to rival carriers and telecommunications equipment manufacturers from WorldCom's restatement of earnings was $7.8 billion. WorldCom's false or fraudulent statements also supplied state and federal governments with incorrect information essential to the formulation of telecommunication policy. State and federal governments, courts, and regulatory commissions would thus be justified in applying extreme skepticism to future representations made by WorldCom.Part IV explains how WorldCom's fraud and bankruptcy may have been intended to harm competition, and in the future may do so, by inducing exit (or forfeiture of market share) by the company's rivals. WorldCom repeatedly deceived investors, competitors, and regulators with false statements about its Internet traffic projections and financial performance. At a minimum, WorldCom's fraudulent or false statements may have raised rivals' costs by inducing inefficient investment in capacity or inefficient expenditures for customer acquisition and may have artificially reduced WorldCom
这篇论文在2003年3月进行了实质性的修订,以分析世界通信公司的欺诈和破产,以及美国联邦通信委员会2003年2月20日决定对强制分拆进行三年一次的审查。迄今为止,政策制定者和学者们未能认识到这些主题是如何相互关联的。美国花了7年时间试图解除对电信业的管制。我们不再处于过渡时期。是时候进行评估了。在这篇文章中,我将讨论三个主题。第一部分讨论的第一个问题是放松管制的行政成本,根据1996年的《电信法》,这一成本大幅增长。第二部分阐述了FCC在制定当地竞争政策时使用竞争者福利标准而不是消费者福利标准的后果。我在其三年期审查中评估了FCC决定的报道特征。有关该决定的新闻稿和声明表明,联邦通信委员会可能最终接受了一种消费者福利的方式,以TELRIC价格强制分拆。然而,围绕FCC决定的杂乱无章的行政程序增加了上诉逆转的可能性。从第三部分开始,我更详细地讨论了世通的欺诈和破产。我对世通的欺诈和破产给电信业带来的危害进行了初步评估。我解释了世通的不当行为是如何给其他电信公司、政府、员工和资本市场造成附带损害的。世通虚假的互联网流量报告和会计欺诈鼓励了对长途容量和互联网骨干容量的过度投资。由于互联网流量数据是专有的,而WorldCom主导着互联网骨干服务,而且WorldCom受监管监督,竞争对手相信WorldCom对互联网流量增长的虚假陈述是合理的。事件研究分析表明,WorldCom的重报给竞争对手运营商和电信设备制造商造成的损失为78亿美元。世通的虚假或欺诈性陈述也为州和联邦政府提供了制定电信政策所必需的不正确信息。因此,州和联邦政府、法院和监管委员会有理由对世通未来的陈述持极端怀疑态度。第四部分解释了世通的欺诈和破产可能是为了损害竞争,并且在未来可能会这样做,通过诱导公司的竞争对手退出(或没收市场份额)。世通公司在互联网流量预测和财务表现方面一再欺骗投资者、竞争对手和监管机构。至少,WorldCom的欺诈性或虚假陈述可能通过诱导低效的产能投资或低效的客户获取支出来提高竞争对手的成本,并可能人为地降低WorldCom的资本成本,从而促进其长期的收购。在破产前的那段时间里,世通的商业策略可能旨在损害互联网主干或长途服务的竞争对手。由于世通的实际成本是未知的,其互联网骨干服务的定价与成本无关。作为世通貌似有理的掠夺行为的条件,弥补损失是不必要的,因为其管理层有其他的个人获利方式。世通管理层、投资银行家和审计人员的协调行动可能损害了电信业的竞争。第五部分认为,联邦通信委员会有一项独特的义务——不同于破产法庭或证券交易委员会的授权——调查世界通信公司的不当行为对电信业的影响。对世界通信公司来说,根据破产法第11章破产可能是扭曲长途和互联网主干市场竞争的一种手段。由于破产法第11章的目的不是根除反竞争的商业模式,也不是为电信基础设施制定政策,所以联邦通信委员会是唯一有权捍卫竞争过程的机构。根据破产法第11章进行重组后,世界通信摆脱了债务,这将使该公司能够以低于世界通信效率甚至更高的竞争对手的价格收购世界通信。经济效率将受到影响,因为消费者支付的费用将低于提供世通提供的服务所需的真实社会成本。此外,美国破产法院免除世通债务(全部或部分)所赋予世通的竞争优势可能构成违反欧洲共同体条约第87条的国家援助。在第六部分中,我认为世通退出市场不会带来重大的社会成本。作为一家持续经营的公司,世通的价值是值得怀疑的,而其他运营商可能很容易吸收世通的互联网和长途客户。 这篇论文在2003年3月进行了实质性的修订,以分析世界通信公司的欺诈和破产,以及美国联邦通信委员会2003年2月20日决定对强制分拆进行三年一次的审查。迄今为止,政策制定者和学者们未能认识到这些主题是如何相互关联的。美国花了7年时间试图解除对电信业的管制。我们不再处于过渡时期。是时候进行评估了。在这篇文章中,我将讨论三个主题。第一部分讨论的第一个问题是放松管制的行政成本,根据1996年的《电信法》,这一成本大幅增长。第二部分阐述了FCC在制定当地竞争政策时使用竞争者福利标准而不是消费者福利标准的后果。我在其三年期审查中评估了FCC决定的报道特征。有关该决定的新闻稿和声明表明,联邦通信委员会可能最终接受了一种消费者福利的方式,以TELRIC价格强制分拆。然而,围绕FCC决定的杂乱无章的行政程序增加了上诉逆转的可能性。从第三部分开始,我更详细地讨论了世通的欺诈和破产。我对世通的欺诈和破产给电信业带来的危害进行了初步评估。我解释了世通的不当行为是如何给其他电信公司、政府、员工和资本市场造成附带损害的。世通虚假的互联网流量报告和会计欺诈鼓励了对长途容量和互联网骨干容量的过度投资。由于互联网流量数据是专有的,而WorldCom主导着互联网骨干服务,而且WorldCom受监管监督,竞争对手相信WorldCom对互联网流量增长的虚假陈述是合理的。事件研究分析表明,WorldCom的重报给竞争对手运营商和电信设备制造商造成的损失为78亿美元。世通的虚假或欺诈性陈述也为州和联邦政府提供了制定电信政策所必需的不正确信息。因此,州和联邦政府、法院和监管委员会有理由对世通未来的陈述持极端怀疑态度。第四部分解释了世通的欺诈和破产可能是为了损害竞争,并且在未来可能会这样做,通过诱导公司的竞争对手退出(或没收市场份额)。世通公司在互联网流量预测和财务表现方面一再欺骗投资者、竞争对手和监管机构。至少,WorldCom的欺诈性或虚假陈述可能通过诱导低效的产能投资或低效的客户获取支出来提高竞争对手的成本,并可能人为地降低WorldCom的资本成本,从而促进其长期的收购。在破产前的那段时间里,世通的商业策略可能旨在损害互联网主干或长途服务的竞争对手。由于世通的实际成本是未知的,其互联网骨干服务的定价与成本无关。作为世通貌似有理的掠夺行为的条件,弥补损失是不必要的,因为其管理层有其他的个人获利方式。世通管理层、投资银行家和审计人员的协调行动可能损害了电信业的竞争。第五部分认为,联邦通信委员会有一项独特的义务——不同于破产法庭或证券交易委员会的授权——调查世界通信公司的不当行为对电信业的影响。对世界通信公司来说,根据破产法第11章破产可能是扭曲长途和互联网主干市场竞争的一种手段。由于破产法第11章的目的不是根除反竞争的商业模式,也不是为电信基础设施制定政策,所以联邦通信委员会是唯一有权捍卫竞争过程的机构。根据破产法第11章进行重组后,世界通信摆脱了债务,这将使该公司能够以低于世界通信效率甚至更高的竞争对手的价格收购世界通信。经济效率将受到影响,因为消费者支付的费用将低于提供世通提供的服务所需的真实社会成本。此外,美国破产法院免除世通债务(全部或部分)所赋予世通的竞争优势可能构成违反欧洲共同体条约第87条的国家援助。在第六部分中,我认为世通退出市场不会带来重大的社会成本。作为一家持续经营的公司,世通的价值是值得怀疑的,而其他运营商可能很容易吸收世通的互联网和长途客户。 美国联邦通信委员会应该调查世通欺诈对电信政策的影响。调查结果可能包括发现世通没有资格持有其FCC许可证和授权。这一法律结论将迅速而恰当地推动世通走向清算。 美国联邦通信委员会应该调查世通欺诈对电信政策的影响。调查结果可能包括发现世通没有资格持有
{"title":"The Failure of Good Intentions: The WorldCom Fraud and the Collapse of American Telecommunications After Deregulation","authors":"J., Gregory Sidakt","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.335180","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.335180","url":null,"abstract":"This paper was substantially revised in March 2003 to analyze WorldCom's fraud and bankruptcy and the FCC's February 20, 2003 decision its Triennial Review of mandatory unbundling. To date, policymakers and scholars have failed to recognize how those topics are interrelated. The United States has spent seven years trying to deregulate telecommunications. We are not in the transition any longer. It is time to take stock. In this essay, I address three topics. The first, addressed in Part I, is the administrative cost of deregulation, which has grown substantially under the Telecommunications Act of 1996.Part II addresses the consequences of the FCC's use of a competitor-welfare standard when formulating its policies for local competition, rather than a consumer-welfare standard. I evaluate the reported features of the FCC's decision in its Triennial Review. Press releases and statements concerning that decision suggest that the FCC may have finally embraced a consumer-welfare approach to mandatory unbundling at TELRIC prices. The haphazard administrative process surrounding the FCC's decision, however, increases the likelihood of reversal on appeal.Beginning in Part III, I address at greater length the WorldCom fraud and bankruptcy. I offer an early assessment of the harm to the telecommunications industry from WorldCom's fraud and bankruptcy. I explain how WorldCom's misconduct caused collateral damage to other telecommunications firms, government, workers, and the capital markets. WorldCom's false Internet traffic reports and accounting fraud encouraged overinvestment in long-distance capacity and Internet backbone capacity. Because Internet traffic data are proprietary and WorldCom dominated Internet backbone services, and because WorldCom was subject to regulatory oversight, it was reasonable for rival carriers to believe WorldCom's misrepresentation of Internet traffic growth. Event study analysis suggests that the harm to rival carriers and telecommunications equipment manufacturers from WorldCom's restatement of earnings was $7.8 billion. WorldCom's false or fraudulent statements also supplied state and federal governments with incorrect information essential to the formulation of telecommunication policy. State and federal governments, courts, and regulatory commissions would thus be justified in applying extreme skepticism to future representations made by WorldCom.Part IV explains how WorldCom's fraud and bankruptcy may have been intended to harm competition, and in the future may do so, by inducing exit (or forfeiture of market share) by the company's rivals. WorldCom repeatedly deceived investors, competitors, and regulators with false statements about its Internet traffic projections and financial performance. At a minimum, WorldCom's fraudulent or false statements may have raised rivals' costs by inducing inefficient investment in capacity or inefficient expenditures for customer acquisition and may have artificially reduced WorldCom","PeriodicalId":46196,"journal":{"name":"Yale Journal on Regulation","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":2.8,"publicationDate":"2002-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.2139/SSRN.335180","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"68587821","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 89
Deregulation and Managed Competition in Network Industries 网络产业的放松管制与管理竞争
IF 2.8 1区 社会学 Q1 Social Sciences Pub Date : 2001-11-06 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.289849
Gregory Sidakt, Daniel F. Spulber
The competitive transformation of telecommunications and other network industries in the United States has caused governmental policy makers to be increasingly concerned with the fairness of the deregulatory process. This Essay offers a set of concrete guidelines that regulators of network industries should follow in removing regulatory controls: To achieve the productive and allocative benefits of competition and to ensure that the transition from regulation to competition is accomplished fairly, regulators should observe the principles of economic incentive, equal opportunity, and impartiality. Economic incentives allow incumbent firms to maintain their quality of service and innovation and investment, and allow them to recover stranded costs for past, present, and future regulatory obligations. Regulators can ensure equal opportunity by ensuring that regulation falls evenly on both competitive entrants and incumbents. Impartiality in increasing competition can be achieved by regulators refraining from market interventions that favor particular competitors. Only by treating incumbents and entrants symmetrically and resisting the temptation to manage competition will the regulators ensure that the deregulatory process in network industries will yield all of the benefits of market competition.
美国电信业和其他网络行业的竞争性转变使政府决策者越来越关注解除管制过程的公平性。本文提供了网络行业监管者在取消监管控制时应遵循的一套具体指导方针:为了实现竞争的生产效益和配置效益,并确保从监管到竞争的过渡是公平完成的,监管者应遵守经济激励、机会平等和公正的原则。经济激励使现有公司能够保持其服务质量、创新和投资,并使它们能够收回过去、现在和未来监管义务的滞留成本。监管机构可以通过确保监管均匀地落在竞争性进入者和现有者身上,来确保机会均等。增加竞争的公正性可以通过监管机构避免偏袒特定竞争者的市场干预来实现。只有对称地对待现有者和进入者,并抵制管理竞争的诱惑,监管机构才能确保网络行业的放松管制过程将产生市场竞争的所有好处。
{"title":"Deregulation and Managed Competition in Network Industries","authors":"Gregory Sidakt, Daniel F. Spulber","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.289849","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.289849","url":null,"abstract":"The competitive transformation of telecommunications and other network industries in the United States has caused governmental policy makers to be increasingly concerned with the fairness of the deregulatory process. This Essay offers a set of concrete guidelines that regulators of network industries should follow in removing regulatory controls: To achieve the productive and allocative benefits of competition and to ensure that the transition from regulation to competition is accomplished fairly, regulators should observe the principles of economic incentive, equal opportunity, and impartiality. Economic incentives allow incumbent firms to maintain their quality of service and innovation and investment, and allow them to recover stranded costs for past, present, and future regulatory obligations. Regulators can ensure equal opportunity by ensuring that regulation falls evenly on both competitive entrants and incumbents. Impartiality in increasing competition can be achieved by regulators refraining from market interventions that favor particular competitors. Only by treating incumbents and entrants symmetrically and resisting the temptation to manage competition will the regulators ensure that the deregulatory process in network industries will yield all of the benefits of market competition.","PeriodicalId":46196,"journal":{"name":"Yale Journal on Regulation","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":2.8,"publicationDate":"2001-11-06","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.2139/SSRN.289849","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"68425006","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 22
The Pricing of Inputs Sold to Competitors 卖给竞争者的投入的定价
IF 2.8 1区 社会学 Q1 Social Sciences Pub Date : 2001-11-02 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.289386
W. Baumol, J. Sidak
Local telephone companies have long been regulated as natural monopolies. However, technological innovation and the prospect of falling regulatory barriers to entry now expose some portions of the local exchange to competition from cable television systems, wireless telephony, and rival wireline systems. Nevertheless, it is probable that certain parts of local telephony will remain naturally monopolistic. In these cases the local exchange carrier must be permitted to sell necessary inputs to its competitors in the market for final telecommunications products at a price that reflects all its costs, including opportunity costs. This essay explains in nontechnical terms the derivation and logic of the efficient component-pricing rule, or ECPR. The authors' analysis applies to any network industry. Thus, it is useful in antitrust analysis of essential facilities and in regulatory analysis of transportation, energy transmission, pipelines, and mail delivery.
本地电话公司长期以来一直被视为自然垄断企业。然而,技术革新和进入监管壁垒下降的前景,现在使地方交换的某些部分面临有线电视系统、无线电话和竞争对手有线系统的竞争。然而,本地电话的某些部分很可能仍然是自然垄断的。在这些情况下,必须允许当地交换运营商以反映其所有成本(包括机会成本)的价格,向其最终电信产品市场上的竞争对手出售必要的投入。本文用非技术术语解释了有效组件定价规则(ECPR)的推导和逻辑。作者的分析适用于任何网络行业。因此,它在基本设施的反垄断分析和运输、能源传输、管道和邮件传递的监管分析中是有用的。
{"title":"The Pricing of Inputs Sold to Competitors","authors":"W. Baumol, J. Sidak","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.289386","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.289386","url":null,"abstract":"Local telephone companies have long been regulated as natural monopolies. However, technological innovation and the prospect of falling regulatory barriers to entry now expose some portions of the local exchange to competition from cable television systems, wireless telephony, and rival wireline systems. Nevertheless, it is probable that certain parts of local telephony will remain naturally monopolistic. In these cases the local exchange carrier must be permitted to sell necessary inputs to its competitors in the market for final telecommunications products at a price that reflects all its costs, including opportunity costs. This essay explains in nontechnical terms the derivation and logic of the efficient component-pricing rule, or ECPR. The authors' analysis applies to any network industry. Thus, it is useful in antitrust analysis of essential facilities and in regulatory analysis of transportation, energy transmission, pipelines, and mail delivery.","PeriodicalId":46196,"journal":{"name":"Yale Journal on Regulation","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":2.8,"publicationDate":"2001-11-02","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"68423698","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 169
Monopoly and the Mandate of Canada Post 垄断和加拿大邮政的授权
IF 2.8 1区 社会学 Q1 Social Sciences Pub Date : 2001-11-02 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.289390
J. Sidak, Daniel F. Spulber
Mail delivery is one of the few economic activities that has avoided the wave of deregulation and privatization that has swept network industries over the last few decades. This Article examines several questions regarding the business activities of Canada Post Corporation in a competitive environment. What should be the appropriate mandate of Canada Post? If Canada Post is a natural monopoly, what form of regulation best serves Canadian consumers? If Canada Post's delivery of letter mail is not a natural monopoly, what basis exists for retaining Canada Post's current statutory monopoly? What potential exists for Canada Post to abuse its statutory monopoly-and other statutory privileges and immunities-to compete unfairly against efficient private suppliers of postal services? Part I of this Article outlines the regulatory and institutional setting in which Canada Post operates, including the nature and extent of Canada Post's legal monopoly. Part II demonstrates why technological justifications for the postal monopoly are no longer valid. Part III establishes that public provisions of the full range of postal services is no longer needed. Part IV explains how postal pricing and regulation can cause competitive problems for private firms because of incorrect measurement and misallocation of attributable costs and because of the potential to misuse Ramsey pricing principles. Part V presents four options that are available to the Canadian Parliament for addressing the problem of protecting efficient competition from the postal monopoly.
在过去几十年席卷网络行业的放松管制和私有化浪潮中,邮件递送是为数不多的几项经济活动之一。本文考察了加拿大邮政公司在竞争环境下的商业活动的几个问题。加拿大邮政的适当任务是什么?如果加拿大邮政是一个自然垄断,什么样的监管形式最适合加拿大的消费者?如果加拿大邮政的信件递送业务不是自然垄断,那么加拿大邮政保留其法定垄断地位的依据是什么?加拿大邮政滥用其法定垄断地位——以及其他法定特权和豁免权——与高效的私人邮政服务供应商进行不公平竞争的可能性有多大?本文第一部分概述了加拿大邮政运作的监管和机构设置,包括加拿大邮政合法垄断的性质和程度。第二部分说明了为什么邮政垄断的技术理由不再有效。第三部分规定不再需要公共提供全面的邮政服务。第四部分解释了邮政定价和监管如何由于可归属成本的不正确计量和分配不当以及滥用拉姆齐定价原则的可能性而导致私营公司的竞争问题。第五部分提出了加拿大议会可用于解决保护有效竞争免受邮政垄断的问题的四种选择。
{"title":"Monopoly and the Mandate of Canada Post","authors":"J. Sidak, Daniel F. Spulber","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.289390","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.289390","url":null,"abstract":"Mail delivery is one of the few economic activities that has avoided the wave of deregulation and privatization that has swept network industries over the last few decades. This Article examines several questions regarding the business activities of Canada Post Corporation in a competitive environment. What should be the appropriate mandate of Canada Post? If Canada Post is a natural monopoly, what form of regulation best serves Canadian consumers? If Canada Post's delivery of letter mail is not a natural monopoly, what basis exists for retaining Canada Post's current statutory monopoly? What potential exists for Canada Post to abuse its statutory monopoly-and other statutory privileges and immunities-to compete unfairly against efficient private suppliers of postal services? Part I of this Article outlines the regulatory and institutional setting in which Canada Post operates, including the nature and extent of Canada Post's legal monopoly. Part II demonstrates why technological justifications for the postal monopoly are no longer valid. Part III establishes that public provisions of the full range of postal services is no longer needed. Part IV explains how postal pricing and regulation can cause competitive problems for private firms because of incorrect measurement and misallocation of attributable costs and because of the potential to misuse Ramsey pricing principles. Part V presents four options that are available to the Canadian Parliament for addressing the problem of protecting efficient competition from the postal monopoly.","PeriodicalId":46196,"journal":{"name":"Yale Journal on Regulation","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":2.8,"publicationDate":"2001-11-02","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.2139/SSRN.289390","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"68423823","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
An Antitrust Rule for Software Integration 软件集成的反垄断规则
IF 2.8 1区 社会学 Q1 Social Sciences Pub Date : 2001-04-30 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.268508
J. Sidak
What is the proper legal standard for product integration involving software? Because software is subject to low marginal costs, network effects, and rapid technological innovation, the Supreme Court's existing antitrust rules on tying arrangements, which evolved from industries not possessing such characteristics, are inappropriate. In this Article, I ask why firms integrate software products. Next, I review the Supreme Court's tying decisions in Jefferson Parish and Eastman Kodak. I propose an approach to judging the lawfulness of product integration in technologically dynamic markets that supplements the Supreme Court's current standard with four additional steps in cases of tying of computer software. Thereafter, I examine the D.C. Circuit's approach to software integration, which arose from that court's 1998 interpretation, in Microsoft II, of an antitrust consent decree between the U.S. Department of Justice and Microsoft Corporation. I argue that the D.C. Circuit's rule has general applicability and should be recognized as the appropriate standard for software integration under antitrust law. I show how my approach imparts greater clarity to the D.C. Circuit's rule. I examine the competing product integration rule proposed in 2000 by Professor Lawrence Lessig as amicus curiae in the government's subsequent antitrust case against Microsoft, concerning the integration of Internet Explorer and Windows 98. My approach enables Professor Lessig's analysis to be reconciled with the D.C. Circuit's rule, but Professor Lessig's rule, on its own, would contain serious shortcomings. Thereafter, I evaluate Judge Thomas Penfield Jackson's April 2000 findings of law on the integration of Internet Explorer and Windows 98. I conclude that Judge Jackson's approach, in contrast to the D.C. Circuit's rule as refined by my approach, would harm consumers in the technologically dynamic market for computer software.
涉及软件的产品集成的适当法律标准是什么?由于软件受低边际成本、网络效应和快速技术创新的影响,最高法院现有的关于捆绑安排的反垄断规则是不合适的,这些规则是从不具备这些特征的行业演变而来的。在这篇文章中,我问为什么公司集成软件产品。接下来,我将回顾最高法院对杰斐逊教区和伊士曼柯达案的判决。我提出了一种在技术动态市场中判断产品整合合法性的方法,该方法补充了最高法院目前的标准,在计算机软件捆绑案件中增加了四个步骤。此后,我考察了华盛顿特区巡回法院处理软件集成的方法,该方法源于该法院1998年对微软二案的解释,即美国司法部与微软公司之间的反垄断同意令。我认为,华盛顿特区巡回法院的规则具有普遍的适用性,应该被认为是反垄断法下软件集成的适当标准。我展示了我的方法如何使华盛顿特区巡回法院的规则更加清晰。我研究了2000年劳伦斯·莱西格教授提出的竞争性产品整合规则,该规则在政府随后针对微软的反垄断案中作为法庭之友提出,涉及Internet Explorer和Windows 98的整合。我的方法使莱西格教授的分析与华盛顿特区巡回法院的裁决相一致,但莱西格教授的裁决本身就存在严重的缺陷。此后,我将评价法官托马斯·彭菲尔德·杰克逊2000年4月关于Internet Explorer和Windows 98整合的法律发现。我的结论是,与经我的方法改进的华盛顿特区巡回法院的规则相反,杰克逊法官的做法会损害计算机软件技术动态市场中的消费者。
{"title":"An Antitrust Rule for Software Integration","authors":"J. Sidak","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.268508","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.268508","url":null,"abstract":"What is the proper legal standard for product integration involving software? Because software is subject to low marginal costs, network effects, and rapid technological innovation, the Supreme Court's existing antitrust rules on tying arrangements, which evolved from industries not possessing such characteristics, are inappropriate. In this Article, I ask why firms integrate software products. Next, I review the Supreme Court's tying decisions in Jefferson Parish and Eastman Kodak. I propose an approach to judging the lawfulness of product integration in technologically dynamic markets that supplements the Supreme Court's current standard with four additional steps in cases of tying of computer software. Thereafter, I examine the D.C. Circuit's approach to software integration, which arose from that court's 1998 interpretation, in Microsoft II, of an antitrust consent decree between the U.S. Department of Justice and Microsoft Corporation. I argue that the D.C. Circuit's rule has general applicability and should be recognized as the appropriate standard for software integration under antitrust law. I show how my approach imparts greater clarity to the D.C. Circuit's rule. I examine the competing product integration rule proposed in 2000 by Professor Lawrence Lessig as amicus curiae in the government's subsequent antitrust case against Microsoft, concerning the integration of Internet Explorer and Windows 98. My approach enables Professor Lessig's analysis to be reconciled with the D.C. Circuit's rule, but Professor Lessig's rule, on its own, would contain serious shortcomings. Thereafter, I evaluate Judge Thomas Penfield Jackson's April 2000 findings of law on the integration of Internet Explorer and Windows 98. I conclude that Judge Jackson's approach, in contrast to the D.C. Circuit's rule as refined by my approach, would harm consumers in the technologically dynamic market for computer software.","PeriodicalId":46196,"journal":{"name":"Yale Journal on Regulation","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":2.8,"publicationDate":"2001-04-30","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"68254702","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 17
期刊
Yale Journal on Regulation
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1