首页 > 最新文献

Economics of Governance最新文献

英文 中文
Balance of power in a conflict model 冲突模式中的权力平衡
IF 0.9 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-08-30 DOI: 10.1007/s10101-024-00318-8
Ryota Tsuchiya

This study provides a microeconomic foundation for the bipolar stability hypothesis in international politics. It extends the well-designed conflict model of Esteban and Ray (Am Econ Rev 101(4):1345–1374, 2011) to include monetary compensation arrangements between the winning and losing groups, presenting a new conflict-related indicator called the balance of power index. The main finding of this study is that societal polarization serves to alleviate rather than exacerbate conflict intensity, which is elucidated by the balance of power index. This new characteristic of polarization is associated with the founding of the bipolar stability hypothesis by Waltz (J Int Affairs 21(2):215–231, 1967), Waltz (Theory of international politics. Addison-Wesley Publishing Company, Reading, 1979) under the economic behavioral model.

本研究为国际政治中的两极稳定假说提供了微观经济学基础。它扩展了埃斯特班和雷(Am Econ Rev 101(4):1345-1374,2011 年)精心设计的冲突模型,将胜败双方的货币补偿安排纳入其中,提出了一个与冲突相关的新指标--均势指数。本研究的主要发现是,社会两极分化会缓解而非加剧冲突强度,这一点已被权力平衡指数所阐明。两极分化的这一新特征与华尔兹(J Int Affairs 21(2):215-231, 1967)、华尔兹(Theory of international politics.Addison-Wesley Publishing Company,Reading,1979)在经济行为模式下提出的。
{"title":"Balance of power in a conflict model","authors":"Ryota Tsuchiya","doi":"10.1007/s10101-024-00318-8","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1007/s10101-024-00318-8","url":null,"abstract":"<p>This study provides a microeconomic foundation for the bipolar stability hypothesis in international politics. It extends the well-designed conflict model of Esteban and Ray (Am Econ Rev 101(4):1345–1374, 2011) to include monetary compensation arrangements between the winning and losing groups, presenting a new conflict-related indicator called the balance of power index. The main finding of this study is that societal polarization serves to alleviate rather than exacerbate conflict intensity, which is elucidated by the balance of power index. This new characteristic of polarization is associated with the founding of the bipolar stability hypothesis by Waltz (J Int Affairs 21(2):215–231, 1967), Waltz (Theory of international politics. Addison-Wesley Publishing Company, Reading, 1979) under the economic behavioral model.</p>","PeriodicalId":46302,"journal":{"name":"Economics of Governance","volume":"62 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.9,"publicationDate":"2024-08-30","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"142224270","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Skimming the achieved? Quantifying the fiscal incentives of the German fiscal equalization scheme and its reforms since 1970 攫取成果?量化自 1970 年以来德国财政均衡计划及其改革的财政激励措施
IF 0.9 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-08-19 DOI: 10.1007/s10101-024-00316-w
Yannick Bury, Lars P. Feld, Heiko T. Burret

Marginal rates of contribution (MRC), i.e., the rates at which additional revenues are skimmed via larger contributions or lower transfer receipts, quantify the incentives of a fiscal equalization scheme. This paper is the first to calculate marginal rates of contribution for the Laender (states) in the German fiscal equalization scheme for each of the 51 years since its establishment in 1970 and over five major reforms, taking into account all relevant revenues. Our results show that MRC have been at a consistently high level. Until 2019 the scheme induced an almost full skimming of additional tax revenues of recipient states. With the system’s latest reform in 2020, MRC increased further. Recipient states now face an over-skimming of additional tax revenues and, thus, massive fiscal disincentives to maintain their own tax base. While these findings have been widely expected, comprehensive evidence has been missing so far.

边际缴款率(MRC),即通过增加缴款或减少转移性收入榨取额外收入的比率,量化了财政均衡计划的激励机制。本文首次计算了德国财政均衡计划自 1970 年建立以来 51 年中每年以及五次重大改革中各州的边际贡献率,并考虑了所有相关收入。我们的研究结果表明,MRC 一直处于较高水平。直到 2019 年,该计划几乎完全榨取了受援国的额外税收。随着 2020 年制度的最新改革,多边减让协定进一步增加。受援国现在面临着额外税收收入被过度榨取的问题,因此在维持本国税基方面面临着巨大的财政抑制。虽然这些发现已被广泛预期,但至今仍缺乏全面的证据。
{"title":"Skimming the achieved? Quantifying the fiscal incentives of the German fiscal equalization scheme and its reforms since 1970","authors":"Yannick Bury, Lars P. Feld, Heiko T. Burret","doi":"10.1007/s10101-024-00316-w","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1007/s10101-024-00316-w","url":null,"abstract":"<p>Marginal rates of contribution (MRC), i.e., the rates at which additional revenues are skimmed via larger contributions or lower transfer receipts, quantify the incentives of a fiscal equalization scheme. This paper is the first to calculate marginal rates of contribution for the Laender (states) in the German fiscal equalization scheme for each of the 51 years since its establishment in 1970 and over five major reforms, taking into account all relevant revenues. Our results show that MRC have been at a consistently high level. Until 2019 the scheme induced an almost full skimming of additional tax revenues of recipient states. With the system’s latest reform in 2020, MRC increased further. Recipient states now face an over-skimming of additional tax revenues and, thus, massive fiscal disincentives to maintain their own tax base. While these findings have been widely expected, comprehensive evidence has been missing so far.</p>","PeriodicalId":46302,"journal":{"name":"Economics of Governance","volume":"24 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.9,"publicationDate":"2024-08-19","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"142185294","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Predicting satisfaction with democracy in Germany using local economic conditions, social capital, and individual characteristics 利用当地经济条件、社会资本和个人特征预测德国的民主满意度
IF 0.9 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-08-12 DOI: 10.1007/s10101-024-00315-x
Tim Friehe, Christian Pfeifer

This paper explores the empirical relationship between local economic conditions, social capital, and individual characteristics on the one hand and satisfaction with democracy on the other hand, using detailed information from the German Socio-Economic Panel. In contrast to previous literature, we focus on economic conditions at the state level instead of the national one. We find that local economic conditions, proxies of social capital, and individual characteristics (e.g., risk attitude, reciprocity, past unemployment experience) are important correlates of satisfaction with democracy and that some heterogeneity between genders, West and East Germany, and people with and without college degree exists in the data.

本文利用德国社会经济小组(German Socio-Economics Panel)的详细信息,探讨了地方经济条件、社会资本和个人特征与民主满意度之间的经验关系。与以往文献不同的是,我们关注的是州一级的经济状况,而不是国家一级的经济状况。我们发现,地方经济条件、社会资本的代用指标和个人特征(如风险态度、互惠性、过去的失业经历)是民主满意度的重要相关因素,而且数据中存在性别、西德和东德、有大学学位和没有大学学位的人之间的一些异质性。
{"title":"Predicting satisfaction with democracy in Germany using local economic conditions, social capital, and individual characteristics","authors":"Tim Friehe, Christian Pfeifer","doi":"10.1007/s10101-024-00315-x","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1007/s10101-024-00315-x","url":null,"abstract":"<p>This paper explores the empirical relationship between local economic conditions, social capital, and individual characteristics on the one hand and satisfaction with democracy on the other hand, using detailed information from the German Socio-Economic Panel. In contrast to previous literature, we focus on economic conditions at the <i>state</i> level instead of the <i>national</i> one. We find that local economic conditions, proxies of social capital, and individual characteristics (e.g., risk attitude, reciprocity, past unemployment experience) are important correlates of satisfaction with democracy and that some heterogeneity between genders, West and East Germany, and people with and without college degree exists in the data.</p>","PeriodicalId":46302,"journal":{"name":"Economics of Governance","volume":"180 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.9,"publicationDate":"2024-08-12","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"142224271","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Environmental policy implementation, gender, and corruption 环境政策的实施、性别与腐败
IF 0.9 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-06-04 DOI: 10.1007/s10101-024-00314-y
Nabamita Dutta, Saibal Kar, Israt Jahan

Beneficial influence of female representation in implementing environment-friendly policies have been documented in recent studies. However, presence of factors such as corruption and bureaucratic red tapes, known to hinder development initiatives, raises question about whether women legislators can achieve the desired level of success with environmental policies. Based on our empirical analysis using cross-sectional data for 83 countries, we find evidence that the positive impact of women in parliament on climate change policy outcomes is significant and most effective for countries with low levels of corruption. Depending on the model specification used, ranging from instrumental variable regressions to inclusion of controls to mitigate omitted variable bias, and matching models, we do find that the beneficial impact of women in parliament becomes insignificant and eventually might become negative with rising corruption. Thus, while women might be able to successfully propose a bill for and turn-into-law, environment-friendly policies in countries with low levels of corruption, the effort is nullified and might be reversed in case of countries with high corruption. We illustrate that the results are sensitive to model selection, and choice of controls.

最近的研究表明,女性代表在实施环境友好型政策方面具有有利影响。然而,众所周知,腐败和官僚作风等因素会阻碍发展计划的实施,因此,女性立法者能否在环境政策方面取得预期的成功令人怀疑。根据我们使用 83 个国家的横截面数据进行的实证分析,我们发现有证据表明,女性议员对气候变化政策结果的积极影响是显著的,而且对腐败程度低的国家最为有效。根据所使用的模型规范,包括工具变量回归、纳入控制以减少遗漏变量偏差以及匹配模型等,我们确实发现,随着腐败程度的上升,女性在议会中的有利影响变得不显著,最终可能变成负面影响。因此,在腐败程度较低的国家,女性可能能够成功地提出环境友好型政策的议案并使之成为法律,但在腐败程度较高的国家,这种努力就会化为乌有,甚至出现逆转。我们说明,结果对模型选择和控制方法的选择很敏感。
{"title":"Environmental policy implementation, gender, and corruption","authors":"Nabamita Dutta, Saibal Kar, Israt Jahan","doi":"10.1007/s10101-024-00314-y","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1007/s10101-024-00314-y","url":null,"abstract":"<p>Beneficial influence of female representation in implementing environment-friendly policies have been documented in recent studies. However, presence of factors such as corruption and bureaucratic red tapes, known to hinder development initiatives, raises question about whether women legislators can achieve the desired level of success with environmental policies. Based on our empirical analysis using cross-sectional data for 83 countries, we find evidence that the positive impact of women in parliament on climate change policy outcomes is <i>significant and most effective</i> for countries with low levels of corruption. Depending on the model specification used, ranging from instrumental variable regressions to inclusion of controls to mitigate omitted variable bias, and matching models, we do find that the beneficial impact of women in parliament becomes insignificant and eventually might become negative with rising corruption. Thus, while women might be able to successfully propose a bill for and turn-into-law, environment-friendly policies in countries with low levels of corruption, the effort is nullified and might be reversed in case of countries with high corruption. We illustrate that the results are sensitive to model selection, and choice of controls.</p>","PeriodicalId":46302,"journal":{"name":"Economics of Governance","volume":"181 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.9,"publicationDate":"2024-06-04","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"141252115","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Preferences for social insurance: the role of job security and risk propensity 对社会保险的偏好:工作保障和风险倾向的作用
IF 0.9 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-06-03 DOI: 10.1007/s10101-024-00313-z
Mauricio Bugarin, Yasushi Hazama

In a 2003 article, Karl Moene (University of Oslo) and Michael Wallerstein (Yale University) demonstrated that wealthier citizens tend to support higher spending in social policies directed at the unemployed, while preferring lower spending in policies aimed at the employed. This paper reveals that these findings hinge on two key assumptions: that citizens have a coefficient of relative risk aversion (CRRA) greater than one, and that all citizens face an equal probability of job loss—a presumption which is not necessarily realistic. By incorporating the observation that job security tends to correlate positively with income, we demonstrate that affluent individuals may still advocate for reduced spending in unemployment policies, even when their CRRA exceeds one. Moreover, a significant shift in the distribution of job security—such as during an abrupt economic crisis—might engender greater societal support for these policies, contrary to their previous research. Finally, empirical data from recent Brazilian history provide analytical support for the theoretical assertions presented herein.

在 2003 年的一篇文章中,Karl Moene(奥斯陆大学)和 Michael Wallerstein(耶鲁大学)证明,较富裕的公民倾向于支持在针对失业者的社会政策中增加支出,而在针对就业者的政策中倾向于减少支出。本文揭示了这些结论取决于两个关键假设:公民的相对风险规避系数(CRRA)大于 1,以及所有公民面临失业的概率相同--这一假设并不一定现实。通过将工作保障往往与收入呈正相关的观察结果结合起来,我们证明,即使富裕的个人的相对风险规避系数超过 1,他们仍然可能主张减少失业政策的支出。此外,就业保障分布的重大变化--例如在突如其来的经济危机期间--可能会使这些政策获得更大的社会支持,这与他们之前的研究相反。最后,巴西近代史的经验数据为本文的理论论断提供了分析支持。
{"title":"Preferences for social insurance: the role of job security and risk propensity","authors":"Mauricio Bugarin, Yasushi Hazama","doi":"10.1007/s10101-024-00313-z","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1007/s10101-024-00313-z","url":null,"abstract":"<p>In a 2003 article, Karl Moene (University of Oslo) and Michael Wallerstein (Yale University) demonstrated that wealthier citizens tend to support higher spending in social policies directed at the unemployed, while preferring lower spending in policies aimed at the employed. This paper reveals that these findings hinge on two key assumptions: that citizens have a coefficient of relative risk aversion (CRRA) greater than one, and that all citizens face an equal probability of job loss—a presumption which is not necessarily realistic. By incorporating the observation that job security tends to correlate positively with income, we demonstrate that affluent individuals may still advocate for reduced spending in unemployment policies, even when their CRRA exceeds one. Moreover, a significant shift in the distribution of job security—such as during an abrupt economic crisis—might engender greater societal support for these policies, contrary to their previous research. Finally, empirical data from recent Brazilian history provide analytical support for the theoretical assertions presented herein.</p>","PeriodicalId":46302,"journal":{"name":"Economics of Governance","volume":"40 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.9,"publicationDate":"2024-06-03","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"141252277","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Can public efficiency increase tax morale? Evidence from 18 Latin American countries 公共效率能否提高纳税士气?来自 18 个拉丁美洲国家的证据
IF 0.9 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-05-04 DOI: 10.1007/s10101-024-00312-0
Víctor Mauricio Castañeda-Rodríguez, Gaetano Lisi

By increasing trust in institutions, public efficiency could be a further key determinant of tax morale. Public efficiency is closely related to the concept of productive public spending, while total public spending also depends on government ideology. In a society where public efficiency and tax morale are high, a virtuous “tax circle” can be triggered since government can increase both tax revenues and productive public spending. Using the Latinobarometer wave (which includes 20,204 interviewees from 18 Latin American countries), the empirical analysis finds that public efficiency would have to increase significantly before its marginal effect on tax morale becomes positive. Hence, the virtuous “tax circle” can trigger in the long term. However, the cross-sectional analysis cannot highlight the potentially significant role of ideological motives, so robustness checks are performed to show that our results are neither driven by such motives nor by the multilevel structure of the dataset or by the sample distribution.

通过提高对机构的信任,公共效率可以进一步成为税收士气的关键决定因素。公共效率与生产性公共支出的概念密切相关,而公共支出总额也取决于政府的意识形态。在一个公共效率和纳税士气都很高的社会,由于政府可以同时增加税收和生产性公共开支,因此可以引发良性的 "税收循环"。利用拉丁美洲晴雨表(Latinobarometer)的数据(包括来自 18 个拉美国家的 20 204 名受访者),实证分析发现,公共效率必须显著提高,其对税收士气的边际效应才会变为正值。因此,从长期来看,良性 "税收循环 "是可以触发的。然而,横截面分析无法突出意识形态动机的潜在重要作用,因此我们进行了稳健性检验,以表明我们的结果既不是由这些动机驱动的,也不是由数据集的多层次结构或样本分布驱动的。
{"title":"Can public efficiency increase tax morale? Evidence from 18 Latin American countries","authors":"Víctor Mauricio Castañeda-Rodríguez, Gaetano Lisi","doi":"10.1007/s10101-024-00312-0","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1007/s10101-024-00312-0","url":null,"abstract":"<p>By increasing trust in institutions, public efficiency could be a further key determinant of tax morale. Public efficiency is closely related to the concept of productive public spending, while total public spending also depends on government ideology. In a society where public efficiency and tax morale are high, a virtuous “tax circle” can be triggered since government can increase both tax revenues and productive public spending. Using the Latinobarometer wave (which includes 20,204 interviewees from 18 Latin American countries), the empirical analysis finds that public efficiency would have to increase significantly before its marginal effect on tax morale becomes positive. Hence, the virtuous “tax circle” can trigger in the long term. However, the cross-sectional analysis cannot highlight the potentially significant role of ideological motives, so robustness checks are performed to show that our results are neither driven by such motives nor by the multilevel structure of the dataset or by the sample distribution.</p>","PeriodicalId":46302,"journal":{"name":"Economics of Governance","volume":"31 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.9,"publicationDate":"2024-05-04","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"140888789","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Governance and state-owned enterprises: how costly is corruption? 治理与国有企业:腐败的代价有多高?
IF 0.9 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-04-20 DOI: 10.1007/s10101-024-00311-1
Anja Baum, Clay Hacknay, Paulo Medas, Mouhamadou Sy

State-owned enterprises (SOEs) are present in key sectors of economies around the world. While they can provide an important public service, there is widespread concern that their activities and financial performance are hindered by corruption. In the meantime, cross-country analysis on the cost of corruption for SOEs remains scarce. We present new cross-country evidence on how corruption affects SOE performance using firm level data. We find that SOEs perform as well as private firms in core sectors when corruption is low but are significantly less efficient when corruption is high. We also show that, in turn, improvements in fiscal transparency and specific SOE governance reforms have the potential to improve SOE performance.

国有企业(SOEs)遍布全球各经济体的关键部门。虽然它们可以提供重要的公共服务,但人们普遍担心它们的活动和财务业绩会受到腐败的阻碍。与此同时,有关国有企业腐败成本的跨国分析仍然很少。我们利用公司层面的数据,就腐败如何影响国有企业绩效提供了新的跨国证据。我们发现,当腐败程度较低时,国有企业在核心部门的表现与私营企业一样好,但当腐败程度较高时,国有企业的效率就会明显降低。我们还表明,反过来,提高财政透明度和具体的国有企业治理改革也有可能提高国有企业的绩效。
{"title":"Governance and state-owned enterprises: how costly is corruption?","authors":"Anja Baum, Clay Hacknay, Paulo Medas, Mouhamadou Sy","doi":"10.1007/s10101-024-00311-1","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1007/s10101-024-00311-1","url":null,"abstract":"<p>State-owned enterprises (SOEs) are present in key sectors of economies around the world. While they can provide an important public service, there is widespread concern that their activities and financial performance are hindered by corruption. In the meantime, cross-country analysis on the cost of corruption for SOEs remains scarce. We present new cross-country evidence on how corruption affects SOE performance using firm level data. We find that SOEs perform as well as private firms in core sectors when corruption is low but are significantly less efficient when corruption is high. We also show that, in turn, improvements in fiscal transparency and specific SOE governance reforms have the potential to improve SOE performance.</p>","PeriodicalId":46302,"journal":{"name":"Economics of Governance","volume":"46 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.9,"publicationDate":"2024-04-20","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"140624159","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Ideological ambiguity and political spectrum 意识形态的模糊性和政治光谱
IF 0.9 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-03-19 DOI: 10.1007/s10101-024-00310-2
Hector Galindo-Silva

This study examines the relationship between ambiguity and the ideological positioning of political parties across the political spectrum. We identify a strong non-monotonic (inverted U-shaped) relationship between party ideology and ambiguity within a sample of 202 European political parties. This pattern is observed across all ideological dimensions covered in the data. To explain this pattern, we argue that centrist parties are perceived as less risky by voters compared to extremist parties, giving them an advantage in employing ambiguity to attract more voters at a lower cost. We support our explanation with additional evidence from electoral outcomes and economic indicators in the respective party countries.

本研究探讨了模糊性与各政治派别政党意识形态定位之间的关系。在 202 个欧洲政党样本中,我们发现政党意识形态与模糊性之间存在强烈的非单调关系(倒 U 型)。这种模式在数据所涵盖的所有意识形态维度中都能观察到。为了解释这种模式,我们认为,与极端主义政党相比,中间派政党被选民认为风险较小,因此它们在利用模糊性以较低成本吸引更多选民方面具有优势。我们从各政党所在国家的选举结果和经济指标中获得了更多证据来支持我们的解释。
{"title":"Ideological ambiguity and political spectrum","authors":"Hector Galindo-Silva","doi":"10.1007/s10101-024-00310-2","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1007/s10101-024-00310-2","url":null,"abstract":"<p>This study examines the relationship between ambiguity and the ideological positioning of political parties across the political spectrum. We identify a strong non-monotonic (inverted U-shaped) relationship between party ideology and ambiguity within a sample of 202 European political parties. This pattern is observed across all ideological dimensions covered in the data. To explain this pattern, we argue that centrist parties are perceived as less risky by voters compared to extremist parties, giving them an advantage in employing ambiguity to attract more voters at a lower cost. We support our explanation with additional evidence from electoral outcomes and economic indicators in the respective party countries.</p>","PeriodicalId":46302,"journal":{"name":"Economics of Governance","volume":"67 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.9,"publicationDate":"2024-03-19","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"140204432","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
When does government debt make people happier? Evidence from panel data of 125 countries 政府债务何时让人们更幸福?来自 125 个国家面板数据的证据
IF 0.9 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-02-20 DOI: 10.1007/s10101-024-00309-9
Haejo Kang, Dong-Eun Rhee

This study utilizes panel data from 125 countries spanning 2005–2015 to empirically examine the impact of government debt on country-level subjective well-being. The fixed effect model results show that an increase in the government debt-to-GDP ratio significantly reduces subjective well-being in countries with low governance quality. However, this negative effect of government debt on happiness is substantially offset in countries exhibiting governance quality above the median value. The main result is robust to controlling for various sources of government debt. Moreover, we find that under certain conditions, such as high levels of government effectiveness, rule of law, or strong control of corruption, an increase in government debt is positively associated with people’s subjective well-being. In addition, the positive effect of government debt on country-level happiness is also observed in high-income countries with high governance quality. Our results suggest that it is not government debt itself that influences citizens' happiness levels, but rather how this debt is managed and the degree of trust citizens place in their government.

本研究利用 2005-2015 年间 125 个国家的面板数据,实证检验了政府债务对国家层面主观幸福感的影响。固定效应模型的结果表明,在治理质量较低的国家,政府债务与国内生产总值之比增加会显著降低主观幸福感。然而,在治理质量高于中位值的国家,政府债务对幸福感的负面影响被大大抵消。在控制了政府债务的各种来源后,主要结果是稳健的。此外,我们还发现,在某些条件下,如高水平的政府效率、法治或对腐败的有力控制,政府债务的增加与人们的主观幸福感呈正相关。此外,在治理质量高的高收入国家,也能观察到政府债务对国家层面幸福感的积极影响。我们的研究结果表明,影响公民幸福水平的不是政府债务本身,而是如何管理这些债务以及公民对政府的信任程度。
{"title":"When does government debt make people happier? Evidence from panel data of 125 countries","authors":"Haejo Kang, Dong-Eun Rhee","doi":"10.1007/s10101-024-00309-9","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1007/s10101-024-00309-9","url":null,"abstract":"<p>This study utilizes panel data from 125 countries spanning 2005–2015 to empirically examine the impact of government debt on country-level subjective well-being. The fixed effect model results show that an increase in the government debt-to-GDP ratio significantly reduces subjective well-being in countries with low governance quality. However, this negative effect of government debt on happiness is substantially offset in countries exhibiting governance quality above the median value. The main result is robust to controlling for various sources of government debt. Moreover, we find that under certain conditions, such as high levels of government effectiveness, rule of law, or strong control of corruption, an increase in government debt is positively associated with people’s subjective well-being. In addition, the positive effect of government debt on country-level happiness is also observed in high-income countries with high governance quality. Our results suggest that it is not government debt itself that influences citizens' happiness levels, but rather how this debt is managed and the degree of trust citizens place in their government.</p>","PeriodicalId":46302,"journal":{"name":"Economics of Governance","volume":"1 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.9,"publicationDate":"2024-02-20","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"139909819","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Legislative redistricting and the partisan distribution of transportation expenditure 立法机构重新划分与交通支出的党派分布
IF 0.9 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-02-06 DOI: 10.1007/s10101-024-00308-w
Walter Melnik

I show that a state representative’s political party determines transportation expenditure in the area she represents. Previous studies of this topic consider party changes through election outcomes, which may be correlated with unobservable determinants of expenditure. To overcome this issue, I identify my estimates using Ohio’s 2012 state legislative redistricting, which moved many geographic areas into districts with opposite party incumbents. The Republican party controlled the state legislature and governorship over the period I study. I find that areas moving from governing party Republican to minority party Democratic districts received $3.4M (0.18 standard deviations) less annual highway construction funding than areas remaining in Republican districts. Areas moving from a Democratic to a Republican district, on the other hand, experienced no increase in expenditure—the negative effect of moving to a different representative’s district appears to outweigh the positive effect of a majority party representative. Descriptive evidence suggests that changing representative’s party through redistricting had a different effect on construction funding than changing through an election, underlining the importance of my identification strategy.

我的研究表明,州代表所在的政党决定了她所代表地区的交通支出。以往对这一主题的研究通过选举结果来考虑政党的变化,而选举结果可能与支出的不可观测决定因素相关。为了克服这一问题,我利用俄亥俄州 2012 年的州议会选区重划来确定我的估计值,这次选区重划将许多地理区域划入了有对立党派现任议员的选区。在研究期间,共和党控制了州议会和州长职位。我发现,从执政党共和党选区转到少数党民主党选区的地区每年获得的公路建设资金比留在共和党选区的地区少 340 万美元(0.18 个标准差)。另一方面,从民主党选区转移到共和党选区的地区,支出没有增加--转移到不同代表选区的负面影响似乎超过了多数党代表的正面影响。描述性证据表明,通过重新划分选区改变代表的党派对建设资金的影响与通过选举改变代表的党派对建设资金的影响不同,这凸显了我的识别策略的重要性。
{"title":"Legislative redistricting and the partisan distribution of transportation expenditure","authors":"Walter Melnik","doi":"10.1007/s10101-024-00308-w","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1007/s10101-024-00308-w","url":null,"abstract":"<p>I show that a state representative’s political party determines transportation expenditure in the area she represents. Previous studies of this topic consider party changes through election outcomes, which may be correlated with unobservable determinants of expenditure. To overcome this issue, I identify my estimates using Ohio’s 2012 state legislative redistricting, which moved many geographic areas into districts with opposite party incumbents. The Republican party controlled the state legislature and governorship over the period I study. I find that areas moving from governing party Republican to minority party Democratic districts received $3.4M (0.18 standard deviations) less annual highway construction funding than areas remaining in Republican districts. Areas moving from a Democratic to a Republican district, on the other hand, experienced no increase in expenditure—the negative effect of moving to a different representative’s district appears to outweigh the positive effect of a majority party representative. Descriptive evidence suggests that changing representative’s party through redistricting had a different effect on construction funding than changing through an election, underlining the importance of my identification strategy.</p>","PeriodicalId":46302,"journal":{"name":"Economics of Governance","volume":"16 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.9,"publicationDate":"2024-02-06","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"139764612","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
期刊
Economics of Governance
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1