首页 > 最新文献

Theory and Decision最新文献

英文 中文
Coordinated and uncoordinated punishment in a team investment game 团队投资游戏中的协调和非协调惩罚
IF 0.8 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-02-24 DOI: 10.1007/s11238-024-09977-9
Vicente Calabuig, Natalia Jiménez-Jiménez, Gonzalo Olcina, Ismael Rodriguez-Lara

Coordinated punishment occurs when punishment requires a specific number of punishers to be effective, otherwise, no damage will be inflicted on the target. While societies often rely on this punishment device, its benefits are unclear compared to uncoordinated punishment, where punishment decisions are substitutes. In this paper, we compare the efficacy of coordinated and uncoordinated punishment in a team investment game with two investors and one allocator. Our findings indicate that coordinated punishment results in higher levels of cooperation and reciprocity, as measured by the levels of joint investment and the return by allocators. Importantly, this does not translate into higher payoffs: investors use punishment more frequently when this is coordinated, which destroys the efficiency gains generated by the highest investment. In fact, our results suggest that the highest level of efficiency would be achieved if investors were not allowed to punish.

协调惩罚是指惩罚需要特定数量的惩罚者才能有效,否则就不会对目标造成伤害。虽然社会经常依赖这种惩罚手段,但与非协调惩罚相比,协调惩罚的好处并不明显,因为在非协调惩罚中,惩罚决定是相互替代的。在本文中,我们比较了在有两个投资者和一个分配者的团队投资博弈中协调惩罚和非协调惩罚的效果。我们的研究结果表明,协调惩罚能带来更高水平的合作和互惠,这可以用分配者的共同投资水平和回报率来衡量。重要的是,这并没有转化为更高的回报:当协调惩罚时,投资者会更频繁地使用惩罚,这就破坏了最高投资所产生的效率收益。事实上,我们的结果表明,如果不允许投资者进行惩罚,就能实现最高的效率水平。
{"title":"Coordinated and uncoordinated punishment in a team investment game","authors":"Vicente Calabuig, Natalia Jiménez-Jiménez, Gonzalo Olcina, Ismael Rodriguez-Lara","doi":"10.1007/s11238-024-09977-9","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1007/s11238-024-09977-9","url":null,"abstract":"<p>Coordinated punishment occurs when punishment requires a specific number of punishers to be effective, otherwise, no damage will be inflicted on the target. While societies often rely on this punishment device, its benefits are unclear compared to uncoordinated punishment, where punishment decisions are substitutes. In this paper, we compare the efficacy of coordinated and uncoordinated punishment in a team investment game with two investors and one allocator. Our findings indicate that coordinated punishment results in higher levels of cooperation and reciprocity, as measured by the levels of joint investment and the return by allocators. Importantly, this does not translate into higher payoffs: investors use punishment more frequently when this is coordinated, which destroys the efficiency gains generated by the highest investment. In fact, our results suggest that the highest level of efficiency would be achieved if investors were not allowed to punish.</p>","PeriodicalId":47535,"journal":{"name":"Theory and Decision","volume":"142 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.8,"publicationDate":"2024-02-24","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"139953701","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
The role of noise variance on effort in group contests 噪声方差对小组竞赛努力程度的影响
IF 0.8 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-02-17 DOI: 10.1007/s11238-023-09974-4
Merve İntişah, Mürüvvet Büyükboyacı

We theoretically and experimentally examine the effect of noise variance and prize value on effort in individual contests and in three types of group contests: perfect-substitutes, best-shot, and weakest-link. For all contest types, we use the rank-order contest model, where effort and random noise determine performance. The theoretical model for individual contests predicts that effort will increase with prize value and decrease with noise variance. As expected, all subjects in our experiment decrease their efforts as noise variance rises, regardless of the value of the prize. Prize value, however, has no effect on effort. In group contests, each group consists of two players with different prize values. The player for whom the prize value is higher is referred to as a strong player; the other is referred to as a weak player. The theoretical model also predicts that exerted positive efforts will decrease with noise variance in all group contests. Our experimental results show that in perfect-substitutes and weakest-link contests, noise variance has no effect on either strong or weak subjects’ efforts. In best-shot contests, however, both strong and weak subjects decrease their efforts when noise variance increases. Finally, we compare the efforts of subjects in individual and group contests. We find differences only in perfect-substitutes and best-shot contests when the noise variance is high. Efforts are higher in perfect-substitutes contests and lower in best-shot contests compared to individual contests.

我们从理论和实验上研究了噪声方差和奖品价值对个人竞赛和三种团体竞赛中努力程度的影响:完全替代竞赛、最佳射手竞赛和最弱联系竞赛。在所有竞赛类型中,我们都使用了秩序竞赛模型,即努力和随机噪声决定成绩。个人竞赛的理论模型预测,努力程度会随着奖品价值的增加而增加,并随着噪声方差的减小而减小。不出所料,在我们的实验中,无论奖品价值如何,所有受试者的努力程度都会随着噪音方差的增加而降低。然而,奖品价值对努力程度没有影响。在小组竞赛中,每组由两名选手组成,他们的奖品价值各不相同。奖品价值较高的一方被称为强者,另一方被称为弱者。理论模型还预测,在所有小组竞赛中,所付出的积极努力会随着噪声方差的增加而减少。我们的实验结果表明,在完全替代和弱联系竞赛中,噪声方差对强者或弱者的努力都没有影响。然而,在最佳射门竞赛中,当噪声方差增大时,强被试和弱被试的努力程度都会降低。最后,我们比较了受试者在个人竞赛和小组竞赛中的努力程度。我们发现,只有当噪声方差较大时,完全替代竞赛和最佳射门竞赛才会出现差异。与个人竞赛相比,完全替代竞赛中的努力程度更高,而最佳射门竞赛中的努力程度更低。
{"title":"The role of noise variance on effort in group contests","authors":"Merve İntişah, Mürüvvet Büyükboyacı","doi":"10.1007/s11238-023-09974-4","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1007/s11238-023-09974-4","url":null,"abstract":"<p>We theoretically and experimentally examine the effect of noise variance and prize value on effort in individual contests and in three types of group contests: perfect-substitutes, best-shot, and weakest-link. For all contest types, we use the rank-order contest model, where effort and random noise determine performance. The theoretical model for individual contests predicts that effort will increase with prize value and decrease with noise variance. As expected, all subjects in our experiment decrease their efforts as noise variance rises, regardless of the value of the prize. Prize value, however, has no effect on effort. In group contests, each group consists of two players with different prize values. The player for whom the prize value is higher is referred to as a strong player; the other is referred to as a weak player. The theoretical model also predicts that exerted positive efforts will decrease with noise variance in all group contests. Our experimental results show that in perfect-substitutes and weakest-link contests, noise variance has no effect on either strong or weak subjects’ efforts. In best-shot contests, however, both strong and weak subjects decrease their efforts when noise variance increases. Finally, we compare the efforts of subjects in individual and group contests. We find differences only in perfect-substitutes and best-shot contests when the noise variance is high. Efforts are higher in perfect-substitutes contests and lower in best-shot contests compared to individual contests.</p>","PeriodicalId":47535,"journal":{"name":"Theory and Decision","volume":"133 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.8,"publicationDate":"2024-02-17","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"139903750","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Constrained dictatorial rules are subject to variable-population paradoxes 受约束的独裁规则受制于可变人口悖论
IF 0.8 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-02-14 DOI: 10.1007/s11238-023-09975-3
William Thomson

In the context of classical exchange economies, we study four ways in which agents can strategically take advantage of allocation rules by affecting who participates and on what terms (Thomson in Soc Choice Welf 42:289–311, 2014). (1) An agent transfers their endowment to someone else and withdraws. The two of them may end up controlling resources that allow them to simultaneously reach higher welfare levels than they otherwise would. (2) An agent invites someone in and let their guest use some of their (the host’s) endowment. The guest transfers back to them what they are assigned over their endowment. The host may benefit. (3) An agent withdraws with their endowment. As in (1), they and someone who stays may end up controlling resources that allow the two of them to simultaneously reach higher welfare levels than they otherwise would. (4) An agent pre-delivers to someone else the net trade that the rule would assign to that agent had the agent participated. The second agent withdraws. The first agent participates with a modified endowment. The first agent may benefit. We ask whether “the constrained priority rules”, defined by maximizing the welfare of a particular agent subject to each of the others finding their assignment at least as desirable as their endowment satisfy these various requirements. The answers are all negative. Because these types of rules are often better behaved than rules that attempt some fairness in distributing gains from trade, these results strengthen the negative conclusions reached in Thomson (2014), and they may provide the key to identifying circumstances in which rules exist that satisfy the axioms, or to proving general impossibility results.

在经典交换经济的背景下,我们研究了代理人可以通过影响谁参与以及以何种条件参与来战略性地利用分配规则的四种方式(Thomson in Soc Choice Welf 42:289-311, 2014)。(1)代理人将自己的禀赋转让给他人并退出。他们两人最终可能会控制资源,使他们同时达到比原来更高的福利水平。(2) 一个代理人邀请别人进来,让客人使用自己(主人)的部分禀赋。客人将自己的禀赋分配给他们。主人可从中获益。(3) 代理人用自己的捐赠提款。与(1)中的情况一样,他们和留下来的人最终可能会控制资源,使他们两人同时达到比原来更高的福利水平。(4) 某位代理人将规则分配给该代理人的净交易额预先交付给其他人,如果该代理人参与的话。第二个代理人退出。第一个代理人以修改后的禀赋参与。第一个代理人可能会受益。我们要问,"受约束的优先权规则 "是否满足这些不同的要求?"受约束的优先权规则 "的定义是,在其他每个代理人都认为自己的分配至少与其禀赋一样理想的前提下,使某个代理人的福利最大化。答案都是否定的。由于这些类型的规则往往比试图在一定程度上公平分配贸易收益的规则表现得更好,这些结果加强了汤姆森(2014)得出的否定结论,它们可能为确定在哪些情况下存在满足公理的规则或证明一般不可能性结果提供了关键。
{"title":"Constrained dictatorial rules are subject to variable-population paradoxes","authors":"William Thomson","doi":"10.1007/s11238-023-09975-3","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1007/s11238-023-09975-3","url":null,"abstract":"<p>In the context of classical exchange economies, we study four ways in which agents can strategically take advantage of allocation rules by affecting who participates and on what terms (Thomson in Soc Choice Welf 42:289–311, 2014). (1) An agent transfers their endowment to someone else and withdraws. The two of them may end up controlling resources that allow them to simultaneously reach higher welfare levels than they otherwise would. (2) An agent invites someone in and let their guest use some of their (the host’s) endowment. The guest transfers back to them what they are assigned over their endowment. The host may benefit. (3) An agent withdraws with their endowment. As in (1), they and someone who stays may end up controlling resources that allow the two of them to simultaneously reach higher welfare levels than they otherwise would. (4) An agent pre-delivers to someone else the net trade that the rule would assign to that agent had the agent participated. The second agent withdraws. The first agent participates with a modified endowment. The first agent may benefit. We ask whether “the constrained priority rules”, defined by maximizing the welfare of a particular agent subject to each of the others finding their assignment at least as desirable as their endowment satisfy these various requirements. The answers are all negative. Because these types of rules are often better behaved than rules that attempt some fairness in distributing gains from trade, these results strengthen the negative conclusions reached in Thomson (2014), and they may provide the key to identifying circumstances in which rules exist that satisfy the axioms, or to proving general impossibility results.</p>","PeriodicalId":47535,"journal":{"name":"Theory and Decision","volume":"16 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.8,"publicationDate":"2024-02-14","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"139770836","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Is social capital bridging or bonding? Evidence from a field experiment with association members 社会资本是桥梁还是纽带?以协会成员为对象的实地实验证据
IF 0.8 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-02-10 DOI: 10.1007/s11238-023-09971-7
Giacomo Degli Antoni, Gianluca Grimalda

Social capital theorists posit that association members are key agents for propagating norms of trust and trustworthiness from within associations toward the society as a whole. Nevertheless, others claim that social capital is primarily bonding, that is, it helps ingroup members better achieve internal goals, but little benefits or even costs carry over to the rest of society. We deploy experimental methods to probe into whether social capital in associations has a predominantly bridging or bonding nature. We compare members’ behavior in anonymous Trust Games with behavior by a demographically comparable sample of non-members. We find that (a) Members are significantly more trusting and trustworthy than the general population both when interacting with fellow members and with people from the general population; (b) Members trust and repay trust from people from the general public nearly at the same level as they do with fellow members. Therefore, most of social capital existing within associations “bridges” over to the rest of society. We quantify 83% of additional trust, and 71% of additional trustworthiness existing in associations vis-à-vis society at large to be bridging and the remainder to be bonding. (c) Association members are no more optimistic or less accurate in predicting others’ behavior than people from the general public. (d) Increased involvement in association activities is not correlated with increased pro-sociality.

社会资本理论者认为,协会成员是协会内部向整个社会传播信任和信用规范的关键力量。但也有人认为,社会资本主要是粘合性的,也就是说,它能帮助内部群体成员更好地实现内部目标,但对社会其他群体却没有什么益处,甚至是成本。我们采用实验方法来探究社团中的社会资本主要是桥梁性质还是纽带性质。我们将成员在匿名信任游戏中的行为与在人口统计学上具有可比性的非成员样本的行为进行了比较。我们发现:(a) 无论是与其他会员还是与普通人交往,会员对他人的信任和信赖程度都明显高于普通人;(b) 会员对普通人的信任和回报程度几乎与对其他会员的信任和回报程度相同。因此,社团内部存在的大部分社会资本都会 "桥接 "到社会的其他部分。我们将社团相对于整个社会的额外信任和额外信用的 83% 和 71% 量化为桥梁资本,其余为纽带资本。(c) 在预测他人行为方面,协会成员并不比普通大众更乐观或更不准确。(d) 社团活动参与度的提高与亲社会性的提高无关。
{"title":"Is social capital bridging or bonding? Evidence from a field experiment with association members","authors":"Giacomo Degli Antoni, Gianluca Grimalda","doi":"10.1007/s11238-023-09971-7","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1007/s11238-023-09971-7","url":null,"abstract":"<p>Social capital theorists posit that association members are key agents for propagating norms of trust and trustworthiness from within associations toward the society as a whole. Nevertheless, others claim that social capital is primarily bonding, that is, it helps ingroup members better achieve internal goals, but little benefits or even costs carry over to the rest of society. We deploy experimental methods to probe into whether social capital in associations has a predominantly bridging or bonding nature. We compare members’ behavior in anonymous Trust Games with behavior by a demographically comparable sample of non-members. We find that (a) Members are significantly more trusting and trustworthy than the general population both when interacting with fellow members and with people from the general population; (b) Members trust and repay trust from people from the general public nearly at the same level as they do with fellow members. Therefore, most of social capital existing within associations “bridges” over to the rest of society. We quantify 83% of additional trust, and 71% of additional trustworthiness existing in associations vis-à-vis society at large to be bridging and the remainder to be bonding. (c) Association members are no more optimistic or less accurate in predicting others’ behavior than people from the general public. (d) Increased involvement in association activities is not correlated with increased pro-sociality.</p>","PeriodicalId":47535,"journal":{"name":"Theory and Decision","volume":"15 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.8,"publicationDate":"2024-02-10","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"139770674","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
False-name-proof and strategy-proof voting rules under separable preferences 可分离偏好下的防假名和防策略投票规则
IF 0.8 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-01-25 DOI: 10.1007/s11238-023-09973-5

Abstract

We consider the problem of a society that uses a voting rule to choose a subset from a given set of objects (candidates, binary issues, or alike). We assume that voters’ preferences over subsets of objects are separable: adding an object to a set leads to a better set if and only if the object is good (as a singleton set, the object is better than the empty set). A voting rule is strategy-proof if no voter benefits by not revealing its preferences truthfully and it is false-name-proof if no voter benefits by submitting several votes under other identities. We characterize all voting rules that satisfy false-name-proofness, strategy-proofness, and ontoness as the class of voting rules in which an object is chosen if it has either at least one vote in every society or a unanimous vote in every society. To do this, we first prove that if a voting rule is false-name-proof, strategy-proof, and onto, then the identities of the voters are not important.

摘要 我们考虑的问题是,一个社会使用投票规则从给定的对象集合(候选人、二元问题或类似问题)中选择一个子集。我们假定投票人对对象子集的偏好是可分离的:如果且仅如果对象是好的,那么在一个集合中添加一个对象就会得到一个更好的集合(作为一个单子集合,对象比空集更好)。如果没有投票人因为不如实透露自己的偏好而获益,那么投票规则就是防策略的;如果没有投票人因为以其他身份提交多张选票而获益,那么投票规则就是防假名的。我们将所有满足防假名、防策略和无通调的投票规则描述为这样一类投票规则:如果一个对象在每个社会中都至少有一票,或者在每个社会中都获得全票,那么这个对象就会被选中。为此,我们首先要证明,如果一个投票规则是防假名、防策略和无条件的,那么投票者的身份并不重要。
{"title":"False-name-proof and strategy-proof voting rules under separable preferences","authors":"","doi":"10.1007/s11238-023-09973-5","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1007/s11238-023-09973-5","url":null,"abstract":"<h3>Abstract</h3> <p>We consider the problem of a society that uses a voting rule to choose a subset from a given set of objects (candidates, binary issues, or alike). We assume that voters’ preferences over subsets of objects are separable: adding an object to a set leads to a better set if and only if the object is good (as a singleton set, the object is better than the empty set). A voting rule is strategy-proof if no voter benefits by not revealing its preferences truthfully and it is false-name-proof if no voter benefits by submitting several votes under other identities. We characterize all voting rules that satisfy false-name-proofness, strategy-proofness, and ontoness as the class of voting rules in which an object is chosen if it has either at least one vote in every society or a unanimous vote in every society. To do this, we first prove that if a voting rule is false-name-proof, strategy-proof, and onto, then the identities of the voters are not important.</p>","PeriodicalId":47535,"journal":{"name":"Theory and Decision","volume":"46 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.8,"publicationDate":"2024-01-25","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"139578323","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Decomposition of interaction indices: alternative interpretations of cardinal–probabilistic interaction indices 交互作用指数的分解:心智-概率交互作用指数的替代解释
IF 0.8 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-01-23 DOI: 10.1007/s11238-023-09970-8
Sébastien Courtin, Rodrigue Tido Takeng , Frédéric Chantreuil

In cooperative game theory, the concept of interaction index is an extension of the concept of one-point solution that takes into account interactions among players. In this paper, we focus on cardinal–probabilistic interaction indices that generalize the class of semivalues. We provide two types of decompositions. With the first one, a cardinal–probabilistic interaction index for a given coalition equals the difference between its external interaction index and a weighted sum of the individual impact of the remaining players on the interaction index of the considered coalition. The second decomposition, based on the notion of the "decomposer", splits an interaction index into a direct part, the decomposer, which measures the interaction in the coalition considered, and an indirect part, which indicates how all remaining players individually affect the interaction of the coalition considered. We propose alternative characterizations of the cardinal–probabilistic interaction indices.

在合作博弈论中,互动指数的概念是单点解概念的扩展,它考虑了博弈者之间的互动。在本文中,我们将重点放在泛化半等式类的心算-概率交互指数上。我们提供了两种分解。第一种分解法是,给定联盟的心算-概率交互指数等于其外部交互指数与其余玩家对所考虑联盟的交互指数的个人影响的加权和之间的差值。第二种分解方法基于 "分解者 "的概念,将互动指数分为直接部分和间接部分,前者即分解者,用于衡量所考虑联盟中的互动情况,后者则表示所有其余参与者如何单独影响所考虑联盟的互动情况。我们还提出了其他的交互指数特征。
{"title":"Decomposition of interaction indices: alternative interpretations of cardinal–probabilistic interaction indices","authors":"Sébastien Courtin, Rodrigue Tido Takeng , Frédéric Chantreuil","doi":"10.1007/s11238-023-09970-8","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1007/s11238-023-09970-8","url":null,"abstract":"<p>In cooperative game theory, the concept of interaction index is an extension of the concept of one-point solution that takes into account interactions among players. In this paper, we focus on cardinal–probabilistic interaction indices that generalize the class of semivalues. We provide two types of decompositions. With the first one, a cardinal–probabilistic interaction index for a given coalition equals the difference between its external interaction index and a weighted sum of the individual impact of the remaining players on the interaction index of the considered coalition. The second decomposition, based on the notion of the \"decomposer\", splits an interaction index into a direct part, the decomposer, which measures the interaction in the coalition considered, and an indirect part, which indicates how all remaining players individually affect the interaction of the coalition considered. We propose alternative characterizations of the cardinal–probabilistic interaction indices.</p>","PeriodicalId":47535,"journal":{"name":"Theory and Decision","volume":"7 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.8,"publicationDate":"2024-01-23","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"139562174","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Aggregating individual credences into collective binary beliefs: an impossibility result 将个人信念汇总为集体二元信念:一个不可能的结果
IF 0.8 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-01-13 DOI: 10.1007/s11238-023-09968-2
Minkyung Wang

This paper addresses how multiple individual credences on logically related issues should be aggregated into collective binary beliefs. We call this binarizing belief aggregation. It is vulnerable to dilemmas such as the discursive dilemma or the lottery paradox: proposition-wise independent aggregation can generate inconsistent or not deductively closed collective judgments. Addressing this challenge using the familiar axiomatic approach, we introduce general conditions on a binarizing belief aggregation rule, including rationality conditions on individual inputs and collective outputs, and determine which rules (if any) satisfy different combinations of these conditions. Furthermore, we analyze similarities and differences between our proofs and other related proofs in the literature and conclude that the problem of binarizing belief aggregation is a free-standing aggregation problem not reducible to judgment aggregation or probabilistic opinion pooling.

本文探讨了如何将逻辑相关问题上的多个个人信念聚合成集体二元信念。我们称之为二元信念聚合。这种方法容易陷入辨证困境或彩票悖论等困境:命题独立聚合可能产生不一致或非演绎封闭的集体判断。为了利用我们熟悉的公理方法来应对这一挑战,我们引入了二元化信念聚合规则的一般条件,包括个人输入和集体输出的合理性条件,并确定哪些规则(如果有的话)满足这些条件的不同组合。此外,我们还分析了我们的证明与文献中其他相关证明的异同,并得出结论:二值化信念聚合问题是一个独立的聚合问题,不能还原为判断聚合或概率意见集合。
{"title":"Aggregating individual credences into collective binary beliefs: an impossibility result","authors":"Minkyung Wang","doi":"10.1007/s11238-023-09968-2","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1007/s11238-023-09968-2","url":null,"abstract":"<p>This paper addresses how multiple individual credences on logically related issues should be aggregated into collective binary beliefs. We call this binarizing belief aggregation. It is vulnerable to dilemmas such as the discursive dilemma or the lottery paradox: proposition-wise independent aggregation can generate inconsistent or not deductively closed collective judgments. Addressing this challenge using the familiar axiomatic approach, we introduce general conditions on a binarizing belief aggregation rule, including rationality conditions on individual inputs and collective outputs, and determine which rules (if any) satisfy different combinations of these conditions. Furthermore, we analyze similarities and differences between our proofs and other related proofs in the literature and conclude that the problem of binarizing belief aggregation is a free-standing aggregation problem not reducible to judgment aggregation or probabilistic opinion pooling.</p>","PeriodicalId":47535,"journal":{"name":"Theory and Decision","volume":"18 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.8,"publicationDate":"2024-01-13","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"139461710","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Suspicious minds and views of fairness 多疑的心态和公平观
IF 0.8 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-01-06 DOI: 10.1007/s11238-023-09965-5
Øivind Schøyen

Do people with different views of what is fair attribute different intentions to actions? In a novel experimental design, participants were significantly more likely to attribute a no-redistribution vote to selfishness if they considered redistribution as being fair. I define this—attributing actions that do not adhere to one’s own fairness view to selfishness—as suspicious attribution. I develop a theory of intention attribution to show how suspicious attribution arises from two other findings from the experiment: the participants underestimate the number of people with fairness views differing from their own and overestimate the selfishness of participants with other fairness views. I discuss how the findings can help explain political polarization.

对什么是公平有不同看法的人是否会将不同的意图归因于行动?在一项新颖的实验设计中,如果参与者认为再分配是公平的,那么他们就更有可能把没有再分配的投票归因于自私。我将这种情况定义为可疑归因--将不符合自己公平观的行为归因于自私。我发展了一种意图归因理论,以说明可疑归因是如何从实验的另外两个发现中产生的:参与者低估了与自己公平观不同的人的数量,以及高估了持其他公平观的参与者的自私性。我将讨论这些发现如何有助于解释政治两极分化。
{"title":"Suspicious minds and views of fairness","authors":"Øivind Schøyen","doi":"10.1007/s11238-023-09965-5","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1007/s11238-023-09965-5","url":null,"abstract":"<p>Do people with different views of what is fair attribute different intentions to actions? In a novel experimental design, participants were significantly more likely to attribute a no-redistribution vote to selfishness if they considered redistribution as being fair. I define this—attributing actions that do not adhere to one’s own fairness view to selfishness—as suspicious attribution. I develop a theory of intention attribution to show how suspicious attribution arises from two other findings from the experiment: the participants underestimate the number of people with fairness views differing from their own and overestimate the selfishness of participants with other fairness views. I discuss how the findings can help explain political polarization.</p>","PeriodicalId":47535,"journal":{"name":"Theory and Decision","volume":"1 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.8,"publicationDate":"2024-01-06","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"139372905","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Are risk attitude, impatience, and impulsivity related to the individual discount rate? Evidence from energy-efficient durable goods 风险态度、不耐烦和冲动与个人贴现率有关吗?节能耐用品提供的证据
IF 0.8 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-01-02 DOI: 10.1007/s11238-023-09961-9
Sébastien Foudi

Discounting is a manifestation of behavioral impulsivity, which is closely related to self-regulation processes. The decision-making process for intertemporal choices is governed by the inhibition of impulses, which can influence both risk and time-related attitudes. This paper utilizes self-reported measures of risk, impatience, and impulsivity attitudes to examine their impact on the implicit discount rate used when weighing the current purchase cost against future energy savings of appliances. It analyzes and tests the interplay between these attitudes using specific functional forms and causal models. The results highlight the role of risk, impatience and impulsivity on the discount rate and the biases that arise from omitting impulsive attitudes. In addition, other factors such as environmental and social preferences, attitudes, and financial constraints contribute to the implicit discount rate.

贴现是行为冲动的一种表现形式,与自我调节过程密切相关。时际选择的决策过程受冲动抑制的支配,而冲动抑制会影响风险和与时间相关的态度。本文利用自我报告的风险、不耐烦和冲动态度测量方法,研究它们对权衡当前购买成本和未来电器节能效果时所使用的内隐贴现率的影响。研究使用特定的函数形式和因果模型分析并检验了这些态度之间的相互作用。结果凸显了风险、不耐烦和冲动对贴现率的影响,以及忽略冲动态度所产生的偏差。此外,环境和社会偏好、态度和财务限制等其他因素也会对隐含贴现率产生影响。
{"title":"Are risk attitude, impatience, and impulsivity related to the individual discount rate? Evidence from energy-efficient durable goods","authors":"Sébastien Foudi","doi":"10.1007/s11238-023-09961-9","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1007/s11238-023-09961-9","url":null,"abstract":"<p>Discounting is a manifestation of behavioral impulsivity, which is closely related to self-regulation processes. The decision-making process for intertemporal choices is governed by the inhibition of impulses, which can influence both risk and time-related attitudes. This paper utilizes self-reported measures of risk, impatience, and impulsivity attitudes to examine their impact on the implicit discount rate used when weighing the current purchase cost against future energy savings of appliances. It analyzes and tests the interplay between these attitudes using specific functional forms and causal models. The results highlight the role of risk, impatience and impulsivity on the discount rate and the biases that arise from omitting impulsive attitudes. In addition, other factors such as environmental and social preferences, attitudes, and financial constraints contribute to the implicit discount rate.</p>","PeriodicalId":47535,"journal":{"name":"Theory and Decision","volume":"15 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.8,"publicationDate":"2024-01-02","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"139079766","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
A test of loyalty 忠诚的考验
IF 0.8 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2023-12-31 DOI: 10.1007/s11238-023-09966-4
Renaud Foucart, Jonathan H. W. Tan

We propose and test a model of loyalty in games. Players can mutually maintain loyalty by working towards a common goal that is pareto-superior to any Nash equilibrium without it. Loyalty imposes a psychological cost on defecting in an ongoing cooperation, which is thus sustained. We distinguish loyalty from reciprocity and explain how it complements guilt aversion with two dynamic games from a field experiment conducted in a Pakistani factory. The evidence supports the validity of loyalty, which has a stronger effect within than between groups.

我们提出并测试了博弈中的忠诚度模型。博弈者可以通过努力实现一个共同目标来相互保持忠诚,这个目标比任何没有忠诚的纳什均衡都要帕累托优越。忠诚度会给正在进行的合作中的叛变带来心理成本,从而使合作得以持续。我们将忠诚与互惠区别开来,并通过在巴基斯坦一家工厂进行的现场实验中的两个动态博弈,解释了忠诚如何与内疚厌恶相辅相成。证据支持忠诚的有效性,忠诚在群体内部比群体之间的影响更大。
{"title":"A test of loyalty","authors":"Renaud Foucart, Jonathan H. W. Tan","doi":"10.1007/s11238-023-09966-4","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1007/s11238-023-09966-4","url":null,"abstract":"<p>We propose and test a model of loyalty in games. Players can mutually maintain loyalty by working towards a common goal that is pareto-superior to any Nash equilibrium without it. Loyalty imposes a psychological cost on defecting in an ongoing cooperation, which is thus sustained. We distinguish loyalty from reciprocity and explain how it complements guilt aversion with two dynamic games from a field experiment conducted in a Pakistani factory. The evidence supports the validity of loyalty, which has a stronger effect within than between groups.</p>","PeriodicalId":47535,"journal":{"name":"Theory and Decision","volume":"17 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.8,"publicationDate":"2023-12-31","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"139065898","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
期刊
Theory and Decision
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1