首页 > 最新文献

Canadian Journal of Economics-Revue Canadienne D Economique最新文献

英文 中文
Gravity for cross-border licensing and the impact of deep trade agreements: Theory and evidence 跨境许可的引力和深度贸易协定的影响:理论与证据
IF 1.3 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-07-31 DOI: 10.1111/caje.12731
Naoto Jinji, Yukiko Sawada, Xingyuan Zhang, Shoji Haruna

We examine whether deep regional trade agreements facilitate cross-border licensing. A micro-founded gravity equation for each supply mode is derived from a model in which heterogeneous firms choose to supply their goods to foreign markets through export, foreign direct investment or licensing. We present several comparative statics results regarding the effects of changes in the fixed costs of serving the destination country, the freeness of trade, and the strength of intellectual property rights protection on bilateral flows of licensing revenues. We then empirically test our theoretical predictions using data on the cross-border flows of royalties and licence fees for 49 countries in the period 1995–2012. In addition to variables that capture the impact of shallow and deep regional trade agreements, we construct dummy variables that represent subcategories of IP rights-related provisions. Consistent with our theoretical predictions, we find that improved access to the destination market through a deep regional trade agreement and stronger IP rights protection through a regional trade agreement with legally enforceable IP rights and technology-related provisions increase bilateral flows of licensing revenues. Among IP rights-related provisions, the accession to or ratification of existing international IP agreements and the protection of trademarks, patents, or industrial designs are important for facilitating cross-border licensing.

我们研究了深度区域贸易协定是否有利于跨境许可。在该模型中,异质企业选择通过出口、外国直接投资或许可方式向国外市场提供产品。我们就服务目的地国的固定成本、贸易自由度和知识产权保护力度的变化对双边许可收入流量的影响提出了一些比较统计结果。然后,我们利用 1995-2012 年间 49 个国家的版税和许可费跨境流动数据,对我们的理论预测进行了实证检验。除了捕捉浅层和深层区域贸易协定影响的变量外,我们还构建了代表知识产权相关条款子类别的虚拟变量。与我们的理论预测一致,我们发现,通过深度区域贸易协定改善目的地市场的准入,以及通过具有可依法强制执行的知识产权和技术相关条款的区域贸易协定加强知识产权保护,都会增加许可收入的双边流动。在与知识产权相关的条款中,加入或批准现有的国际知识产权协定以及保护商标、专利或工业品外观设计对于促进跨境许可非常重要。
{"title":"Gravity for cross-border licensing and the impact of deep trade agreements: Theory and evidence","authors":"Naoto Jinji,&nbsp;Yukiko Sawada,&nbsp;Xingyuan Zhang,&nbsp;Shoji Haruna","doi":"10.1111/caje.12731","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1111/caje.12731","url":null,"abstract":"<p>We examine whether deep regional trade agreements facilitate cross-border licensing. A micro-founded gravity equation for each supply mode is derived from a model in which heterogeneous firms choose to supply their goods to foreign markets through export, foreign direct investment or licensing. We present several comparative statics results regarding the effects of changes in the fixed costs of serving the destination country, the freeness of trade, and the strength of intellectual property rights protection on bilateral flows of licensing revenues. We then empirically test our theoretical predictions using data on the cross-border flows of royalties and licence fees for 49 countries in the period 1995–2012. In addition to variables that capture the impact of shallow and deep regional trade agreements, we construct dummy variables that represent subcategories of IP rights-related provisions. Consistent with our theoretical predictions, we find that improved access to the destination market through a deep regional trade agreement and stronger IP rights protection through a regional trade agreement with legally enforceable IP rights and technology-related provisions increase bilateral flows of licensing revenues. Among IP rights-related provisions, the accession to or ratification of existing international IP agreements and the protection of trademarks, patents, or industrial designs are important for facilitating cross-border licensing.</p>","PeriodicalId":47941,"journal":{"name":"Canadian Journal of Economics-Revue Canadienne D Economique","volume":"57 3","pages":"836-869"},"PeriodicalIF":1.3,"publicationDate":"2024-07-31","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/caje.12731","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"142013514","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"OA","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Multi-plant firms and the heavy tail of firm size distribution 多工厂企业和企业规模分布的重尾
IF 1.3 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-07-23 DOI: 10.1111/caje.12732
Anindya S. Chakrabarti, Shekhar Tomar

The right tail of the firm size distribution has a heavy tail. The origin of this phenomenon, especially the specific characteristics of firms driving this pattern, remain a subject of extensive debate. Previous work has shown that plant size distribution has thinner tails than firm size distribution, indicating the role of multi-plant firms. However, we do not know whether this phenomenon is simply a mechanical effect arising from aggregation across multiple plants or whether the plants of multi-plant firms are different from those of single-plant firms. Using novel data with plant-to-firm mapping, we document that plants of multi-plant firms are more heavy-tailed than single-plant firms, indicating the dominance of the selection effect at the intensive margin. Extensive margin via aggregation of sales at the firm level plays a less crucial role than the selection effect. Importantly, single-plant exporters have a thinner tail than multi-plant non-exporters, suggesting a more dominant role of multi-plant identity than export identity in explaining heavy tails.

企业规模分布的右尾部有一个沉重的尾巴。这一现象的起源,特别是驱动这一模式的企业具体特征,仍是一个广泛争论的话题。以往的研究表明,工厂规模分布的尾部比企业规模分布的尾部要薄,这表明了多工厂企业的作用。然而,我们并不清楚这一现象是否仅仅是多工厂聚集产生的机械效应,还是多工厂企业的工厂与单工厂企业的工厂不同。利用工厂到公司映射的新数据,我们发现多工厂公司的工厂比单工厂公司的工厂更加重尾,这表明选择效应在密集边际占主导地位。与选择效应相比,通过在企业层面汇总销售额而形成的广阔边际所起的关键作用较小。重要的是,单一工厂出口商的尾部比多工厂非出口商的尾部更细,这表明在解释重尾方面,多工厂特征比出口特征发挥着更主要的作用。
{"title":"Multi-plant firms and the heavy tail of firm size distribution","authors":"Anindya S. Chakrabarti,&nbsp;Shekhar Tomar","doi":"10.1111/caje.12732","DOIUrl":"10.1111/caje.12732","url":null,"abstract":"<p>The right tail of the firm size distribution has a heavy tail. The origin of this phenomenon, especially the specific characteristics of firms driving this pattern, remain a subject of extensive debate. Previous work has shown that plant size distribution has thinner tails than firm size distribution, indicating the role of multi-plant firms. However, we do not know whether this phenomenon is simply a mechanical effect arising from aggregation across multiple plants or whether the plants of multi-plant firms are different from those of single-plant firms. Using novel data with plant-to-firm mapping, we document that plants of multi-plant firms are more heavy-tailed than single-plant firms, indicating the dominance of the selection effect at the intensive margin. Extensive margin via aggregation of sales at the firm level plays a less crucial role than the selection effect. Importantly, single-plant exporters have a thinner tail than multi-plant non-exporters, suggesting a more dominant role of multi-plant identity than export identity in explaining heavy tails.</p>","PeriodicalId":47941,"journal":{"name":"Canadian Journal of Economics-Revue Canadienne D Economique","volume":"57 3","pages":"1028-1041"},"PeriodicalIF":1.3,"publicationDate":"2024-07-23","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"141814217","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
China's declining business dynamism 中国企业活力下降
IF 1.3 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-07-23 DOI: 10.1111/caje.12726
Diego A. Cerdeiro, Cian Ruane

We document five novel facts about the dynamism of Chinese manufacturing firms between 2003 and 2018. We show that: (i) the revenue and capital shares of young firms have declined, (ii) life-cycle growth of firm revenues and assets has declined, (iii) life-cycle growth of process efficiency / product quality and investment in intangibles has declined (iv) younger firms have higher capital productivity than older firms, with the gap increasing over time, and (v) the dispersion of capital growth and the responsiveness of capital growth to capital productivity have both declined. Using a simple model, we estimate that the lower life-cycle productivity growth of young firms reduces manufacturing productivity growth by 0.8 percentage points annually, and worsening allocative efficiency of capital between young and old firms reduced manufacturing total factor productivity by 1.25% between the early 2000s and late 2010s. We find that business dynamism is weaker in provinces where state-owned enterprises account for a larger share of the capital stock.

我们记录了 2003 年至 2018 年间中国制造业企业活力的五个新事实。我们发现(i) 年轻企业的收入和资本份额下降;(ii) 企业收入和资产的生命周期增长下降;(iii) 工艺效率/产品质量和无形资产投资的生命周期增长下降;(iv) 年轻企业的资本生产率高于老企业,且差距随着时间的推移不断扩大;(v) 资本增长的分散性和资本增长对资本生产率的响应性均下降。通过一个简单的模型,我们估计年轻企业较低的生命周期生产率增长每年会使制造业生产率增长降低0.8个百分点,而年轻企业与老企业之间不断恶化的资本配置效率在2000年代初至2010年代末期间使制造业全要素生产率降低了1.25%。我们发现,在国有企业占资本存量份额较大的省份,企业活力较弱。
{"title":"China's declining business dynamism","authors":"Diego A. Cerdeiro,&nbsp;Cian Ruane","doi":"10.1111/caje.12726","DOIUrl":"10.1111/caje.12726","url":null,"abstract":"<p>We document five novel facts about the dynamism of Chinese manufacturing firms between 2003 and 2018. We show that: (i) the revenue and capital shares of young firms have declined, (ii) life-cycle growth of firm revenues and assets has declined, (iii) life-cycle growth of process efficiency / product quality and investment in intangibles has declined (iv) younger firms have higher capital productivity than older firms, with the gap increasing over time, and (v) the dispersion of capital growth and the responsiveness of capital growth to capital productivity have both declined. Using a simple model, we estimate that the lower life-cycle productivity growth of young firms reduces manufacturing productivity growth by 0.8 percentage points annually, and worsening allocative efficiency of capital between young and old firms reduced manufacturing total factor productivity by 1.25% between the early 2000s and late 2010s. We find that business dynamism is weaker in provinces where state-owned enterprises account for a larger share of the capital stock.</p>","PeriodicalId":47941,"journal":{"name":"Canadian Journal of Economics-Revue Canadienne D Economique","volume":"57 3","pages":"726-752"},"PeriodicalIF":1.3,"publicationDate":"2024-07-23","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"141813043","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Technology market, product market and aggregate innovation 技术市场、产品市场和总体创新
IF 1.3 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-07-19 DOI: 10.1111/caje.12727
Shiyun Xia

This paper examines the growth maximization mix for intellectual property rights (IPR) in an economy in which incumbents and outside inventors endogenously choose how to develop inventions and commercialization strategies, both of which determine the innovation rate. Outside inventors can choose to commercialize their inventions by (i) launching a new product or (ii) selling to incumbents. I find that if inventors all sell on the technology market, then protecting inventors' patents from imitation by firms raises aggregate innovation. If, instead, all inventors enter the product market, the IPR policy that regulates the ability of incumbents' patents to block the entry of improved products faces a trade-off between innovation from existing firms and inventors, which leads to a single-peaked relationship between economic growth and the blocking strength. When both commercialization strategies are chosen, a balanced IPR policy can raise aggregate innovation by encouraging inventors to choose the more efficient commercialization method.

本文研究了在一个经济中知识产权(IPR)的增长最大化组合,在这个经济中,在位者和外部发明者内生地选择如何开发发明和商业化战略,这两者决定了创新率。外部发明者可以选择通过以下方式将其发明商业化:(i) 推出新产品或 (ii) 出售给在位者。我发现,如果发明者都在技术市场上销售,那么保护发明者的专利不被企业模仿就会提高总体创新率。相反,如果所有发明者都进入产品市场,那么知识产权政策对现有企业专利阻止改进产品进入市场的能力进行监管,就会在现有企业和发明者的创新之间进行权衡,从而导致经济增长与阻止力度之间的单峰关系。当两种商业化策略都被选择时,平衡的知识产权政策可以通过鼓励发明人选择更有效的商业化方法来提高总体创新水平。
{"title":"Technology market, product market and aggregate innovation","authors":"Shiyun Xia","doi":"10.1111/caje.12727","DOIUrl":"10.1111/caje.12727","url":null,"abstract":"<p>This paper examines the growth maximization mix for intellectual property rights (IPR) in an economy in which incumbents and outside inventors endogenously choose how to develop inventions and commercialization strategies, both of which determine the innovation rate. Outside inventors can choose to commercialize their inventions by (i) launching a new product or (ii) selling to incumbents. I find that if inventors all sell on the technology market, then protecting inventors' patents from imitation by firms raises aggregate innovation. If, instead, all inventors enter the product market, the IPR policy that regulates the ability of incumbents' patents to block the entry of improved products faces a trade-off between innovation from existing firms and inventors, which leads to a single-peaked relationship between economic growth and the blocking strength. When both commercialization strategies are chosen, a balanced IPR policy can raise aggregate innovation by encouraging inventors to choose the more efficient commercialization method.</p>","PeriodicalId":47941,"journal":{"name":"Canadian Journal of Economics-Revue Canadienne D Economique","volume":"57 3","pages":"901-932"},"PeriodicalIF":1.3,"publicationDate":"2024-07-19","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"141823397","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Family migration and structural transformation 家庭移民和结构转型
IF 1.3 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-07-16 DOI: 10.1111/caje.12725
Huoqing Cao, Chaoran Chen, Xican Xi, Sharon Xuejing Zuo

This paper integrates the migration decisions of married couples into a multi-sector spatial model, investigating their impact on structural transformation, productivity and gender wage gap. Focusing on China, a country characterized by a higher share of agricultural employment and a lower share in services compared with countries with similar income, we uncover a significant gender gap in migration costs among rural married couples. Furthermore, while migration costs have decreased for all demographic groups from 2000 to 2010, the decline was least pronounced for married couples when both partners left agriculture. We find that reducing migration costs for married couples who migrate together would lead to a decline in agricultural employment, a rise in service sector employment, an increase in aggregate productivity and a narrowing of the gender wage gap. Eliminating the gender differences in migration costs would also increase service sector employment and reduce the gender wage gap.

本文将已婚夫妇的迁移决策纳入多部门空间模型,研究其对结构转型、生产率和性别工资差距的影响。与收入相近的国家相比,中国的农业就业比例较高,而服务业就业比例较低,因此我们以中国为研究对象,发现农村已婚夫妇的迁移成本存在显著的性别差距。此外,从 2000 年到 2010 年,虽然所有人口群体的迁移成本都有所下降,但对于双方都离开农业的已婚夫妇来说,下降幅度最小。我们发现,降低共同移民的已婚夫妇的移民成本将导致农业就业率下降、服务业就业率上升、综合生产率提高以及性别工资差距缩小。消除移民成本中的性别差异还将增加服务业就业,缩小性别工资差距。
{"title":"Family migration and structural transformation","authors":"Huoqing Cao,&nbsp;Chaoran Chen,&nbsp;Xican Xi,&nbsp;Sharon Xuejing Zuo","doi":"10.1111/caje.12725","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1111/caje.12725","url":null,"abstract":"<p>This paper integrates the migration decisions of married couples into a multi-sector spatial model, investigating their impact on structural transformation, productivity and gender wage gap. Focusing on China, a country characterized by a higher share of agricultural employment and a lower share in services compared with countries with similar income, we uncover a significant gender gap in migration costs among rural married couples. Furthermore, while migration costs have decreased for all demographic groups from 2000 to 2010, the decline was least pronounced for married couples when both partners left agriculture. We find that reducing migration costs for married couples who migrate together would lead to a decline in agricultural employment, a rise in service sector employment, an increase in aggregate productivity and a narrowing of the gender wage gap. Eliminating the gender differences in migration costs would also increase service sector employment and reduce the gender wage gap.</p>","PeriodicalId":47941,"journal":{"name":"Canadian Journal of Economics-Revue Canadienne D Economique","volume":"57 3","pages":"753-776"},"PeriodicalIF":1.3,"publicationDate":"2024-07-16","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/caje.12725","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"142013520","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"OA","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Occupational choice, human capital and financial constraints 职业选择、人力资本和财务限制
IF 1.3 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-07-14 DOI: 10.1111/caje.12721
Rui Castro, Pavel Ševčík

We study the aggregate productivity effects of firm-level financial frictions. Credit constraints affect not only production decisions but also household-level schooling decisions. In turn, entrepreneurial schooling decisions impact firm-level productivities, whose cross-sectional distribution becomes endogenous. In anticipation of future constraints, entrepreneurs underinvest in schooling early in life. Frictions lower aggregate productivity because talent is misallocated across occupations and capital is misallocated across firms. Firm-level productivities are also lower due to schooling distortions. These effects combined account for between 36% and 68% of the US–India aggregate productivity difference. Schooling distortions are the major source of aggregate productivity differences.

我们研究了企业层面的金融摩擦对总体生产率的影响。信贷约束不仅会影响生产决策,还会影响家庭教育决策。反过来,企业家的就学决策也会影响企业层面的生产力,而生产力的横截面分布是内生的。由于预期未来会出现限制,企业家在创业初期会对学校教育投资不足。由于人才在不同职业间分配不当,资本在不同企业间分配不当,各种限制降低了总体生产率。企业层面的生产率也会因学校教育的扭曲而降低。这些影响加在一起占美国和印度总生产率差异的 36% 到 68%。学校教育扭曲是总体生产率差异的主要来源。
{"title":"Occupational choice, human capital and financial constraints","authors":"Rui Castro,&nbsp;Pavel Ševčík","doi":"10.1111/caje.12721","DOIUrl":"10.1111/caje.12721","url":null,"abstract":"<p>We study the aggregate productivity effects of firm-level financial frictions. Credit constraints affect not only production decisions but also household-level schooling decisions. In turn, entrepreneurial schooling decisions impact firm-level productivities, whose cross-sectional distribution becomes endogenous. In anticipation of future constraints, entrepreneurs underinvest in schooling early in life. Frictions lower aggregate productivity because talent is misallocated across occupations and capital is misallocated across firms. Firm-level productivities are also lower due to schooling distortions. These effects combined account for between 36% and 68% of the US–India aggregate productivity difference. Schooling distortions are the major source of aggregate productivity differences.</p>","PeriodicalId":47941,"journal":{"name":"Canadian Journal of Economics-Revue Canadienne D Economique","volume":"57 3","pages":"674-703"},"PeriodicalIF":1.3,"publicationDate":"2024-07-14","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/caje.12721","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"141649663","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"OA","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Bilateralism vs. multilateralism: Role of political economy for the prospect of multilateral free trade 双边主义与多边主义:政治经济学对多边自由贸易前景的作用
IF 1.3 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-07-09 DOI: 10.1111/caje.12723
Eric Conglin Chi, Halis Murat Yildiz

In this paper, we use a unified framework of competing exporters and competing importers models where political biases in both exporting and import-competing sectors influence governments' decisions in trade agreement formation and external tariff setting. Using an endogenous trade agreement formation model, we show that the relative strength of political biases in import-competing and exporting sectors are pivotal in determining the free-riding incentives, exclusion incentives and whether the ability to form free trade areas acts as building or stumbling blocks towards multilateral free trade. When the political biases toward exporting and import-competing sectors are sufficiently weak, the ability to form free trade agreements acts as strong building blocks toward free trade. However, when the political bias towards exporting sectors is at the intermediate range and political bias towards import-competing sectors is sufficiently strong, the ability to form free trade agreements acts as strong stumbling blocks.

在本文中,我们使用了竞争出口国和竞争进口国模型的统一框架,其中出口和进口竞争部门的政治偏见会影响政府在贸易协定形成和对外关税制定方面的决策。利用内生贸易协定形成模型,我们表明进口竞争部门和出口部门政治偏见的相对强度在决定搭便车激励、排斥激励以及形成自由贸易区的能力是多边自由贸易的基石还是绊脚石方面起着关键作用。当出口部门和进口竞争部门的政治倾向足够弱时,形成自由贸易协定的能力就会成为自由贸易的强大基石。然而,当对出口部门的政治偏见处于中间范围,而对进口竞争部门的政治偏见足够强时,形成自由贸易协定的能力就会成为强大的绊脚石。
{"title":"Bilateralism vs. multilateralism: Role of political economy for the prospect of multilateral free trade","authors":"Eric Conglin Chi,&nbsp;Halis Murat Yildiz","doi":"10.1111/caje.12723","DOIUrl":"10.1111/caje.12723","url":null,"abstract":"<p>In this paper, we use a unified framework of competing exporters and competing importers models where political biases in both exporting and import-competing sectors influence governments' decisions in trade agreement formation and external tariff setting. Using an endogenous trade agreement formation model, we show that the relative strength of political biases in import-competing and exporting sectors are pivotal in determining the free-riding incentives, exclusion incentives and whether the ability to form free trade areas acts as building or stumbling blocks towards multilateral free trade. When the political biases toward exporting and import-competing sectors are sufficiently weak, the ability to form free trade agreements acts as strong building blocks toward free trade. However, when the political bias towards exporting sectors is at the intermediate range and political bias towards import-competing sectors is sufficiently strong, the ability to form free trade agreements acts as strong stumbling blocks.</p>","PeriodicalId":47941,"journal":{"name":"Canadian Journal of Economics-Revue Canadienne D Economique","volume":"57 3","pages":"870-900"},"PeriodicalIF":1.3,"publicationDate":"2024-07-09","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"141663124","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
The plant-level view of Korea's growth miracle and slowdown 从工厂层面看韩国经济增长的奇迹与放缓
IF 1.3 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-07-07 DOI: 10.1111/caje.12719
Munseob Lee, Yongseok Shin

We analyze the evolution of the plant size distribution, static allocative efficiency and business dynamism of the Korean manufacturing sector during its growth miracle (1967–2000) and the subsequent slowdown since 2000. The average plant size has an inverse-U pattern over time, with a peak in the late 1970s. The measure of static misallocation decreases modestly until 1983 but increases substantially afterwards. These results are at odds with what one may extrapolate from the existing cross-country evidence on the positive relationship between plant size and economic development or the negative one between static misallocation and development. We also find that the growth rate of manufacturing productivity is not systematically correlated with either the level or the rate of change of the average plant size or static misallocation. On the other hand, business dynamism, measured by either churning or responsiveness to shocks, diminished significantly since 2000, coinciding with the decline in the growth rate of manufacturing productivity. Our findings call for more systematic research on how economic performance correlates with establishment/firm size distribution and with static and dynamic allocative efficiency.

我们分析了韩国制造业在其增长奇迹(1967-2000 年)和 2000 年以来增长放缓期间的工厂规模分布、静态分配效率和企业活力的演变。随着时间的推移,平均工厂规模呈反 U 型分布,在 20 世纪 70 年代末达到顶峰。在 1983 年之前,静态错配的衡量标准略有下降,但在 1983 年之后则大幅上升。这些结果与人们从现有的跨国证据中推断出的工厂规模与经济发展之间的正相关关系或静态错配与发展之间的负相关关系不符。我们还发现,制造业生产率的增长率与平均工厂规模或静态配置不当的水平或变化率都没有系统性关联。另一方面,自 2000 年以来,以 "流失 "或对冲击的反应能力来衡量的企业活力显著下降,与制造业生产率增长率的下降相吻合。我们的研究结果要求对经济表现如何与机构/企业规模分布以及静态和动态分配效率相关联进行更系统的研究。
{"title":"The plant-level view of Korea's growth miracle and slowdown","authors":"Munseob Lee,&nbsp;Yongseok Shin","doi":"10.1111/caje.12719","DOIUrl":"10.1111/caje.12719","url":null,"abstract":"<p>We analyze the evolution of the plant size distribution, static allocative efficiency and business dynamism of the Korean manufacturing sector during its growth miracle (1967–2000) and the subsequent slowdown since 2000. The average plant size has an inverse-U pattern over time, with a peak in the late 1970s. The measure of static misallocation decreases modestly until 1983 but increases substantially afterwards. These results are at odds with what one may extrapolate from the existing cross-country evidence on the positive relationship between plant size and economic development or the negative one between static misallocation and development. We also find that the growth rate of manufacturing productivity is not systematically correlated with either the level or the rate of change of the average plant size or static misallocation. On the other hand, business dynamism, measured by either churning or responsiveness to shocks, diminished significantly since 2000, coinciding with the decline in the growth rate of manufacturing productivity. Our findings call for more systematic research on how economic performance correlates with establishment/firm size distribution and with static and dynamic allocative efficiency.</p>","PeriodicalId":47941,"journal":{"name":"Canadian Journal of Economics-Revue Canadienne D Economique","volume":"57 3","pages":"704-725"},"PeriodicalIF":1.3,"publicationDate":"2024-07-07","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"141670727","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Symposium on Misallocation and Structural Transformation: Introduction 错配与结构转型专题讨论会:导言
IF 1.3 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-07-02 DOI: 10.1111/caje.12720
Tasso Adamopoulos, Diego Restuccia
<p>Our motivation for the “Symposium on Misallocation and Structural Transformation” is that the processes of resource allocation and structural change are, each individually and jointly, interwoven with the process of economic growth and development. The common thread that transpires these processes is the allocation of economy-wide inputs across production units (sectors, firms, farms, regions, tasks). There is a growing recognition that this allocation and how it interacts with input accumulation and within unit productivity growth is at the heart of economic growth. Understanding the mechanisms and underlying forces that lead to resource misallocation and structural change are crucial for interpreting how today's developed economies came to be, but particularly critical for today's lower income countries, for which growth and development remain elusive, and concrete policy guidance is paramount.</p><p>A fundamental inquiry within the discipline of economics pertains to the determinants underlying why some countries are rich and others poor. The magnitude of the disparity in income per capita across nations is extremely large, a factor of more than 30-fold between the richest and poorest countries in the world (Jones <span>2016</span>). The welfare implications associated with closing this income gap are staggering, which necessitates understanding the fundamental sources of these great disparities and the associated policy implications. A consensus in the literature has centred around the importance of labour productivity, and in particular total factor productivity (TFP), the effectiveness with which countries can turn given amounts of inputs such as capital and labour into output, in accounting for a substantial portion of the differences in income across nations (Klenow and Rodriguez-Clare <span>1997</span>, Prescott <span>1998</span>). Consequently, an essential follow-up question pertains to the fundamental drivers of differences in aggregate productivity across countries.</p><p>A major area of research in macroeconomics over recent decades has revolved around the quantitative examination of the role for aggregate outcomes of resource allocation across heterogeneous production units within sectors (Restuccia and Rogerson <span>2008</span>, Hsieh and Klenow <span>2009</span>) and sectoral structural transformation (Gollin et al. <span>2002</span>, Duarte and Restuccia <span>2010</span>). These examinations are motivated by empirical findings illustrating wide differences among nations in the operational scale in production such as farm size in the agricultural sector or establishment size in the non-agricutural sector (Adamopoulos and Restuccia <span>2014</span>, Bento and Restuccia <span>2017</span>; <span>2021</span>) and the disparities both in sectoral productivities and stages of structural transformation among nations (Caselli <span>2005</span>, Restuccia et al. <span>2008</span>, Duarte and Restuccia <span>2010</span>).</p><p>Consi
我们举办 "错配与结构转型专题讨论会 "的动机是,资源配置和结构变化的过程与经 济增长和发展的过程相互交织,既相互独立,又相互关联。这些过程的共同点是整个经济的投入在各生产单位(部门、企业、农场、地区、任务)之间的分配。越来越多的人认识到,这种分配及其与投入积累和单位内部生产率增长之间的相互作用是经济增长的核心。理解导致资源配置失当和结构变化的机制和内在力量,对于解释当今发达经济体是如何形成的至关重要,但对于当今低收入国家尤为关键,因为这些国家的增长和发展仍然难以实现,具体的政策指导至关重要。各国之间的人均收入差距极大,世界上最富裕国家和最贫穷国家之间的差距超过 30 倍(琼斯,2016 年)。缩小这一收入差距所带来的福利影响是惊人的,因此有必要了解这些巨大差距的根本原因及相关政策影响。文献中的一个共识是,劳动生产率,尤其是全要素生产率(TFP),即各国将一定量的资本和劳动力等投入转化为产出的效率,在各国收入差距中占很大比重(Klenow 和 Rodriguez-Clare 1997 年,Prescott 1998 年)。近几十年来,宏观经济学研究的一个主要领域一直围绕着对部门内异质生产单位之间资源配置的总体结果(Restuccia 和 Rogerson,2008 年;Hsieh 和 Klenow,2009 年)和部门结构转型(Gollin 等,2002 年;Duarte 和 Restuccia,2010 年)所起作用的定量研究。实证研究结果表明,各国在生产经营规模(如农业部门的农场规模或非农业部门的机构规模)方面存在巨大差异(Adamopoulos 和 Restuccia,2014 年;Bento 和 Restuccia,2017 年;2021 年),而且各国在部门生产率和结构转型阶段方面也存在差异(Caselli,2005 年;Restuccia 等人,2008 年;Duarte 和 Restuccia,2010 年)。考虑部门内生产异质性的原因是,在发达国家,生产要素在不同生产单位之间的重新配置解释了生产力随时间增长的很大一部分原因(Baily 等,1992 年;Foster 等,2008 年)。如果资源在各生产单位之间分配不当,即使在总资源不变的情况下,总生产率也会很低。事实证明,这一分析框架非常有价值,因为它揭示了在一些情况下,各国表面上同质的宏观经济环境掩盖了生产者所面临的有效回报或成本的巨大差异,从而对资源分配模式和总体结果产生了不同的影响(Hopenhayn,2014 年;Restuccia 和 Rogerson,2017 年)。例如,监管框架以及制度和政策环境的变化可能会给不同的生产者带来不同的成本结构和市场条件,从而影响资源配置,降低总体生产率。对部门内各生产单位之间潜在的不当分配进行的探讨发现,在许多情况下,即使是用意良好的政策或制度框架也会对总体生产率水平产生巨大的负面影响。总体而言,关于错配的文献在量化其对总体生产率的影响时采用了两种方法。间接方法使用异质企业的典型模型,并从生产者之间边际产品的差异中推算出错配的程度,这种方法在 Hsieh 和 Klenow(2009 年)的开创性工作中得到推广。这种方法揭示了许多不同部门和国家存在的相当程度的错配。这种直接方法可以确定造成错配的具体政策、制度或摩擦,对其进行测量,并利用结构模型量化其影响。
{"title":"Symposium on Misallocation and Structural Transformation: Introduction","authors":"Tasso Adamopoulos,&nbsp;Diego Restuccia","doi":"10.1111/caje.12720","DOIUrl":"10.1111/caje.12720","url":null,"abstract":"&lt;p&gt;Our motivation for the “Symposium on Misallocation and Structural Transformation” is that the processes of resource allocation and structural change are, each individually and jointly, interwoven with the process of economic growth and development. The common thread that transpires these processes is the allocation of economy-wide inputs across production units (sectors, firms, farms, regions, tasks). There is a growing recognition that this allocation and how it interacts with input accumulation and within unit productivity growth is at the heart of economic growth. Understanding the mechanisms and underlying forces that lead to resource misallocation and structural change are crucial for interpreting how today's developed economies came to be, but particularly critical for today's lower income countries, for which growth and development remain elusive, and concrete policy guidance is paramount.&lt;/p&gt;&lt;p&gt;A fundamental inquiry within the discipline of economics pertains to the determinants underlying why some countries are rich and others poor. The magnitude of the disparity in income per capita across nations is extremely large, a factor of more than 30-fold between the richest and poorest countries in the world (Jones &lt;span&gt;2016&lt;/span&gt;). The welfare implications associated with closing this income gap are staggering, which necessitates understanding the fundamental sources of these great disparities and the associated policy implications. A consensus in the literature has centred around the importance of labour productivity, and in particular total factor productivity (TFP), the effectiveness with which countries can turn given amounts of inputs such as capital and labour into output, in accounting for a substantial portion of the differences in income across nations (Klenow and Rodriguez-Clare &lt;span&gt;1997&lt;/span&gt;, Prescott &lt;span&gt;1998&lt;/span&gt;). Consequently, an essential follow-up question pertains to the fundamental drivers of differences in aggregate productivity across countries.&lt;/p&gt;&lt;p&gt;A major area of research in macroeconomics over recent decades has revolved around the quantitative examination of the role for aggregate outcomes of resource allocation across heterogeneous production units within sectors (Restuccia and Rogerson &lt;span&gt;2008&lt;/span&gt;, Hsieh and Klenow &lt;span&gt;2009&lt;/span&gt;) and sectoral structural transformation (Gollin et al. &lt;span&gt;2002&lt;/span&gt;, Duarte and Restuccia &lt;span&gt;2010&lt;/span&gt;). These examinations are motivated by empirical findings illustrating wide differences among nations in the operational scale in production such as farm size in the agricultural sector or establishment size in the non-agricutural sector (Adamopoulos and Restuccia &lt;span&gt;2014&lt;/span&gt;, Bento and Restuccia &lt;span&gt;2017&lt;/span&gt;; &lt;span&gt;2021&lt;/span&gt;) and the disparities both in sectoral productivities and stages of structural transformation among nations (Caselli &lt;span&gt;2005&lt;/span&gt;, Restuccia et al. &lt;span&gt;2008&lt;/span&gt;, Duarte and Restuccia &lt;span&gt;2010&lt;/span&gt;).&lt;/p&gt;&lt;p&gt;Consi","PeriodicalId":47941,"journal":{"name":"Canadian Journal of Economics-Revue Canadienne D Economique","volume":"57 3","pages":"667-673"},"PeriodicalIF":1.3,"publicationDate":"2024-07-02","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/caje.12720","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"141684556","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"OA","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Measuring physicians' response to incentives: Labour supply, multitasking and earnings 衡量医生对激励措施的反应:劳动力供给、多重任务和收入
IF 1.6 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-05-07 DOI: 10.1111/caje.12710
Nibene H. Somé, Bernard Fortin, Bruce Shearer

Physicians are typically paid for services completed. Yet, they provide different types of services with different prices, introducing a multitasking element to their labour-supply decisions. We show that optimal behaviour generates a maximum earnings function in which earnings depend on prices and total hours worked. Estimation by limited-information methods identifies a lower bound to the own-price substitution effect of a price change. Full-information methods identify the full response to incentives, including income effects. We illustrate these methods on a sample of specialist physicians working in Québec, Canada. Our results suggest that the own-price substitution effects of a price change are both economically and statistically significant. Income effects are present but overridden when prices increase for individual services. In contrast, in the presence of broad-based fee increases, the income effect dominates the substitution effect, which leads physicians to reduce their supply of services.

医生通常按完成的服务付费。然而,他们提供的服务类型不同,价格也不同,这就为他们的劳动力供给决策引入了多重任务因素。我们的研究表明,最优行为会产生一个最大收益函数,在这个函数中,收益取决于价格和总工作时间。通过有限信息方法进行估计,可以确定价格变化对自身价格替代效应的下限。全信息方法则可以确定对激励措施的全部反应,包括收入效应。我们以在加拿大魁北克省工作的专科医生为样本对这些方法进行了说明。我们的研究结果表明,价格变动的自有价格替代效应在经济上和统计上都是显著的。收入效应是存在的,但当个别服务价格上涨时,收入效应会被盖过。相反,在广泛提高收费的情况下,收入效应会主导替代效应,从而导致医生减少服务供应。
{"title":"Measuring physicians' response to incentives: Labour supply, multitasking and earnings","authors":"Nibene H. Somé,&nbsp;Bernard Fortin,&nbsp;Bruce Shearer","doi":"10.1111/caje.12710","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1111/caje.12710","url":null,"abstract":"<p>Physicians are typically paid for services completed. Yet, they provide different types of services with different prices, introducing a multitasking element to their labour-supply decisions. We show that optimal behaviour generates a maximum earnings function in which earnings depend on prices and total hours worked. Estimation by limited-information methods identifies a lower bound to the own-price substitution effect of a price change. Full-information methods identify the full response to incentives, including income effects. We illustrate these methods on a sample of specialist physicians working in Québec, Canada. Our results suggest that the own-price substitution effects of a price change are both economically and statistically significant. Income effects are present but overridden when prices increase for individual services. In contrast, in the presence of broad-based fee increases, the income effect dominates the substitution effect, which leads physicians to reduce their supply of services.</p>","PeriodicalId":47941,"journal":{"name":"Canadian Journal of Economics-Revue Canadienne D Economique","volume":"57 2","pages":"622-661"},"PeriodicalIF":1.6,"publicationDate":"2024-05-07","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"140919270","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
期刊
Canadian Journal of Economics-Revue Canadienne D Economique
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1