首页 > 最新文献

Economics of Innovation and New Technology最新文献

英文 中文
Innovation, asymmetric information and the capital structure of new firms 创新、信息不对称与新企业资本结构
3区 经济学 Q1 Economics, Econometrics and Finance Pub Date : 2023-10-10 DOI: 10.1080/10438599.2023.2265821
Jonathan Taglialatela, Andrea Mina
ABSTRACTStart-ups are essential contributors to economic development, but they often face several barriers to growth, including access to finance. We study their capital structure in their early years of operation through the lens of Pecking Order Theory, exploring how the pursuit of innovation influences firms’ reliance on different types of finance. Panel analyses of 8273 German start-ups show that innovation activities are relevant predict start-ups’ revealed preferences for finance. Effects on the type and order of financing sources depend on the degree of information asymmetries specific to research and development activities, human capital endowments, and the market introduction of new products and processes. New firms focused on research and development activities and with better human capital are less likely to receive informationally complex finance such as debt and will rely relatively more on owner and equity finance. Mixed evidence is found, instead, on the role of new products or processes. Our results suggest that the traditional pecking order theory does not hold for new firms, implying that owner and external equity play a much more prominent role for such firms. Then, managers and entrepreneurs should consider specific sources of finance and financial instruments in light of their innovative activities.KEYWORDS: Innovationinformation asymmetriesstart-uppecking orderentrepreneurial financeJEL CODES: G32O16O30 Disclosure statementNo potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s).Notes1 For a broader discussion on the relationship between Schumpeterian innovation and firm financial constraints see Hajivassiliou and Savignac (Citation2008), Hottenrott and Peters (Citation2012) and Lahr and Mina (Citation2021).2 Following this perspective, several contributions have explored the effect of innovation on investment selection behaviours in venture capital markets (Audretsch, Bönte, and Mahagaonkar Citation2012; Baum and Silverman Citation2004; Conti, Thursby, and Thursby Citation2013; Conti, Thursby, and Rothaermel Citation2013; Häussler, Harhoff, and Müller Citation2012; Hsu and Ziedonis Citation2013; Mann and Sager Citation2007; Lahr and Mina Citation2016).3 Before 2014 this database was known as KfW/ZEW Start-up Panel.4 The first two years of data (i.e., 2005-2006) only contain information about the firm’s cost, investments and revenues and exclude information on innovation. Therefore, they cannot serve the purpose of this study.5 We stress that our data indicate the types of financing obtained by firms, but contain no information on whether firms have applied for other types of finance and were rejected. In other words, without observation of finance-seeking behaviours, we can only observe the “revealed preferences” of firms.6 The results of simple Logit models are available upon request. All the statistical tests confirmed the better fit of all panel specifications.
摘要初创企业是经济发展的重要贡献者,但它们往往面临一些障碍,包括获得融资。我们通过Pecking Order理论的视角来研究企业早期运营的资本结构,探讨创新追求如何影响企业对不同类型融资的依赖。对8273家德国初创企业的面板分析表明,创新活动与初创企业对财务的偏好相关。对融资来源类型和顺序的影响取决于研发活动、人力资本禀赋以及新产品和新工艺的市场引进所特有的信息不对称程度。以研究和发展活动为重点并拥有较好人力资本的新公司不太可能获得信息复杂的融资,如债务,而将相对更多地依赖所有者和股权融资。相反,关于新产品或新工艺的作用,人们发现了各种各样的证据。我们的研究结果表明,传统的优序理论并不适用于新公司,这意味着所有者和外部股权在新公司中发挥了更为突出的作用。然后,管理人员和企业家应根据其创新活动考虑具体的资金来源和金融工具。关键词:创新信息不对称创业订单创业融资代码:G32O16O30披露声明作者未报告潜在利益冲突。注1关于熊彼特式创新与企业财务约束之间关系的更广泛讨论,请参见Hajivassiliou and Savignac (Citation2008)、Hottenrott and Peters (Citation2012)和Lahr and Mina (Citation2021)遵循这一观点,一些贡献探讨了创新对风险资本市场投资选择行为的影响(Audretsch, Bönte, and Mahagaonkar Citation2012;Baum and Silverman Citation2004;Conti, Thursby, and Thursby Citation2013;Conti, Thursby, and Rothaermel Citation2013;Häussler, Harhoff, and m ller Citation2012;《科学通报》2013;Mann and Sager citation; 2007;2 . Lahr and Mina Citation2016)在2014年之前,该数据库被称为KfW/ZEW创业小组。4前两年的数据(即2005-2006年)仅包含有关公司成本,投资和收入的信息,不包括创新信息。因此,它们不能服务于本研究的目的我们强调,我们的数据表明了企业获得的融资类型,但不包含企业是否申请了其他类型的融资并被拒绝的信息。换句话说,如果不观察企业的融资行为,我们只能观察企业的“显性偏好”简单的Logit模型的结果可根据要求提供。所有的统计测试都证实了所有面板规格的更好的拟合。
{"title":"Innovation, asymmetric information and the capital structure of new firms","authors":"Jonathan Taglialatela, Andrea Mina","doi":"10.1080/10438599.2023.2265821","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1080/10438599.2023.2265821","url":null,"abstract":"ABSTRACTStart-ups are essential contributors to economic development, but they often face several barriers to growth, including access to finance. We study their capital structure in their early years of operation through the lens of Pecking Order Theory, exploring how the pursuit of innovation influences firms’ reliance on different types of finance. Panel analyses of 8273 German start-ups show that innovation activities are relevant predict start-ups’ revealed preferences for finance. Effects on the type and order of financing sources depend on the degree of information asymmetries specific to research and development activities, human capital endowments, and the market introduction of new products and processes. New firms focused on research and development activities and with better human capital are less likely to receive informationally complex finance such as debt and will rely relatively more on owner and equity finance. Mixed evidence is found, instead, on the role of new products or processes. Our results suggest that the traditional pecking order theory does not hold for new firms, implying that owner and external equity play a much more prominent role for such firms. Then, managers and entrepreneurs should consider specific sources of finance and financial instruments in light of their innovative activities.KEYWORDS: Innovationinformation asymmetriesstart-uppecking orderentrepreneurial financeJEL CODES: G32O16O30 Disclosure statementNo potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s).Notes1 For a broader discussion on the relationship between Schumpeterian innovation and firm financial constraints see Hajivassiliou and Savignac (Citation2008), Hottenrott and Peters (Citation2012) and Lahr and Mina (Citation2021).2 Following this perspective, several contributions have explored the effect of innovation on investment selection behaviours in venture capital markets (Audretsch, Bönte, and Mahagaonkar Citation2012; Baum and Silverman Citation2004; Conti, Thursby, and Thursby Citation2013; Conti, Thursby, and Rothaermel Citation2013; Häussler, Harhoff, and Müller Citation2012; Hsu and Ziedonis Citation2013; Mann and Sager Citation2007; Lahr and Mina Citation2016).3 Before 2014 this database was known as KfW/ZEW Start-up Panel.4 The first two years of data (i.e., 2005-2006) only contain information about the firm’s cost, investments and revenues and exclude information on innovation. Therefore, they cannot serve the purpose of this study.5 We stress that our data indicate the types of financing obtained by firms, but contain no information on whether firms have applied for other types of finance and were rejected. In other words, without observation of finance-seeking behaviours, we can only observe the “revealed preferences” of firms.6 The results of simple Logit models are available upon request. All the statistical tests confirmed the better fit of all panel specifications.","PeriodicalId":51485,"journal":{"name":"Economics of Innovation and New Technology","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2023-10-10","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"136354169","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2
Impact of technological change on growth trajectory of India: a multivariate-BVAR analysis 技术变革对印度经济增长轨迹的影响:多变量- bvar分析
3区 经济学 Q1 Economics, Econometrics and Finance Pub Date : 2023-10-10 DOI: 10.1080/10438599.2023.2267994
Debasis Rooj, Rituparna Kaushik
ABSTRACTThis paper examines the impact of technological change on Indian economic growth using the Bayesian Vector Auto-Regressive (BVAR) methodology. We use a comprehensive annual time series dataset covering the period of 1980 to 2019 on real economic activity, gross fixed capital formation, and employment. Technological innovation is measured by the number of patents filed by resident Indians. Technological innovation positively impacts both economic growth and gross fixed capital formation. Our findings indicate that increasing the number of patents leads to higher investment, which drives India's economic growth. However, our results also point towards the possible negative influence of technological innovation on the aggregate employment scenario in India. Our main findings are robust to alternative identification strategies and variable transformation. The asymmetric analysis also corroborates the positive influence of patents on driving investment and economic growth in India.KEYWORDS: Economic growthtechnological changepatentsBayesian VARJEL CLASSIFICATION: E44E31 AcknowledgmentWe thank the Managing Editor, Prof. Cristiano Antonelli, for providing invaluable suggestions in helping us improve the manuscript. We also thank three anonymous reviewers of our manuscript for their detailed comments and suggestions. We also thank Dr. Reshmi Sengupta, Dr. Nilanjan Banik, and Dr. Arnab Chakrabarti for their suggestions and comments in improving certain sections of the paper.Disclosure statementNo potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s).Notes1 Antonelli and Scellato provide comprehensive discussions on the idea of "Innovation."2 Although the data is available until 2020, we restrict our sample to 2019 and exclude 2020 to avoid the problem that can arise due to the COVID-19 pandemic.3 Normal-Wishart prior constraints λ2 to the value of 1. We have estimated the baseline model with different set values for the hyperparameters. The finding suggests that IRFs are not qualitatively different due to changes in the values of the hyperparameters. However, for some choices, the confidence intervals become wider or narrower, and these are only indicative of the shape of the posterior distribution and have no statistical significance. Therefore, we can conclude that the findings from these specifications are robust to choices of different hyperparameter values for the priors.4 We have considered slightly lower values of the AR(1) parameter, such as 0.9 and 0.8, but it has a negligible impact on the results.5 The DIC value for our baseline model is -969.84.6 BVAR estimation is conducted by employing the BEAR toolbox in MATLAB developed by Dieppe et al. (Citation2016)7 Sims and Zha (Citation1999) assert that the traditional frequentist error bands may be misleading as they mix parameter location information with model fit information. The authors propose using likelihood-based bands and argue that 68% interval bands provide a more precise es
摘要本文采用贝叶斯向量自回归(BVAR)方法研究了技术变革对印度经济增长的影响。我们使用了一个全面的年度时间序列数据集,涵盖1980年至2019年的实体经济活动、固定资本形成总额和就业。技术创新是通过印度居民申请专利的数量来衡量的。技术创新对经济增长和固定资本形成总量均有正向影响。我们的研究结果表明,专利数量的增加导致投资的增加,从而推动印度的经济增长。然而,我们的结果也指向技术创新对印度总就业情景可能产生的负面影响。我们的主要发现是稳健的替代识别策略和变量转换。非对称分析也证实了专利对推动印度投资和经济增长的积极影响。关键词:经济增长技术变革专利贝叶斯VARJEL分类:E44E31致谢感谢主编Cristiano Antonelli教授为我们改进稿件提供的宝贵建议。我们也感谢三位匿名审稿人对我们手稿的详细评论和建议。我们也感谢Reshmi Sengupta博士、Nilanjan Banik博士和Arnab Chakrabarti博士对本文某些部分的改进提出的建议和意见。披露声明作者未报告潜在的利益冲突。注1 Antonelli和Scellato对“创新”的概念进行了全面的讨论。“2虽然数据到2020年才可用,但我们将样本限制在2019年,并排除2020年,以避免因COVID-19大流行而可能出现的问题Normal-Wishart先验约束λ2到1的值。我们用不同的超参数设定值估计了基线模型。这一发现表明,由于超参数值的变化,irf在质量上并没有不同。然而,对于某些选择,置信区间变宽或变窄,这只是表明后验分布的形状,没有统计学意义。因此,我们可以得出结论,这些规范的发现对先验的不同超参数值的选择是稳健的我们考虑了略低的AR(1)参数值,如0.9和0.8,但它对结果的影响可以忽略不计我们的基线模型的DIC值为-969.84.6。BVAR估计是利用Dieppe等人(Citation2016)在MATLAB中开发的BEAR工具箱进行的。Sims和Zha (Citation1999)认为,传统的频率误差带可能会误导,因为它们将参数位置信息与模型拟合信息混合在一起。作者建议使用基于似然的频带,并认为68%的间隔频带可以更精确地估计真实覆盖概率。
{"title":"Impact of technological change on growth trajectory of India: a multivariate-BVAR analysis","authors":"Debasis Rooj, Rituparna Kaushik","doi":"10.1080/10438599.2023.2267994","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1080/10438599.2023.2267994","url":null,"abstract":"ABSTRACTThis paper examines the impact of technological change on Indian economic growth using the Bayesian Vector Auto-Regressive (BVAR) methodology. We use a comprehensive annual time series dataset covering the period of 1980 to 2019 on real economic activity, gross fixed capital formation, and employment. Technological innovation is measured by the number of patents filed by resident Indians. Technological innovation positively impacts both economic growth and gross fixed capital formation. Our findings indicate that increasing the number of patents leads to higher investment, which drives India's economic growth. However, our results also point towards the possible negative influence of technological innovation on the aggregate employment scenario in India. Our main findings are robust to alternative identification strategies and variable transformation. The asymmetric analysis also corroborates the positive influence of patents on driving investment and economic growth in India.KEYWORDS: Economic growthtechnological changepatentsBayesian VARJEL CLASSIFICATION: E44E31 AcknowledgmentWe thank the Managing Editor, Prof. Cristiano Antonelli, for providing invaluable suggestions in helping us improve the manuscript. We also thank three anonymous reviewers of our manuscript for their detailed comments and suggestions. We also thank Dr. Reshmi Sengupta, Dr. Nilanjan Banik, and Dr. Arnab Chakrabarti for their suggestions and comments in improving certain sections of the paper.Disclosure statementNo potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s).Notes1 Antonelli and Scellato provide comprehensive discussions on the idea of \"Innovation.\"2 Although the data is available until 2020, we restrict our sample to 2019 and exclude 2020 to avoid the problem that can arise due to the COVID-19 pandemic.3 Normal-Wishart prior constraints λ2 to the value of 1. We have estimated the baseline model with different set values for the hyperparameters. The finding suggests that IRFs are not qualitatively different due to changes in the values of the hyperparameters. However, for some choices, the confidence intervals become wider or narrower, and these are only indicative of the shape of the posterior distribution and have no statistical significance. Therefore, we can conclude that the findings from these specifications are robust to choices of different hyperparameter values for the priors.4 We have considered slightly lower values of the AR(1) parameter, such as 0.9 and 0.8, but it has a negligible impact on the results.5 The DIC value for our baseline model is -969.84.6 BVAR estimation is conducted by employing the BEAR toolbox in MATLAB developed by Dieppe et al. (Citation2016)7 Sims and Zha (Citation1999) assert that the traditional frequentist error bands may be misleading as they mix parameter location information with model fit information. The authors propose using likelihood-based bands and argue that 68% interval bands provide a more precise es","PeriodicalId":51485,"journal":{"name":"Economics of Innovation and New Technology","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2023-10-10","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"136352432","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Firm survival and innovation: direct and indirect effects of knowledge for SMEs 企业生存与创新:知识对中小企业的直接与间接影响
3区 经济学 Q1 Economics, Econometrics and Finance Pub Date : 2023-10-09 DOI: 10.1080/10438599.2023.2263371
Sergio Destefanis, Ornella Wanda Maietta, Fernanda Mazzotta, Lavinia Parisi
ABSTRACTThis paper explores the effects of innovation on firm survival by using data from a representative survey of small and medium manufacturing firms in the province of Salerno, Italy. We innovate upon the literature by (a) comparing the impact of different sources of internal and external knowledge (including universities) on the probability of firm survival; (b) assessing the mediating impact of the human capital of workers and entrepreneurs on learning from these knowledge sources. Finally, we measure the impact of different types of innovation on firm survival. Our evidence upholds the link between innovation and firm survival, particularly for product and organisational innovation. Results regarding the impact of different sources of knowledge highlight the roles of employee training, the human capital of entrepreneurs and workers and the productivity of university departments providing relevant knowledge. Other elements of external knowledge, such as proximity to the University of Salerno or being in the city of Salerno, are significant facilitators of survival only if mediated through high levels of the human capital of entrepreneurs and workers.KEYWORDS: Internal and external knowledge; absorptive capacitySMEsuniversity collaborationhuman capitalJEL CLASSIFICATIONS: L20O3D22I2 Disclosure statementNo potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s).Notes1 There is a common presumption that firm survival is ‘good’. However the literature on firm exit emphasises the distinction between voluntary entrepreneurial closure and failure (Bates Citation2005; Coad Citation2014; DeTienne, McKelvie, and Chandler Citation2015; Headd Citation2003; Khelil Citation2016; Wennberg, Delmar, and McKelvie Citation2016).2 Hyytinen, Pajarinen, and Rouvinen (Citation2015) and Fernandes and Paunov (Citation2015) also apply probit models to the study of innovation and survival. Their analyses, however, do not allow for the joint determination of innovation and survival and hence do not yield estimates of the direct and indirect effects of innovation on survival.3 It is worth noting that in 2016, 93% of EU manufacturing firms had fewer than ten employees (Muller et al. Citation2017).4 Note however that Trushin and Ugur (Citation2021) find that firms in hazardous environments can mitigate the detrimental effects of these environments on survival through R&D expenditure.5 Interestingly, Holl, Peters, and Rammer (Citation2023) report a similar spatial range for German manufacturing firms in a related context (the impact of patents on innovation persistence).6 This finding is consistent with the theoretical model of Desmet and Parente (Citation2012), where a large firm size is essential for the introduction of effective cost-saving technologies.7 The survey was conducted by the Centre for Economic and Labour Policy Evaluation at the University of Salerno and funded by the Sichelgaita Foundation in Salerno.8 LMAs, akin to British travel to work areas, are
下面我们将简要介绍这些probit模型。根据一位匿名推荐人的建议,关于这些模型的进一步细节在补充材料中提供。16在所有情况下,平均VIF小于2.5,并且在所有方程中的大多数变量中也低于5(对于三个变量,它高于5但低于7.5)对于离散变量,直接效应和间接效应的总和不等于总边际效应,因为计算直接效应和间接效应的方法是为连续变量设计的,并与离散变量的一些近似一起使用众所周知,在自由度减少的情况下,极大似然方法会受到收敛问题的影响(参见Altonji, Elder, and Taber Citation2005)我们感谢两位匿名的推荐人提出这些稳健性检查的建议我们数据集的性质阻止了沿着Hyytinen、Pajarinen和Rouvinen的思路对风险偏好进行更深入的分析(Citation2015) 21我们尝试将企业家的高教育水平和毕业生工人的份额与所有可用的内部和外部知识来源进行交互,包括用于员工培训的假人、MIPAAF实验室、地区(控制与竞争对手和客户的重要联系)和大学部门的生产力。然而,为了确保更紧凑的展示,我们只报告与企业家的高教育水平或与毕业生工人的份额有重要相互作用的规范。
{"title":"Firm survival and innovation: direct and indirect effects of knowledge for SMEs","authors":"Sergio Destefanis, Ornella Wanda Maietta, Fernanda Mazzotta, Lavinia Parisi","doi":"10.1080/10438599.2023.2263371","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1080/10438599.2023.2263371","url":null,"abstract":"ABSTRACTThis paper explores the effects of innovation on firm survival by using data from a representative survey of small and medium manufacturing firms in the province of Salerno, Italy. We innovate upon the literature by (a) comparing the impact of different sources of internal and external knowledge (including universities) on the probability of firm survival; (b) assessing the mediating impact of the human capital of workers and entrepreneurs on learning from these knowledge sources. Finally, we measure the impact of different types of innovation on firm survival. Our evidence upholds the link between innovation and firm survival, particularly for product and organisational innovation. Results regarding the impact of different sources of knowledge highlight the roles of employee training, the human capital of entrepreneurs and workers and the productivity of university departments providing relevant knowledge. Other elements of external knowledge, such as proximity to the University of Salerno or being in the city of Salerno, are significant facilitators of survival only if mediated through high levels of the human capital of entrepreneurs and workers.KEYWORDS: Internal and external knowledge; absorptive capacitySMEsuniversity collaborationhuman capitalJEL CLASSIFICATIONS: L20O3D22I2 Disclosure statementNo potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s).Notes1 There is a common presumption that firm survival is ‘good’. However the literature on firm exit emphasises the distinction between voluntary entrepreneurial closure and failure (Bates Citation2005; Coad Citation2014; DeTienne, McKelvie, and Chandler Citation2015; Headd Citation2003; Khelil Citation2016; Wennberg, Delmar, and McKelvie Citation2016).2 Hyytinen, Pajarinen, and Rouvinen (Citation2015) and Fernandes and Paunov (Citation2015) also apply probit models to the study of innovation and survival. Their analyses, however, do not allow for the joint determination of innovation and survival and hence do not yield estimates of the direct and indirect effects of innovation on survival.3 It is worth noting that in 2016, 93% of EU manufacturing firms had fewer than ten employees (Muller et al. Citation2017).4 Note however that Trushin and Ugur (Citation2021) find that firms in hazardous environments can mitigate the detrimental effects of these environments on survival through R&D expenditure.5 Interestingly, Holl, Peters, and Rammer (Citation2023) report a similar spatial range for German manufacturing firms in a related context (the impact of patents on innovation persistence).6 This finding is consistent with the theoretical model of Desmet and Parente (Citation2012), where a large firm size is essential for the introduction of effective cost-saving technologies.7 The survey was conducted by the Centre for Economic and Labour Policy Evaluation at the University of Salerno and funded by the Sichelgaita Foundation in Salerno.8 LMAs, akin to British travel to work areas, are","PeriodicalId":51485,"journal":{"name":"Economics of Innovation and New Technology","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2023-10-09","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"135093685","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Can the development of digital finance stimulate enterprise innovation? Empirical evidence from China 数字金融的发展能否激发企业创新?来自中国的经验证据
3区 经济学 Q1 Economics, Econometrics and Finance Pub Date : 2023-10-05 DOI: 10.1080/10438599.2023.2266376
Kai Zhao, Haonan Shan, Zeping Chen, Wanshu Wu
ABSTRACTBased on the data of China A-share listed enterprises, this paper examines the actual effect and mechanism of the development of digital finance on different innovation behaviors of enterprises, by using the panel data model and regression-based mediation analysis. It is found that the development of digital finance not only promotes the R&D investment of enterprises but also improves the quantity and quality of enterprise innovation output. The incentive effect of digital finance on enterprise R&D investment is stronger than that on innovation output, while the incentive effect of digital finance on enterprise breakthrough innovation is stronger than that of incremental innovation. Both the ‘broadening’ and the ‘deepening’ of digital finance have a significant positive effect on enterprise innovation, while the ‘digitalization degree’ of digital finance has no significant effect on enterprise innovation, and even may hinder the improvement of innovation quality. The incentive effect of digital finance on the innovation output of state-owned enterprises is reflected in ‘quantity’, while the incentive effect on innovation of non-state-owned enterprises is reflected in ‘quality’. Digital finance can stimulate enterprise innovation by easing the financing constraints of enterprises, optimizing the government subsidy system, and improving the business environment.KEYWORDS: Digital financeenterprise innovationinnovation qualitybusiness environmentgovernment subsidies Disclosure statementNo potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s).Additional informationFundingThis work was supported by Shandong Provincial Natural Science Foundation [Grant Number ZR2023MG075]; National Planning Office of Philosophy and Social Sciences of China [Grant Number 20FJYB017].
摘要本文基于中国a股上市企业数据,运用面板数据模型和基于回归的中介分析,考察了数字金融发展对企业不同创新行为的实际影响及其机制。研究发现,数字金融的发展不仅促进了企业的研发投入,而且提高了企业创新产出的数量和质量。数字金融对企业研发投入的激励作用强于对创新产出的激励作用,数字金融对企业突破性创新的激励作用强于增量式创新的激励作用。数字金融的“拓宽”和“深化”对企业创新都有显著的正向影响,而数字金融的“数字化程度”对企业创新没有显著影响,甚至可能阻碍创新质量的提高。数字金融对国有企业创新产出的激励作用表现为“量”,对非国有企业创新产出的激励作用表现为“质”。数字金融可以通过缓解企业融资约束、优化政府补贴制度、改善营商环境等方式激发企业创新。关键词:数字金融企业创新创新质量商业环境政府补贴披露声明作者未发现潜在利益冲突基金资助:山东省自然科学基金[资助号:ZR2023MG075];国家哲学社会科学规划办公室[批准号20FJYB017]。
{"title":"Can the development of digital finance stimulate enterprise innovation? Empirical evidence from China","authors":"Kai Zhao, Haonan Shan, Zeping Chen, Wanshu Wu","doi":"10.1080/10438599.2023.2266376","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1080/10438599.2023.2266376","url":null,"abstract":"ABSTRACTBased on the data of China A-share listed enterprises, this paper examines the actual effect and mechanism of the development of digital finance on different innovation behaviors of enterprises, by using the panel data model and regression-based mediation analysis. It is found that the development of digital finance not only promotes the R&D investment of enterprises but also improves the quantity and quality of enterprise innovation output. The incentive effect of digital finance on enterprise R&D investment is stronger than that on innovation output, while the incentive effect of digital finance on enterprise breakthrough innovation is stronger than that of incremental innovation. Both the ‘broadening’ and the ‘deepening’ of digital finance have a significant positive effect on enterprise innovation, while the ‘digitalization degree’ of digital finance has no significant effect on enterprise innovation, and even may hinder the improvement of innovation quality. The incentive effect of digital finance on the innovation output of state-owned enterprises is reflected in ‘quantity’, while the incentive effect on innovation of non-state-owned enterprises is reflected in ‘quality’. Digital finance can stimulate enterprise innovation by easing the financing constraints of enterprises, optimizing the government subsidy system, and improving the business environment.KEYWORDS: Digital financeenterprise innovationinnovation qualitybusiness environmentgovernment subsidies Disclosure statementNo potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s).Additional informationFundingThis work was supported by Shandong Provincial Natural Science Foundation [Grant Number ZR2023MG075]; National Planning Office of Philosophy and Social Sciences of China [Grant Number 20FJYB017].","PeriodicalId":51485,"journal":{"name":"Economics of Innovation and New Technology","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2023-10-05","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"134975509","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
The alienability of innovation: evidence from patent transfers 创新的可让渡性:来自专利转让的证据
3区 经济学 Q1 Economics, Econometrics and Finance Pub Date : 2023-09-29 DOI: 10.1080/10438599.2023.2261871
Šimon Trlifaj
ABSTRACTThis paper examines the conceptualization of innovation as a public good using an empirical analysis of patent transfers. It proposes that patents make inventions both excludable and alienable, in contrast to secrecy which only makes them excludable. A survival analysis finds that 10% higher complexity of patent descriptions is associated with 9% higher patent transfer hazard. This suggests that inventors more often patent complex inventions for the alienability motive – as opposed to the excludability motive. Small inventors transfer their patents less likely, but they do so sooner than other inventors. This suggests that patents enable an exchange of inventions that would otherwise be kept secret, but small inventors may not benefit from this function disproportionately more than others. These findings have implications for the conceptualization of innovation.KEYWORDS: Innovationpatentssecrecyalienabilityexcludabilitypublic goods Disclosure statementNo potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s).Notes1 Appropriability defined as the ability to protect the firm's competitive advantage from its inventions in the prior three years (Cohen, Nelson, and Walsh Citation2000, p. 5).2 Arrow (Citation1962) generalizes the observation to information, while this paper focuses on innovation.3 Akcigit, Alp Celik, and Greenwood (Citation2016) model an extreme scenario where patented are not transferable. Although this is sub-optimal for patents, it is the case of some intellectual property rights. Copyright may not be re-sold in some countries (WIPO Citation2016). Regional agricultural indicators, such as those on the Parmigiano Reggiano cheese, may not be licensed or sold to producers outside a specific region (WTO Citation1994).4 Private email communication with the USPTO, available from the author upon request.5 For consistency, micro-entities, introduced in 2013, are treated as small entities (see USPTO Citation2020, for details).
摘要本文通过对专利转让的实证分析,探讨了创新作为一种公共产品的概念。它提出,专利使发明具有排他性和可让渡性,而保密只使发明具有排他性。生存分析发现,专利描述复杂性增加10%,专利转移风险增加9%。这表明,发明人更多地是出于可让与性动机而非可排他性动机为复杂发明申请专利。小型发明人转让专利的可能性较小,但他们比其他发明人做得更快。这表明,专利使原本保密的发明得以交换,但小发明家可能不会比其他人更不成比例地从这一功能中受益。这些发现对创新的概念化具有启示意义。关键词:创新专利、机密性、可让与性、排他性、公共产品披露声明作者未报告潜在利益冲突。注1可挪用性被定义为保护公司在前三年的发明中获得竞争优势的能力(Cohen, Nelson, and Walsh Citation2000, p. 5)Arrow (Citation1962)将观察概括为信息,而本文则侧重于创新Akcigit、Alp Celik和Greenwood (Citation2016)模拟了一种极端情况,即专利不可转让。尽管这对于专利来说不是最优的,但对于某些知识产权来说却是如此。在某些国家,版权不得转售(WIPO Citation2016)。区域农业指标,如帕尔马干酪上的指标,不得许可或出售给特定区域以外的生产者(WTO引文1994)与USPTO的私人电子邮件通信,可应作者要求提供为了一致性,2013年引入的微实体被视为小实体(详见USPTO Citation2020)。
{"title":"The alienability of innovation: evidence from patent transfers","authors":"Šimon Trlifaj","doi":"10.1080/10438599.2023.2261871","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1080/10438599.2023.2261871","url":null,"abstract":"ABSTRACTThis paper examines the conceptualization of innovation as a public good using an empirical analysis of patent transfers. It proposes that patents make inventions both excludable and alienable, in contrast to secrecy which only makes them excludable. A survival analysis finds that 10% higher complexity of patent descriptions is associated with 9% higher patent transfer hazard. This suggests that inventors more often patent complex inventions for the alienability motive – as opposed to the excludability motive. Small inventors transfer their patents less likely, but they do so sooner than other inventors. This suggests that patents enable an exchange of inventions that would otherwise be kept secret, but small inventors may not benefit from this function disproportionately more than others. These findings have implications for the conceptualization of innovation.KEYWORDS: Innovationpatentssecrecyalienabilityexcludabilitypublic goods Disclosure statementNo potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s).Notes1 Appropriability defined as the ability to protect the firm's competitive advantage from its inventions in the prior three years (Cohen, Nelson, and Walsh Citation2000, p. 5).2 Arrow (Citation1962) generalizes the observation to information, while this paper focuses on innovation.3 Akcigit, Alp Celik, and Greenwood (Citation2016) model an extreme scenario where patented are not transferable. Although this is sub-optimal for patents, it is the case of some intellectual property rights. Copyright may not be re-sold in some countries (WIPO Citation2016). Regional agricultural indicators, such as those on the Parmigiano Reggiano cheese, may not be licensed or sold to producers outside a specific region (WTO Citation1994).4 Private email communication with the USPTO, available from the author upon request.5 For consistency, micro-entities, introduced in 2013, are treated as small entities (see USPTO Citation2020, for details).","PeriodicalId":51485,"journal":{"name":"Economics of Innovation and New Technology","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2023-09-29","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"135199343","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
IPO underpricing and corporate innovation: evidence from China IPO定价过低与企业创新:来自中国的证据
3区 经济学 Q1 Economics, Econometrics and Finance Pub Date : 2023-09-19 DOI: 10.1080/10438599.2023.2258355
Di Wu, Qifeng Zhao
ABSTRACTThe functions of the stock market such as investment exit mechanism (IPO), interest incentive and capital allocation are beneficial for corporate to engage in innovation activities with higher risk and longer cycle, but IPO underpricing will hinder the realization of such functions. This paper uses the fixed effect model for empirical analysis and finds that the long-term innovation performance of corporate s with IPO underpricing is poor. Mechanism analysis shows that IPO underpricing corporates will have management myopia, lack of R&D enthusiasm that inhibit corporate innovation. Further analysis shows that the improvement of corporate information transparency and institutional investor field research can alleviate this negative impact can alleviate this negative impact. The conclusion of this paper aims to improve efficiency of the capital market, promote the effective pricing of the capital market, and provide certain reference significance for the relevant policies of the capital market to support the high-quality development of the real economy.KEYWORDS: Corporate innovationIPO underpricingmanagement myopiaR&D enthusiasmcorporate information transparencyJEL CLASSIFICATION: G32O31 Disclosure statementNo potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s).Additional informationFundingQifeng Zhao acknowledges support from the National Natural Science Foundation of China [grant number 72302229]; Di Wu acknowledges support from the Social Science Planning Fund Program, Shandong Province [grant number 22DGLJ13].
【摘要】股票市场的投资退出机制(IPO)、利息激励和资本配置等功能有利于企业从事风险较高、周期较长的创新活动,但IPO定价过低会阻碍这些功能的实现。本文运用固定效应模型进行实证分析,发现IPO定价过低的企业长期创新绩效较差。机制分析表明,IPO定价过低的企业会产生管理短视、研发积极性不足,从而抑制企业创新。进一步分析表明,提高公司信息透明度和机构投资者实地调研可以缓解这种负面影响,可以缓解这种负面影响。本文的结论旨在提高资本市场的效率,促进资本市场的有效定价,为资本市场相关政策支持实体经济高质量发展提供一定的参考意义。关键词:企业创新ipo抑价管理myopic研发热情企业信息透明度jel分类:G32O31披露声明作者未报告潜在利益冲突赵启峰感谢中国国家自然科学基金资助项目[批准号:72302229];吴迪感谢山东省社会科学规划基金项目[批准号:22DGLJ13]的资助。
{"title":"IPO underpricing and corporate innovation: evidence from China","authors":"Di Wu, Qifeng Zhao","doi":"10.1080/10438599.2023.2258355","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1080/10438599.2023.2258355","url":null,"abstract":"ABSTRACTThe functions of the stock market such as investment exit mechanism (IPO), interest incentive and capital allocation are beneficial for corporate to engage in innovation activities with higher risk and longer cycle, but IPO underpricing will hinder the realization of such functions. This paper uses the fixed effect model for empirical analysis and finds that the long-term innovation performance of corporate s with IPO underpricing is poor. Mechanism analysis shows that IPO underpricing corporates will have management myopia, lack of R&D enthusiasm that inhibit corporate innovation. Further analysis shows that the improvement of corporate information transparency and institutional investor field research can alleviate this negative impact can alleviate this negative impact. The conclusion of this paper aims to improve efficiency of the capital market, promote the effective pricing of the capital market, and provide certain reference significance for the relevant policies of the capital market to support the high-quality development of the real economy.KEYWORDS: Corporate innovationIPO underpricingmanagement myopiaR&D enthusiasmcorporate information transparencyJEL CLASSIFICATION: G32O31 Disclosure statementNo potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s).Additional informationFundingQifeng Zhao acknowledges support from the National Natural Science Foundation of China [grant number 72302229]; Di Wu acknowledges support from the Social Science Planning Fund Program, Shandong Province [grant number 22DGLJ13].","PeriodicalId":51485,"journal":{"name":"Economics of Innovation and New Technology","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2023-09-19","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"135014882","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Unanticipated consequences: concerns about the sale of taxpayer-funded technologies to foreign entities 意想不到的后果:担心纳税人资助的技术被卖给外国实体
3区 经济学 Q1 Economics, Econometrics and Finance Pub Date : 2023-09-15 DOI: 10.1080/10438599.2023.2258065
Albert N. Link, Christopher A. Swann
ABSTRACTAn unanticipated consequence from the U.S. Small Business Innovation Research (SBIR) program is the propensity of U.S. firms to sell their SBIR-funded and developed technology rights to foreign entities. While such sales are factually documented in reports from both the U.S. National Academies and from the Department of Defense, the U.S. Congress has only recently shown concern about such activity. Using project-level data, we document the extent of foreign sales of technology rights. We also highlight the role of foreign development funding during the commercialization phase. Our statistical analysis finds a positive association between the probability of selling technology rights to foreign firms or investors and the receipt of foreign development funding. This finding might be a bellwether to the U.S. Congress and to other countries that have adopted programs that mirror the U.S. program.KEYWORDS: SBIR programsale of technology rightsforeign development fundingR&DJEL CODES: H11H32H44 Authorship Contribution StatementBoth authors contributed equally at all stages of this study.Disclosure statementNo potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s).Notes1 See https://www.nber.org/research/data/us-business-cycle-expansions-and-contractions.2 This act is one of a number of Congressional responses to the productivity slowdown in the economy that began in the early – to mid-1970 and raised its head again in the early 1980s.3 See also Bastiat (original Citation1848, Citation1995, 1) who wrote: ‘There is only one difference between a bad economist and a good one: the bad economist confines himself to the visible effect; the good economist takes into account both the effect that can be seen and those effects that must be foreseen. Yet this difference is tremendous; for it almost always happens that when the immediate consequence is favorable, the later consequences are disastrous, and vice versa. Whence it follows that the bad economist pursues a small present good that will be followed by a great evil to come, while the good economist pursues a great good to come, at the risk of a small present evil.'4 Unanticipated consequences associated with a legislated subsidy, such as the SBIR program, are not necessarily at odds with the concept of government failure for which the rules set by government are too broad (Dolfsma Citation2011).5 These countries, and the date of the enabling legislation, are: Republic of Turkey (1995), Australia (1996), Brazil (1997), South Korea (1998), Japan (1999), Taiwan (1999), United Kingdom (2001), The Netherlands (2004), and New Zealand (2012). A detailed summary of the programs in each of these countries is forthcoming in a special issue of Annals of Science and Technology Policy.6 For example, Cunningham and Link (Citation2021, 40) wrote that a comparable program in the United Kingdom is the Small Business Research Initiative (SBRI), and it was initiated in 2001 to mirror the U.S. SBIR program. The aut
摘要美国小企业创新研究(SBIR)项目带来的一个意想不到的后果是,美国企业倾向于将其由SBIR资助和开发的技术权利出售给外国实体。尽管美国国家科学院和国防部的报告中都有此类销售的事实记录,但美国国会直到最近才对此类活动表示担忧。使用项目级数据,我们记录了技术权利对外销售的程度。我们还强调外国发展资金在商业化阶段的作用。我们的统计分析发现,向外国公司或投资者出售技术权利的概率与获得外国发展资金之间存在正相关关系。这一发现可能是美国国会和其他国家的一个领头羊,他们已经采取了反映美国计划的计划。关键词:SBIR项目技术权利销售国外发展基金gr&djel代码:H11H32H44作者贡献声明两位作者在本研究的各个阶段贡献相同。披露声明作者未报告潜在的利益冲突。注1参见https://www.nber.org/research/data/us-business-cycle-expansions-and-contractions.2该法案是国会对1970年代初至中期开始并在1980年代初再次抬头的经济生产率放缓的一系列反应之一参见巴斯夏(原Citation1848, Citation1995, 1),他写道:“坏经济学家和好经济学家之间只有一个区别:坏经济学家把自己局限于可见的效果;优秀的经济学家既会考虑看得见的影响,也会考虑必须预见到的影响。然而,这种差异是巨大的;因为当眼前的结果是有利的时候,后来的结果几乎总是灾难性的,反之亦然。由此可见,坏经济学家追求的是眼前的小善,随之而来的是未来的大恶;而好经济学家追求未来的大善,却冒着眼前的小恶的风险。4与立法补贴相关的意外后果,如SBIR计划,不一定与政府失灵的概念不一致,因为政府制定的规则过于宽泛(Dolfsma Citation2011)这些国家和授权立法的日期分别是:土耳其共和国(1995年)、澳大利亚(1996年)、巴西(1997年)、韩国(1998年)、日本(1999年)、台湾(1999年)、英国(2001年)、荷兰(2004年)和新西兰(2012年)。这些国家的项目的详细总结即将在《科技政策年鉴》的特刊中发表。6例如,坎宁安和林克(Citation2021, 40)写道,英国的一个类似项目是小企业研究计划(SBRI),该计划于2001年启动,以反映美国的SBIR计划。作者声称,英国计划最初是一个“重大失败”,但它被修改并重新启动,以支持英国公司之间的技术发展林克和斯科特(Citation2012, 375)更广泛地研究了这个问题,但以一种纯粹描述性的方式,他们得出结论:“与这些项目相关的技术在很大程度上并没有使外国公司受益……”在本文中,我们关注技术转让的一个具体方面,并将项目特征与此类转让联系起来;而且,我们没有考虑国内与国外互动的相对重要性,而是从这样一个概念开始,即任何转移都可能被视为一种意想不到的后果,可能被视为不受欢迎的见NRC (Citation2009)表4.13及其他附表具体参见NRC (Citation2008)中的图7.1和其他附表除了国防部和能源部的报告(NRC Citation2009;Citation2008), NRC为NASA、国家卫生研究院和国家科学基金会发表了类似的研究。每一份报告都提到向外国公司出售技术权利《华尔街日报》也报道了这些事件(O 'Keeffe Citation2022年5月8日)技术权利销售一词是指与专利或专利申请未涵盖的技术有关的任何信息,包括但不限于技术和非技术信息、专有技术、方法、工艺、程序、组合物、装置、配方、协议、技术、软件、设计、图纸、计划、图表、规格、数据、测试或分析结果。以及与该技术有关的所有其他信息(https://www.lawinsider.com/dictionary/technology-rights)。向外国公司和投资者出售技术权利,从广义上讲,是一种技术转让形式,尽管它不可能是1982年法案起草者所设想的预期的技术转让。 最近,在巴拉克·奥巴马总统的《2011年总统备忘录——加速联邦研究的技术转让和商业化以支持高增长企业》和唐纳德·特朗普总统的《总统管理议程》(Citation2018)的推动下,公共资助的技术本身的国内转让受到了很大的重视。在第一阶段,机构征求合同提案或拨款申请,以进行与可行性相关的实验或理论研究或与机构要求相关的研发(R/R&D)。第一阶段拨款旨在确定“具有商业潜力的想法的科学和技术价值和可行性”。“第二阶段的拨款旨在进一步推动第一阶段启动的研发工作,以满足特定的项目需求,并显示出商业应用的潜力。一般而言,只有第一阶段的受助人才有资格申请第二阶段的补助金。第二阶段的奖励将基于第一阶段取得的成果(如适用),以及第二阶段提出的项目的科学技术价值和商业潜力,证明如下:小企业成功将SBIR或其他研究商业化的记录;是否存在来自私营部门或非sbir供资来源的第二阶段供资承诺;研究课题是否存在第三阶段、后续承诺;以及该想法商业潜力的其他指标的存在(Citation2022, 4-5)见上文脚注1311个公共部门机构和组织目前参与了SBIR计划。它们是(按字母顺序排列):农业部(USDA)、商务部(DOC)、国防部(DOD)、教育部(ED)、能源部(DOE)、卫生与公众服务部(HHS)、国土安全部(DHS)、交通部(DOT)、环境保护局(EPA)、美国国家航空航天局(NASA)和国家科学基金会(NSF)。最近关于SBIR计划的详细讨论见于林克和范哈瑟尔特(Citation2023)除了员工数量之外,还有其他三个资格要求。该公司必须是营利性组织,在美国有营业地点,并且由一个或多个美国公民或永久居民外国人拥有和控制50%以上(或由一个或多个美国公民或永久居民外国人拥有和控制50%以上的其他小型企业)。参见《联邦法规》(13 CFR§121.702)。参见Gallo (Citation2022)截至2021年11月,6个月一期项目的法定上限为275,766美元,没有机构寻求小企业管理局的豁免,2年二期项目的上限为1,838,436美元,没有机构寻求小企业管理局的豁免(Gallo Citation2022) 18第(3)点目前是:“(3)培养和鼓励妇女和社会或经济上处于不利地位的人参与创新和创业。19 .该法案还延长了1992年开始实施的小企业技术转让(STTR)计划。参见链接(Citation2023).20在美国国家科学院对2012财年国防授权法案(公法112-81)的持续评估中,国会再次要求NRC研究SBIR和STTR项目。结果是2011年的数据库和2014年的数据库,Link和van Hasselt (Citation2023)对此进行了描述。本文使用了2005年数据库,因为它包含了第二期奖励金额的信息。为确保答复公司的机密性,该信息在2011年数据库或2014年数据库中不可用在我们的分析中,我们认为最后的和正在进行的谈判都是技术销售自变量的数量受到NRC数据库中可用信息的限制。然而,考虑的变量通常是研究SBIR程序的其他作者使用过的变量。参见Link and van Hasselt (Citation2023).23美国核管理委员会的数据库中
{"title":"Unanticipated consequences: concerns about the sale of taxpayer-funded technologies to foreign entities","authors":"Albert N. Link, Christopher A. Swann","doi":"10.1080/10438599.2023.2258065","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1080/10438599.2023.2258065","url":null,"abstract":"ABSTRACTAn unanticipated consequence from the U.S. Small Business Innovation Research (SBIR) program is the propensity of U.S. firms to sell their SBIR-funded and developed technology rights to foreign entities. While such sales are factually documented in reports from both the U.S. National Academies and from the Department of Defense, the U.S. Congress has only recently shown concern about such activity. Using project-level data, we document the extent of foreign sales of technology rights. We also highlight the role of foreign development funding during the commercialization phase. Our statistical analysis finds a positive association between the probability of selling technology rights to foreign firms or investors and the receipt of foreign development funding. This finding might be a bellwether to the U.S. Congress and to other countries that have adopted programs that mirror the U.S. program.KEYWORDS: SBIR programsale of technology rightsforeign development fundingR&DJEL CODES: H11H32H44 Authorship Contribution StatementBoth authors contributed equally at all stages of this study.Disclosure statementNo potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s).Notes1 See https://www.nber.org/research/data/us-business-cycle-expansions-and-contractions.2 This act is one of a number of Congressional responses to the productivity slowdown in the economy that began in the early – to mid-1970 and raised its head again in the early 1980s.3 See also Bastiat (original Citation1848, Citation1995, 1) who wrote: ‘There is only one difference between a bad economist and a good one: the bad economist confines himself to the visible effect; the good economist takes into account both the effect that can be seen and those effects that must be foreseen. Yet this difference is tremendous; for it almost always happens that when the immediate consequence is favorable, the later consequences are disastrous, and vice versa. Whence it follows that the bad economist pursues a small present good that will be followed by a great evil to come, while the good economist pursues a great good to come, at the risk of a small present evil.'4 Unanticipated consequences associated with a legislated subsidy, such as the SBIR program, are not necessarily at odds with the concept of government failure for which the rules set by government are too broad (Dolfsma Citation2011).5 These countries, and the date of the enabling legislation, are: Republic of Turkey (1995), Australia (1996), Brazil (1997), South Korea (1998), Japan (1999), Taiwan (1999), United Kingdom (2001), The Netherlands (2004), and New Zealand (2012). A detailed summary of the programs in each of these countries is forthcoming in a special issue of Annals of Science and Technology Policy.6 For example, Cunningham and Link (Citation2021, 40) wrote that a comparable program in the United Kingdom is the Small Business Research Initiative (SBRI), and it was initiated in 2001 to mirror the U.S. SBIR program. The aut","PeriodicalId":51485,"journal":{"name":"Economics of Innovation and New Technology","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2023-09-15","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"135396759","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Cross-ownership on R&D and welfare in a mixed oligopoly: revisiting with convex cost 混合寡头垄断下研发与福利的交叉所有权:凸成本的重新审视
3区 经济学 Q1 Economics, Econometrics and Finance Pub Date : 2023-09-13 DOI: 10.1080/10438599.2023.2255975
Hao Cheng, Xiaoyuan Ding, Chenhang Zeng
This paper revisits how private cross-ownership affects cost-reducing R&D, production quantities, consumer surplus, firms’ profits and social welfare in a mixed oligopoly with a convex cost function. We show that increasing cross-ownership reduces private firms’ R&D but increases the semi-public firm’s R&D. Further, both consumer surplus and social welfare could be enhanced through cross-ownership when the convexity of cost function is small. However, increasing cross-ownership could hurt consumers and social welfare when the convexity of cost function is large. Our finding highlights that the convexity of cost function is very important to the welfare implications of cross-ownership. Hence, antitrust authorities should be more careful when assessing the welfare effects of partial ownership in different industries.
本文重新考察了具有凸成本函数的混合寡头垄断下私人交叉所有制如何影响降低成本的研发、生产数量、消费者剩余、企业利润和社会福利。研究表明,交叉持股的增加降低了民营企业的研发投入,但增加了半上市企业的研发投入。此外,当成本函数的凸度较小时,通过交叉所有制可以提高消费者剩余和社会福利。然而,当成本函数的凸度较大时,交叉所有权的增加会损害消费者和社会福利。我们的发现强调了成本函数的凸性对交叉持股的福利影响是非常重要的。因此,反垄断当局在评估不同行业的部分所有权对福利的影响时应该更加谨慎。
{"title":"Cross-ownership on R&D and welfare in a mixed oligopoly: revisiting with convex cost","authors":"Hao Cheng, Xiaoyuan Ding, Chenhang Zeng","doi":"10.1080/10438599.2023.2255975","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1080/10438599.2023.2255975","url":null,"abstract":"This paper revisits how private cross-ownership affects cost-reducing R&D, production quantities, consumer surplus, firms’ profits and social welfare in a mixed oligopoly with a convex cost function. We show that increasing cross-ownership reduces private firms’ R&D but increases the semi-public firm’s R&D. Further, both consumer surplus and social welfare could be enhanced through cross-ownership when the convexity of cost function is small. However, increasing cross-ownership could hurt consumers and social welfare when the convexity of cost function is large. Our finding highlights that the convexity of cost function is very important to the welfare implications of cross-ownership. Hence, antitrust authorities should be more careful when assessing the welfare effects of partial ownership in different industries.","PeriodicalId":51485,"journal":{"name":"Economics of Innovation and New Technology","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2023-09-13","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"135740561","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
The U-shaped relationship between patent age and patent value: evidence from assigned patents in China 专利年龄与专利价值的U型关系——来自中国转让专利的证据
IF 3.3 3区 经济学 Q1 Economics, Econometrics and Finance Pub Date : 2023-09-07 DOI: 10.1080/10438599.2023.2255978
Li-ming Li, Yu-Hang Liu, Ya-feng Zhang
{"title":"The U-shaped relationship between patent age and patent value: evidence from assigned patents in China","authors":"Li-ming Li, Yu-Hang Liu, Ya-feng Zhang","doi":"10.1080/10438599.2023.2255978","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1080/10438599.2023.2255978","url":null,"abstract":"","PeriodicalId":51485,"journal":{"name":"Economics of Innovation and New Technology","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":3.3,"publicationDate":"2023-09-07","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"41857857","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Complementarity between product and process innovation in small and micro-enterprises in Johannesburg, South Africa 南非约翰内斯堡小微企业产品和工艺创新的互补性
IF 3.3 3区 经济学 Q1 Economics, Econometrics and Finance Pub Date : 2023-09-05 DOI: 10.1080/10438599.2023.2254241
Godfrey Kamutando, Fiona Tregenna
{"title":"Complementarity between product and process innovation in small and micro-enterprises in Johannesburg, South Africa","authors":"Godfrey Kamutando, Fiona Tregenna","doi":"10.1080/10438599.2023.2254241","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1080/10438599.2023.2254241","url":null,"abstract":"","PeriodicalId":51485,"journal":{"name":"Economics of Innovation and New Technology","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":3.3,"publicationDate":"2023-09-05","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"48841329","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
期刊
Economics of Innovation and New Technology
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1