首页 > 最新文献

Employee benefits journal最新文献

英文 中文
How do the Labor Market Values of Managerial Traits Evolve? 管理特质的劳动力市场价值是如何演变的?
Pub Date : 2018-07-15 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.2547738
Si Li, M. F. Perez
How do the labor market values of executives’ personal traits evolve over time? We propose and estimate an interactive fixed effects model, which allows for time-variant valuation of unobserved manager attributes. We find that managerial talent is the most important unobserved trait determining compensation. The pay premium based on each talent decile has significant time variation that co-moves with the stock market. Such pay premium is concentrated among top talented managers, with executives at the median level of talent earning $241,000 total pay premium and those at the top talent decile earning $1,136,000. We also identify a second economically important executive trait, and this trait is related to managerial cautiousness or risk aversion. The pay premium of this trait is linked to the time variation in the equity market risk premium, with cautiousness being discounted (compensated) during the low (high) risk premium period.
高管个人特质的劳动力市场价值是如何随时间演变的?我们提出并估计了一个交互式固定效应模型,该模型允许对未观察到的经理属性进行时变估值。我们发现,管理人才是决定薪酬最重要的未被观察到的特质。基于每个人才十分位数的薪酬溢价具有显著的时间变化,并与股市同步波动。这种薪酬溢价集中在顶级人才管理人员中,人才水平中位数的高管总薪酬溢价为24.1万美元,而人才水平最高的高管总薪酬溢价为113.6万美元。我们还确定了第二个经济上重要的执行特征,这一特征与管理谨慎或风险厌恶有关。这一特征的薪酬溢价与股票市场风险溢价的时间变化有关,在低(高)风险溢价时期,谨慎性被贴现(补偿)。
{"title":"How do the Labor Market Values of Managerial Traits Evolve?","authors":"Si Li, M. F. Perez","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.2547738","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2547738","url":null,"abstract":"How do the labor market values of executives’ personal traits evolve over time? We propose and estimate an interactive fixed effects model, which allows for time-variant valuation of unobserved manager attributes. We find that managerial talent is the most important unobserved trait determining compensation. The pay premium based on each talent decile has significant time variation that co-moves with the stock market. Such pay premium is concentrated among top talented managers, with executives at the median level of talent earning $241,000 total pay premium and those at the top talent decile earning $1,136,000. We also identify a second economically important executive trait, and this trait is related to managerial cautiousness or risk aversion. The pay premium of this trait is linked to the time variation in the equity market risk premium, with cautiousness being discounted (compensated) during the low (high) risk premium period.","PeriodicalId":76903,"journal":{"name":"Employee benefits journal","volume":"28 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2018-07-15","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"80366809","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Can Strong Corporate Governance Selectively Mitigate the Negative Influence of 'Special Interest' Shareholder Activists? Evidence from the Labor Market for Directors 强有力的公司治理能选择性地减轻“特殊利益”股东积极分子的负面影响吗?来自董事劳动力市场的证据
Pub Date : 2018-06-21 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.2448920
Diane Del Guercio, Tracie Woidtke
The motivation behind labor union and public pension fund activism is widely debated. We posit that activism motivated by private benefits primarily arises when there is a firm-specific conflict of interest, such as when a union activist also represents workers in collective bargaining negotiations. We provide evidence that the labor market for directorships mitigates the negative effect of “special interest” activism on other shareholders. Specifically, directors who cater to self-serving requests are punished with a loss in directorships and damage to their reputation as corporate monitors. Moreover, we provide insight into when boards are most vulnerable to “special interest” pressure.
工会和公共年金运动背后的动机备受争议。我们假设,由私人利益驱动的行动主义主要出现在公司特定利益冲突的情况下,例如当工会活动家在集体谈判中也代表工人时。我们提供的证据表明,董事职位的劳动力市场减轻了“特殊利益”行动主义对其他股东的负面影响。具体来说,迎合自私自利要求的董事受到的惩罚是失去董事职位,并损害他们作为公司监督者的声誉。此外,我们还深入分析了董事会何时最容易受到“特殊利益”压力的影响。
{"title":"Can Strong Corporate Governance Selectively Mitigate the Negative Influence of 'Special Interest' Shareholder Activists? Evidence from the Labor Market for Directors","authors":"Diane Del Guercio, Tracie Woidtke","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.2448920","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2448920","url":null,"abstract":"The motivation behind labor union and public pension fund activism is widely debated. We posit that activism motivated by private benefits primarily arises when there is a firm-specific conflict of interest, such as when a union activist also represents workers in collective bargaining negotiations. We provide evidence that the labor market for directorships mitigates the negative effect of “special interest” activism on other shareholders. Specifically, directors who cater to self-serving requests are punished with a loss in directorships and damage to their reputation as corporate monitors. Moreover, we provide insight into when boards are most vulnerable to “special interest” pressure.","PeriodicalId":76903,"journal":{"name":"Employee benefits journal","volume":"34 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2018-06-21","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"76912662","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 11
Central States Pension Fund: Department of Labor Activities Under the Consent Decree and Federal Law 中央各州养恤基金:同意法令和联邦法律下的劳动活动部
Pub Date : 2018-06-04 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.3191291
Charles A. Jeszeck, D. Lehrer, Margaret Weber, L. Beedon, Charles J Ford, Jessica Moscovitch, Layla Moughari, Joseph Silvestri, Anjali Tekchandani, F. Todisco, Adam Wendel
The Central States, Southeast and Southwest Areas Pension Fund (CSPF) was established in 1955 to provide pension benefits to trucking industry workers and is one of the largest multiemployer plans. According to its regulatory filings, CSPF had less than half the estimated funds needed to cover plan liabilities in 1982 at the time it entered into a court-enforceable consent decree that provides for oversight of certain plan activities. Since then, CSPF has made some progress toward achieving its targeted level of funding; however, CSPF has never been more than 75 percent funded and its funding level has weakened since 2002. Stakeholders GAO interviewed identified numerous factors that contributed to CSPF's financial condition. For example, stakeholders stated that changes within the trucking industry, as well as a decline in union membership, contributed to CSPF's inability to maintain a healthy contribution base. CSPF's active participants made up about 69 percent of all participants in 1982, but accounted for only 16 percent in 2016. The most dramatic change in active participants occurred in 2007 when the United Parcel Service, Inc. (UPS) withdrew from the plan. At that time, UPS accounted for about 30 percent of the plan's active participants (i.e. workers). In addition, the market declines of 2001 to 2002 and 2008 had a significant negative impact on the plan's long-term investment performance. Stakeholders noted that, while each individual factor contributed to CSPF's critical financial condition, the interrelated nature of the factors also had a cumulative effect on the plan's financial condition. The 1982 consent decree between the U.S. Department of Labor (DOL) and CSPF came about as a result of an investigation of alleged breaches of fiduciary duty and mismanagement of plan assets, and is intended to prevent their reoccurrence. In addition to reiterating the requirement that the plan comply with the Employee Retirement Income Security Act of 1974 (ERISA)—the primary law governing the treatment of private-sector pensions in the United States—the consent decree further outlines requirements for the plan to help ensure fiduciary controls and plan management, including seeking court approvals for the appointment of new trustees and changes to the plan's investment policy. The consent decree also delineates roles for DOL and other stakeholders. For example, it allows DOL to object to or comment on certain proposed plan actions, but does not require the agency to do so. GAO's review of plan documents found that the agency provided oversight and technical assistance in the areas specifically identified for its involvement under the consent decree, such as vetting proposed trustees prior to the court's approval. DOL is primarily responsible for enforcing the reporting, disclosure, and fiduciary provisions of ERISA for all tax-qualified pension plans, including CSPF. ERISA sets forth a “prudent man standard of care” in the execution of fiducia
中央邦、东南和西南地区养老基金(CSPF)成立于1955年,为卡车运输业工人提供养老金福利,是最大的多雇主计划之一。根据其提交给监管机构的文件,1982年,当公积金基金与法院达成一项可强制执行的同意令,规定对某些计划活动进行监督时,它所拥有的估计资金还不到覆盖计划负债所需资金的一半。从那时起,公积金基金在实现其目标资金水平方面取得了一些进展;然而,公积金基金的资助从未超过75%,其资助水平自2002年以来有所下降。政府问责局采访的利益相关者确定了影响公积金财务状况的许多因素。例如,利益攸关方指出,卡车运输业内部的变化以及工会会员的减少,导致社保基金无法维持健康的缴费基础。1982年,CSPF的活跃参与者约占所有参与者的69%,但2016年仅占16%。最引人注目的变化发生在2007年,当时联合包裹服务公司(UPS)退出了该计划。当时,UPS约占该计划积极参与者(即工人)的30%。此外,2001年至2002年和2008年的市场下跌对该计划的长期投资业绩产生了显著的负面影响。利益攸关方指出,虽然每个单独的因素都对公积金计划的关键财务状况有所贡献,但这些因素的相互关联性质也对计划的财务状况产生累积影响。1982年美国劳工部(DOL)和CSPF之间的同意法令是对涉嫌违反信托义务和计划资产管理不善的调查的结果,旨在防止此类事件再次发生。除了重申该计划必须遵守1974年《雇员退休收入保障法》(ERISA)——美国管理私营部门养老金待遇的主要法律——的要求外,同意令还进一步概述了该计划的要求,以帮助确保信托控制和计划管理,包括寻求法院批准任命新的受托人和改变计划的投资政策。同意令还描述了DOL和其他利益相关者的角色。例如,它允许劳工部反对或评论某些拟议的计划行动,但不要求该机构这样做。政府问责局对计划文件的审查发现,该机构在同意令明确规定其参与的领域提供了监督和技术援助,例如在法院批准之前审查拟议的受托人。美国劳工部主要负责执行ERISA的报告、披露和信托条款,适用于所有符合税收条件的养老金计划,包括CSPF。根据DOL的规定,ERISA规定了在执行信托责任时的“谨慎人标准”,该标准侧重于做出适当信托决定的过程。计划受托人负责选择和监督投资经理,但通常不对这些经理的个人投资决策负责。为执行该条例,劳工处会进行检查和调查。自同意令成立以来,DOL官员报告说,该机构已经完成了对CSPF的两次调查。这两项调查分别于1998年和2004年完成,没有发现反对该计划的不利结果。除了这些机构的监督作用之外,劳工部还与CSPF和其他机构合作,采取措施改善该计划的财务状况,包括参与拟议立法的讨论,并与CSPF合作,根据2014年《多雇主养老金改革法案》(multi - employer Pension Reform Act of 2014)减少福利。该申请没有得到美国财政部的批准。
{"title":"Central States Pension Fund: Department of Labor Activities Under the Consent Decree and Federal Law","authors":"Charles A. Jeszeck, D. Lehrer, Margaret Weber, L. Beedon, Charles J Ford, Jessica Moscovitch, Layla Moughari, Joseph Silvestri, Anjali Tekchandani, F. Todisco, Adam Wendel","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.3191291","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.3191291","url":null,"abstract":"The Central States, Southeast and Southwest Areas Pension Fund (CSPF) was established in 1955 to provide pension benefits to trucking industry workers and is one of the largest multiemployer plans. According to its regulatory filings, CSPF had less than half the estimated funds needed to cover plan liabilities in 1982 at the time it entered into a court-enforceable consent decree that provides for oversight of certain plan activities. Since then, CSPF has made some progress toward achieving its targeted level of funding; however, CSPF has never been more than 75 percent funded and its funding level has weakened since 2002. \u0000Stakeholders GAO interviewed identified numerous factors that contributed to CSPF's financial condition. For example, stakeholders stated that changes within the trucking industry, as well as a decline in union membership, contributed to CSPF's inability to maintain a healthy contribution base. CSPF's active participants made up about 69 percent of all participants in 1982, but accounted for only 16 percent in 2016. The most dramatic change in active participants occurred in 2007 when the United Parcel Service, Inc. (UPS) withdrew from the plan. At that time, UPS accounted for about 30 percent of the plan's active participants (i.e. workers). In addition, the market declines of 2001 to 2002 and 2008 had a significant negative impact on the plan's long-term investment performance. Stakeholders noted that, while each individual factor contributed to CSPF's critical financial condition, the interrelated nature of the factors also had a cumulative effect on the plan's financial condition. \u0000The 1982 consent decree between the U.S. Department of Labor (DOL) and CSPF came about as a result of an investigation of alleged breaches of fiduciary duty and mismanagement of plan assets, and is intended to prevent their reoccurrence. In addition to reiterating the requirement that the plan comply with the Employee Retirement Income Security Act of 1974 (ERISA)—the primary law governing the treatment of private-sector pensions in the United States—the consent decree further outlines requirements for the plan to help ensure fiduciary controls and plan management, including seeking court approvals for the appointment of new trustees and changes to the plan's investment policy. The consent decree also delineates roles for DOL and other stakeholders. For example, it allows DOL to object to or comment on certain proposed plan actions, but does not require the agency to do so. GAO's review of plan documents found that the agency provided oversight and technical assistance in the areas specifically identified for its involvement under the consent decree, such as vetting proposed trustees prior to the court's approval. \u0000DOL is primarily responsible for enforcing the reporting, disclosure, and fiduciary provisions of ERISA for all tax-qualified pension plans, including CSPF. ERISA sets forth a “prudent man standard of care” in the execution of fiducia","PeriodicalId":76903,"journal":{"name":"Employee benefits journal","volume":"53 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2018-06-04","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"78092409","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Fiduciary Principles in Trust Law 信托法中的信义原则
Pub Date : 2018-03-26 DOI: 10.1093/OXFORDHB/9780190634100.013.3
Robert H. Sitkoff
This chapter canvasses the fiduciary principles applicable to a trustee of a donative, irrevocable private trust. The focus is on American law. The chapter examines: (1) the trigger for finding a trust fiduciary relationship and the scope of that relationship; (2) the duty of loyalty; (3) the duty of prudence across the distribution, investment, custodial, and administrative functions of trusteeship; (4) other fiduciary duties in trust law, including the prominent duty of impartiality and the increasingly salient duty to give information to the beneficiaries; (5) the extent to which fiduciary principles in trust law are mandatory or may be waived by the settlor or by a beneficiary; and (6) the remedies available for a breach of duty by a trustee.
本章探讨了适用于赠与性、不可撤销性私人信托的受托人的信义原则。重点是美国法律。本章主要研究:(1)信托信义关系成立的触发因素和信托信义关系的范围;(二)忠诚义务;(三)在托管的分配、投资、保管和管理职能方面的审慎义务;(四)信托法规定的其他信义义务,包括突出的公正义务和日益突出的向受益人提供信息的义务;(5)受托人或受益人在多大程度上强制放弃信托法规定的信托原则;(6)受托人违反义务的救济办法。
{"title":"Fiduciary Principles in Trust Law","authors":"Robert H. Sitkoff","doi":"10.1093/OXFORDHB/9780190634100.013.3","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1093/OXFORDHB/9780190634100.013.3","url":null,"abstract":"This chapter canvasses the fiduciary principles applicable to a trustee of a donative, irrevocable private trust. The focus is on American law. The chapter examines: (1) the trigger for finding a trust fiduciary relationship and the scope of that relationship; (2) the duty of loyalty; (3) the duty of prudence across the distribution, investment, custodial, and administrative functions of trusteeship; (4) other fiduciary duties in trust law, including the prominent duty of impartiality and the increasingly salient duty to give information to the beneficiaries; (5) the extent to which fiduciary principles in trust law are mandatory or may be waived by the settlor or by a beneficiary; and (6) the remedies available for a breach of duty by a trustee.","PeriodicalId":76903,"journal":{"name":"Employee benefits journal","volume":"59 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2018-03-26","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"75471372","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
The Time Has Come to Revisit Solvency Funding Rules 是时候重新审视偿付能力融资规则了
Pub Date : 2018-02-22 DOI: 10.11575/SPPP.V11I0.43034
N. Nielson
Canadians are not fond of hearing news about people losing their hard-earned pensions because their employer misused the money. The thought of some Working Joe or Jane being deprived of a pension, after a lifetime of working for a company, is naturally repugnant. That is why regulations around defined-benefit pension plans are designed to force employers to keep their pension funds sufficiently solvent. But there are many ways to achieve that end and, while the rules that Canadian companies must follow might serve to help preserve pension savings, they also be very expensive — to employers and regulators — compared to other policies that can do the same thing. In fact, more flexibility in the rules might even make it easier for companies to offer richer pension benefits to employees than they already do. Some of Canada’s outdated pension-funding rules have created the opposite problem: There are now pension plans that are actually overfunded if one assumes the company and the plan will continue. That means money the sponsoring companies could be using to hire more workers, to offer employees better pay and benefits, or to invest, is tied up in pension coffers. The problem lies in the divergence between a “going-concern” valuation — which assumes that the plan continues indefinitely — with the more prescriptive “solvency” valuation that is central to Canadian regulations. It examines funding adequaciy if one assumes the employer is going to go out of business (even if the vast majority of large employers are at any given time at no risk of that). In the days when fixed-income returns were lucrative, companies relied on pension fund investments to top up the funds, reducing sponsor contributions to unsafe levels. The solvency rules required plans that were reaping higher returns in the stock market to continue making some contributions to their plans. Back then, the gap between a going-concern valuation and a solvency valuation was small, and so the rules were not an unacceptable burden. Those rich returns are gone. Now, that gap between valuations has grown dramatically. In B.C., for example, a recent analysis found that when using a going-concern evaluation, 75 per cent of 143 defined-benefit plans registered in the province in 2015 had at least 100-per-cent funding, while the median funding ratio was 124 per cent. Using a solvency model, the median funding ratio was instead estimated to be a much lower 85 per cent. Closing that gap would require onerous pension contributions. More importantly, the contributions it triggers might never be needed to cover benefits. Quebec is the first province to recognize that pension-funding rules need to be revisited and made more responsive, with new rules coming in that will reduce the unnecessary burden on employers while also adapting to changes in the economic environment. Ontario is showing signs that it will take steps in the same direction. Regulators everywhere should be revisiting pension rules to: re
加拿大人不喜欢听到人们因为雇主滥用钱而失去辛苦挣来的养老金的消息。一想到有些上班族在为一家公司工作了一辈子,却被剥夺了养老金,自然会感到反感。这就是为什么围绕固定收益养老金计划的法规旨在迫使雇主保持其养老金有足够的偿付能力。但实现这一目标的方法有很多,尽管加拿大公司必须遵守的规定可能有助于保存养老金储蓄,但与其他能起到同样作用的政策相比,这些规定对雇主和监管机构来说也非常昂贵。事实上,规则的灵活性甚至可能使公司更容易向员工提供比现在更丰厚的养老金福利。加拿大一些过时的养老基金规定产生了相反的问题:如果你假设公司和养老金计划会继续下去,那么现在的养老金计划实际上是资金过剩的。这意味着,赞助公司本可以用来雇佣更多工人、为员工提供更好的薪酬和福利,或用于投资的资金,都被扣在了养老金金库里。问题在于,“持续经营”估值——假设该计划无限期持续下去——与更具指令性的“偿付能力”估值之间存在分歧,后者是加拿大监管的核心。如果假设雇主即将破产(即使绝大多数大型雇主在任何给定时间都没有破产的风险),它会检查资金是否充足。在固定收益回报丰厚的日子里,公司依靠养老基金投资来充实基金,将保荐人的贡献减少到不安全的水平。偿付能力规则要求在股市中获得较高回报的计划继续为其计划做出一些贡献。当时,持续经营估值与偿付能力估值之间的差距很小,因此这些规则并非不可接受的负担。那些丰厚的回报消失了。现在,估值之间的差距急剧扩大。例如,在不列颠哥伦比亚省,最近的一项分析发现,在使用持续经营评估时,2015年在该省注册的143个固定收益计划中,有75%的计划至少有100%的资金,而资金比率中位数为124%。使用偿付能力模型,资金比率中位数估计为85%,要想弥补这一差距,需要缴纳高额的养老金。更重要的是,它引发的缴款可能永远不需要支付福利。魁北克省是第一个认识到养老基金规则需要重新审视并做出更积极回应的省份,新规则的出台将减轻雇主不必要的负担,同时也适应经济环境的变化。有迹象表明,安大略省将朝着同样的方向采取措施。各地的监管机构都应该重新审视养老金规则:取消对资金充足计划的偿付能力估值要求,同时允许监管机构在他们认为有保证的罕见情况下假设最坏的情况;制定计划信用风险评级方法;对计划负债不那么严格,更现实(允许某些类型的负债使用较长的摊销期);但仍然限制资金不足计划的计划变更。这样一来,不仅可以减少过度监管资金充足、运行良好的计划的成本和工作量,还可以释放现金。通过减少保荐人的现金流压力,增加更多的灵活性,政策制定者最终将使固定收益养老金计划更具可持续性。他们甚至可能看到固定收益计划在雇主中卷土重来,这些雇主发现缴纳高额养老金足以将他们赶出固定收益计划的世界。
{"title":"The Time Has Come to Revisit Solvency Funding Rules","authors":"N. Nielson","doi":"10.11575/SPPP.V11I0.43034","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.11575/SPPP.V11I0.43034","url":null,"abstract":"Canadians are not fond of hearing news about people losing their hard-earned pensions because their employer misused the money. The thought of some Working Joe or Jane being deprived of a pension, after a lifetime of working for a company, is naturally repugnant. That is why regulations around defined-benefit pension plans are designed to force employers to keep their pension funds sufficiently solvent. But there are many ways to achieve that end and, while the rules that Canadian companies must follow might serve to help preserve pension savings, they also be very expensive — to employers and regulators — compared to other policies that can do the same thing. In fact, more flexibility in the rules might even make it easier for companies to offer richer pension benefits to employees than they already do. Some of Canada’s outdated pension-funding rules have created the opposite problem: There are now pension plans that are actually overfunded if one assumes the company and the plan will continue. That means money the sponsoring companies could be using to hire more workers, to offer employees better pay and benefits, or to invest, is tied up in pension coffers. The problem lies in the divergence between a “going-concern” valuation — which assumes that the plan continues indefinitely — with the more prescriptive “solvency” valuation that is central to Canadian regulations. It examines funding adequaciy if one assumes the employer is going to go out of business (even if the vast majority of large employers are at any given time at no risk of that). In the days when fixed-income returns were lucrative, companies relied on pension fund investments to top up the funds, reducing sponsor contributions to unsafe levels. The solvency rules required plans that were reaping higher returns in the stock market to continue making some contributions to their plans. Back then, the gap between a going-concern valuation and a solvency valuation was small, and so the rules were not an unacceptable burden. Those rich returns are gone. Now, that gap between valuations has grown dramatically. In B.C., for example, a recent analysis found that when using a going-concern evaluation, 75 per cent of 143 defined-benefit plans registered in the province in 2015 had at least 100-per-cent funding, while the median funding ratio was 124 per cent. Using a solvency model, the median funding ratio was instead estimated to be a much lower 85 per cent. Closing that gap would require onerous pension contributions. More importantly, the contributions it triggers might never be needed to cover benefits. Quebec is the first province to recognize that pension-funding rules need to be revisited and made more responsive, with new rules coming in that will reduce the unnecessary burden on employers while also adapting to changes in the economic environment. Ontario is showing signs that it will take steps in the same direction. Regulators everywhere should be revisiting pension rules to: re","PeriodicalId":76903,"journal":{"name":"Employee benefits journal","volume":"16 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2018-02-22","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"89619474","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
The Legal Differences between CIDC and CDC CIDC与CDC的法律差异
Pub Date : 2018-02-09 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3121141
H. V. Meerten, E. Schmidt
Both Collective Defined Contribution (CDC) and Collective Individual Defined Contribution (CIDC) schemes place any risks on pension scheme members instead of an external risk-bearer. In CDC schemes, assets are pooled collectively, allowing for risks to be shared between pension scheme members. In Individual DC schemes (IDC), the scheme members bear such risks individually. But CDC’s collective nature leaves little room for individual risk management and the pension assets are allocated to scheme members via rules that are often complex and ambiguous. CIDC schemes strive to retain the desirable aspects of CDC and IDC schemes, while improving on some of the drawbacks. The drawbacks of a CDC scheme are mitigated by the introduction of 1) individually quantifiable pension pots through individual accounts, 2) individual risk management and 3) a simplified scheme. The drawbacks of an IDC scheme are mitigated by 1) mandatory participation, 2) collective management of assets, and 3) sharing of risks. It therefore seems that CIDC schemes have a number of important advantages over CDC schemes. CIDC scheme members should be clearly informed of their legal position vis-a-vis their employer and pension provider, and the contract should clearly define the risks. Scheme members appear to benefit from individual risk management and individually identifiable pension pots, while employers and/or pension providers seem relieved from risks and enjoy the security of fixed pension contributions. The possibility to take out a lump sum seems contrary to the collective sharing of risks in both CIDC and CDC schemes.
集体固定缴款(CDC)和集体个人固定缴款(CIDC)计划都将任何风险置于养老金计划成员身上,而不是外部风险承担者。在CDC计划中,资产被集中起来,允许养老金计划成员分担风险。在个人数据中心计划(IDC)中,计划成员分别承担这些风险。但CDC的集体性质给个人风险管理留下了很小的空间,养老金资产是通过复杂而模糊的规则分配给计划成员的。CIDC方案努力保留CDC和IDC方案的可取之处,同时改进一些缺点。CDC计划的缺点可以通过以下方式得到缓解:1)通过个人账户单独量化养老金;2)个人风险管理;3)简化计划。IDC方案的缺点是:1)强制参与;2)资产集体管理;3)风险分担。因此,CIDC方案似乎比CDC方案有许多重要的优势。CIDC计划成员应被清楚地告知他们与雇主和养老金提供者的法律地位,合同应明确界定风险。计划成员似乎受益于个人风险管理和个人可识别的退休金计划,而雇主和/或退休金提供者似乎减轻了风险,并享有固定退休金供款的保障。一次性支付的可能性似乎与CIDC和CDC计划中的集体分担风险背道而驰。
{"title":"The Legal Differences between CIDC and CDC","authors":"H. V. Meerten, E. Schmidt","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3121141","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3121141","url":null,"abstract":"Both Collective Defined Contribution (CDC) and Collective Individual Defined Contribution (CIDC) schemes place any risks on pension scheme members instead of an external risk-bearer. In CDC schemes, assets are pooled collectively, allowing for risks to be shared between pension scheme members. In Individual DC schemes (IDC), the scheme members bear such risks individually. But CDC’s collective nature leaves little room for individual risk management and the pension assets are allocated to scheme members via rules that are often complex and ambiguous. \u0000CIDC schemes strive to retain the desirable aspects of CDC and IDC schemes, while improving on some of the drawbacks. The drawbacks of a CDC scheme are mitigated by the introduction of 1) individually quantifiable pension pots through individual accounts, 2) individual risk management and 3) a simplified scheme. The drawbacks of an IDC scheme are mitigated by 1) mandatory participation, 2) collective management of assets, and 3) sharing of risks. It therefore seems that CIDC schemes have a number of important advantages over CDC schemes. CIDC scheme members should be clearly informed of their legal position vis-a-vis their employer and pension provider, and the contract should clearly define the risks. Scheme members appear to benefit from individual risk management and individually identifiable pension pots, while employers and/or pension providers seem relieved from risks and enjoy the security of fixed pension contributions. The possibility to take out a lump sum seems contrary to the collective sharing of risks in both CIDC and CDC schemes.","PeriodicalId":76903,"journal":{"name":"Employee benefits journal","volume":"151 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2018-02-09","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"79286581","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 3
To Borrow or Insure? Long Term Care Costs and the Impact of Housing 借钱还是投保?长期护理费用和住房的影响
Pub Date : 2018-01-01 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.2707350
Adam W. Shao, Hua Chen, M. Sherris
Health status and health costs a major longevity risk in retirement. Health state important in retirement planning (Ameriks et al., 2011; Yogo, 2009). Large component of wealth in illiquid home equity (Home-ownership rate: 80% for 65 ). Housing and LTC are complementary ways of financing or insuring health costs (Davido, 2010). LTC costs are increasing and the increase is projected to continue (Congressional Budget Office, 2004; Shi and Zhang, 2013). Australia: government requires co payment for LTC costs, potential use of home equity to fund costs. U.S.: Medicaid and Medicare private insurance personal payment. The private LTC insurance market is an important supplement (Glendinning et al., 2004; Colombo et al., 2011).
健康状况和健康费用是退休后长寿的主要风险因素。健康状况在退休计划中很重要(美国人等,2011年;优格,2009)。财富的很大一部分是不流动的房屋净值(65岁的房屋拥有率:80%)。住房和长期贷款是医疗费用融资或保险的互补方式(Davido, 2010年)。长期服务成本正在增加,预计将继续增加(国会预算办公室,2004年;Shi and Zhang, 2013)。澳大利亚:政府要求共同支付LTC成本,可能使用房屋净值来资助成本。美国:医疗补助和医疗保险个人支付。私人LTC保险市场是一个重要的补充(Glendinning et al., 2004;Colombo et al., 2011)。
{"title":"To Borrow or Insure? Long Term Care Costs and the Impact of Housing","authors":"Adam W. Shao, Hua Chen, M. Sherris","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.2707350","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2707350","url":null,"abstract":"Health status and health costs a major longevity risk in retirement. Health state important in retirement planning (Ameriks et al., 2011; Yogo, 2009). Large component of wealth in illiquid home equity (Home-ownership rate: 80% for 65 ). Housing and LTC are complementary ways of financing or insuring health costs (Davido, 2010). LTC costs are increasing and the increase is projected to continue (Congressional Budget Office, 2004; Shi and Zhang, 2013). Australia: government requires co payment for LTC costs, potential use of home equity to fund costs. U.S.: Medicaid and Medicare private insurance personal payment. The private LTC insurance market is an important supplement (Glendinning et al., 2004; Colombo et al., 2011).","PeriodicalId":76903,"journal":{"name":"Employee benefits journal","volume":"24 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2018-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"87851957","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 28
Pension Privatisation: Benefits and Costs 养老金私有化:收益与成本
Pub Date : 2017-10-24 DOI: 10.1093/INDLAW/DWX021
Lilach Lurie
During the last 10 years, many OECD countries introduced reforms which included automatic enrolment or mandatory participation in privately managed pension schemes. The current article aims to reveal the benefits and costs of privately managed pension schemes. The article uses a study of pension schemes’ bylaws in Israel to study the degree to which the shift to privately operated DC schemes results in the transfer of risk from capital to labour and in the entrenchment of gender and income inequalities. The article shows that the shift of pension provision from defined benefit (DB) to defined contribution (DC) entails a significant shift of risk from capital to labour. Moreover, separately from the DB to DC shift, moving from public management to private management increases employees’ pension risks. Lastly, the paper shows that the combination of the shifts from DB to DC and from public to private management involves a shift in governance, which exposes pension scheme members to a high likelihood of lower returns as well as to gender and income inequalities.
在过去十年中,许多经合发组织国家实行了改革,其中包括自动登记或强制参加私人管理的养恤金计划。本文旨在揭示私人管理养老金计划的收益和成本。本文通过对以色列养老金计划细则的研究,研究了向私人运营的养老金计划的转变在多大程度上导致风险从资本转移到劳动力,并加剧了性别和收入不平等。本文表明,养老金从固定收益(DB)向固定缴款(DC)的转变,导致风险从资本向劳动力的显著转移。此外,在从固定收益到固定缴费的转变中,从公共管理转向私人管理增加了员工的养老金风险。最后,本文表明,从固定收益到固定缴费以及从公共管理到私人管理的结合涉及到治理的转变,这使养老金计划成员面临更低回报的可能性以及性别和收入不平等。
{"title":"Pension Privatisation: Benefits and Costs","authors":"Lilach Lurie","doi":"10.1093/INDLAW/DWX021","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1093/INDLAW/DWX021","url":null,"abstract":"During the last 10 years, many OECD countries introduced reforms which included automatic enrolment or mandatory participation in privately managed pension schemes. The current article aims to reveal the benefits and costs of privately managed pension schemes. The article uses a study of pension schemes’ bylaws in Israel to study the degree to which the shift to privately operated DC schemes results in the transfer of risk from capital to labour and in the entrenchment of gender and income inequalities. The article shows that the shift of pension provision from defined benefit (DB) to defined contribution (DC) entails a significant shift of risk from capital to labour. Moreover, separately from the DB to DC shift, moving from public management to private management increases employees’ pension risks. Lastly, the paper shows that the combination of the shifts from DB to DC and from public to private management involves a shift in governance, which exposes pension scheme members to a high likelihood of lower returns as well as to gender and income inequalities.","PeriodicalId":76903,"journal":{"name":"Employee benefits journal","volume":"20 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2017-10-24","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"73390930","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 10
Occupational Pension Funds (IORPs) & Sustainability: What Does the Prudent Person Principle Say? 职业养老基金(IORPs)与可持续性:审慎人原则说了什么?
Pub Date : 2017-09-29 DOI: 10.5278/OJS.NJCL.V0I1.1980
Alexandra Andhov, R. Feldthusen, Vibe Ulfbeck
The European Union encourages individuals to save in private and occupational pension funds to complement their state saving-plans. Throughout their lives, employers directly sponsor occupational retirement saving plans, so individual employees may top up their future pensions. While the European Union clearly supports the formation and cross-border participation in these financial vehicles by adopting EU regulatory framework, the EU has also decided to determine a common investment decision standard to be used in all Member States, called the Prudent Person Principle. According to this principle, the fund - the future retirement for many - shall be managed with care, the skill of an expert, prudence and due diligence. Under this principle, the pension fund’s governing body is given a broad authority to invest the pension assets in a prudent fashion in light of the particular investment plan of a fund. At the same time, the EU is also moving towards more Responsible Investment and inclusion of the ESG-principles (Environment, Social and Governance). The question we aim to answer in this paper is how these two principles co-exist and whether, due to the new Directive adopted by the occupational pension funds in 2016, all funds are obliged to make only responsible, environmentally and socially beneficial investments.
欧盟鼓励个人在私人和职业养老基金中储蓄,以补充他们的国家储蓄计划。在他们的一生中,雇主直接赞助职业退休储蓄计划,因此个人雇员可以为他们未来的养老金充值。虽然欧盟通过采用欧盟监管框架明确支持这些金融工具的形成和跨境参与,但欧盟还决定确定一个共同的投资决策标准,在所有成员国中使用,称为“谨慎人原则”。根据这一原则,基金- -许多人未来的退休生活- -应以专家的技巧、谨慎和尽职的态度加以管理。根据这一原则,养老基金的管治机构被赋予广泛的权力,可以根据基金的特定投资计划,审慎地投资养老基金资产。与此同时,欧盟也在朝着更负责任的投资和esg原则(环境、社会和治理)的方向发展。我们在本文中要回答的问题是,这两个原则是如何共存的,以及由于职业养老基金在2016年通过的新指令,所有基金是否都有义务只进行负责任的、对环境和社会有益的投资。
{"title":"Occupational Pension Funds (IORPs) & Sustainability: What Does the Prudent Person Principle Say?","authors":"Alexandra Andhov, R. Feldthusen, Vibe Ulfbeck","doi":"10.5278/OJS.NJCL.V0I1.1980","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.5278/OJS.NJCL.V0I1.1980","url":null,"abstract":"The European Union encourages individuals to save in private and occupational pension funds to complement their state saving-plans. Throughout their lives, employers directly sponsor occupational retirement saving plans, so individual employees may top up their future pensions. While the European Union clearly supports the formation and cross-border participation in these financial vehicles by adopting EU regulatory framework, the EU has also decided to determine a common investment decision standard to be used in all Member States, called the Prudent Person Principle. According to this principle, the fund - the future retirement for many - shall be managed with care, the skill of an expert, prudence and due diligence. Under this principle, the pension fund’s governing body is given a broad authority to invest the pension assets in a prudent fashion in light of the particular investment plan of a fund. At the same time, the EU is also moving towards more Responsible Investment and inclusion of the ESG-principles (Environment, Social and Governance). The question we aim to answer in this paper is how these two principles co-exist and whether, due to the new Directive adopted by the occupational pension funds in 2016, all funds are obliged to make only responsible, environmentally and socially beneficial investments.","PeriodicalId":76903,"journal":{"name":"Employee benefits journal","volume":"17 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2017-09-29","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"72614171","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2
What Should We Do After Work? Automation and Employment Law 下班后我们应该做什么?自动化与就业法
Pub Date : 2017-09-24 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.3007972
C. Estlund
Will advances in robotics, artificial intelligence, and machine learning put vast swaths of the labor force out of work or into fierce competition for the jobs that remain? Or, as in the past, will new jobs absorb workers displaced by automation? These hotly debated questions have profound implications for the fortress of rights and benefits that the law of work has constructed on the foundation of the employment relationship. This Article charts a path for reforming the law of work in the face of both justified anxiety and uncertainty about the future impact of automation on jobs. Automation is driven largely by the same forces that drive firms’ decisions about “fissuring,” or replacing employees with outside contractors. Fissuring has already transformed the landscape of work and contributed to weaker labor standards and growing inequality. A sensible response to automation should have in mind the adjacent problem of fissuring, and vice versa. Unfortunately, the dominant legal responses to fissuring—which aim to extend firms’ legal responsibility for the workers whose labor they rely on—do not meet the distinctive challenge of automation, and even modestly exacerbate it. Automation offers the ultimate exit from the costs and risks associated with human labor. As technology becomes an ever-more-capable and cost-effective substitute for human workers, it enables firms to circumvent prevailing legal strategies for protecting workers and shoring up the fortress of employment. The question is how to protect workers’ rights and entitlements while reducing firms’ incentive both to replace employees with contractors and to replace human workers with machines. The answer, I argue, lies in separating the issue of what workers’ entitlements should be from the issue of where their economic burdens should fall. Some worker rights and entitlements necessarily entail employer duties and burdens. But for those that do not, we should look for ways to shift their costs beyond employer payrolls, or to extend the entitlements themselves beyond employment. The existing fortress of employment-based rights and benefits is under assault from fissuring and automation; it is failing to protect those who remain outside its walls, and erecting barriers to some who seek to enter. We need to dismantle some of its fortifications and construct a broader foundation of economic security for all, including those who cannot or do not make their living through steady employment.
机器人技术、人工智能和机器学习的进步是否会使大量劳动力失业,或者对剩下的工作岗位展开激烈竞争?或者,像过去一样,新的工作岗位会吸收被自动化取代的工人吗?这些激烈争论的问题对劳动法律在雇佣关系基础上构建的权利和福利堡垒有着深远的影响。面对自动化对工作的未来影响的合理焦虑和不确定性,本文描绘了改革工作法的路径。推动自动化的力量,很大程度上与推动企业决定“决裂”(fisting)或用外部承包商取代员工的力量相同。分裂已经改变了工作环境,导致劳动标准降低,不平等加剧。对自动化的明智回应应该考虑到相邻的断裂问题,反之亦然。不幸的是,对裂缝的主要法律回应——旨在扩大公司对其所依赖的工人的法律责任——并没有满足自动化的独特挑战,甚至适度地加剧了这种挑战。自动化提供了与人力劳动相关的成本和风险的最终出口。随着技术成为人类工人的一种能力更强、成本更低的替代品,它使企业能够绕过保护工人和巩固就业堡垒的现行法律策略。问题是如何保护工人的权利和福利,同时减少公司用承包商取代雇员和用机器取代人类工人的动机。我认为,答案在于将工人应享有何种权利的问题与他们的经济负担应落在何处的问题区分开来。工人的一些权利和权利必然包含雇主的义务和负担。但对于那些不这样做的人,我们应该想方设法将他们的成本转移到雇主工资之外,或者将福利本身扩大到就业之外。现有的以就业为基础的权利和福利堡垒正受到分裂和自动化的冲击;它未能保护那些留在墙外的人,并为一些试图进入的人设置障碍。我们需要拆除其中的一些防御工事,为所有人,包括那些不能或不能通过稳定就业谋生的人,建立一个更广泛的经济安全基础。
{"title":"What Should We Do After Work? Automation and Employment Law","authors":"C. Estlund","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.3007972","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.3007972","url":null,"abstract":"Will advances in robotics, artificial intelligence, and machine learning put vast swaths of the labor force out of work or into fierce competition for the jobs that remain? Or, as in the past, will new jobs absorb workers displaced by automation? These hotly debated questions have profound implications for the fortress of rights and benefits that the law of work has constructed on the foundation of the employment relationship. This Article charts a path for reforming the law of work in the face of both justified anxiety and uncertainty about the future impact of automation on jobs. \u0000Automation is driven largely by the same forces that drive firms’ decisions about “fissuring,” or replacing employees with outside contractors. Fissuring has already transformed the landscape of work and contributed to weaker labor standards and growing inequality. A sensible response to automation should have in mind the adjacent problem of fissuring, and vice versa. Unfortunately, the dominant legal responses to fissuring—which aim to extend firms’ legal responsibility for the workers whose labor they rely on—do not meet the distinctive challenge of automation, and even modestly exacerbate it. Automation offers the ultimate exit from the costs and risks associated with human labor. As technology becomes an ever-more-capable and cost-effective substitute for human workers, it enables firms to circumvent prevailing legal strategies for protecting workers and shoring up the fortress of employment. \u0000The question is how to protect workers’ rights and entitlements while reducing firms’ incentive both to replace employees with contractors and to replace human workers with machines. The answer, I argue, lies in separating the issue of what workers’ entitlements should be from the issue of where their economic burdens should fall. Some worker rights and entitlements necessarily entail employer duties and burdens. But for those that do not, we should look for ways to shift their costs beyond employer payrolls, or to extend the entitlements themselves beyond employment. The existing fortress of employment-based rights and benefits is under assault from fissuring and automation; it is failing to protect those who remain outside its walls, and erecting barriers to some who seek to enter. We need to dismantle some of its fortifications and construct a broader foundation of economic security for all, including those who cannot or do not make their living through steady employment.","PeriodicalId":76903,"journal":{"name":"Employee benefits journal","volume":"25 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2017-09-24","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"82242189","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 26
期刊
Employee benefits journal
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1