首页 > 最新文献

The Journal of corporation law最新文献

英文 中文
The Drivers of Market Efficiency in Revlon Transactions 露华浓交易中市场效率的驱动因素
Pub Date : 2003-03-18 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.389600
Guhan Subramanian
Drawing from practitioner interviews and Gilson & Kraakman's "mechanisms" of market efficiency, I present the argument that the Delaware Supreme Court's decision in Revlon v. MacAndrews & Forbes, Inc. would reduce incentives to search and therefore would reduce overall efficiency in the market for corporate control. I compare this theoretical prediction to the evidence from the past seventeen years of takeover activity, and find no evidence that deal activity for Revlon transactions has been reduced. I argue that three drivers of market efficiency might explain this finding: small net first-bidder costs, preemptive bidding, and heterogeneous buyers. I present some evidence that the market for corporate control was primarily a private-value game in the 1990s, implying that buyer heterogeneity was an important driver of market efficiency. This paper is part of a Symposium commenting on Gilson & Kraakman, The Mechanisms of Market Efficiency, 70 Va. L. Rev. 549 (1984).
根据从业者访谈和Gilson & Kraakman的市场效率“机制”,我提出特拉华州最高法院在露华龙诉MacAndrews & Forbes, Inc.一案中的判决将降低搜索的动机,从而降低公司控制权市场的整体效率。我将这一理论预测与过去17年收购活动的证据进行了比较,没有发现露华浓交易活动减少的证据。我认为,市场效率的三个驱动因素可以解释这一发现:小的净首次投标人成本、先发制人的投标和异质买家。我提出的一些证据表明,在20世纪90年代,公司控制权市场主要是一场私人价值博弈,这意味着买方异质性是市场效率的重要驱动因素。本文是对Gilson & Kraakman的《市场效率机制》(The Mechanisms of Market Efficiency)发表评论的研讨会的一部分,70 Va. L. Rev. 549(1984)。
{"title":"The Drivers of Market Efficiency in Revlon Transactions","authors":"Guhan Subramanian","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.389600","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.389600","url":null,"abstract":"Drawing from practitioner interviews and Gilson & Kraakman's \"mechanisms\" of market efficiency, I present the argument that the Delaware Supreme Court's decision in Revlon v. MacAndrews & Forbes, Inc. would reduce incentives to search and therefore would reduce overall efficiency in the market for corporate control. I compare this theoretical prediction to the evidence from the past seventeen years of takeover activity, and find no evidence that deal activity for Revlon transactions has been reduced. I argue that three drivers of market efficiency might explain this finding: small net first-bidder costs, preemptive bidding, and heterogeneous buyers. I present some evidence that the market for corporate control was primarily a private-value game in the 1990s, implying that buyer heterogeneity was an important driver of market efficiency. This paper is part of a Symposium commenting on Gilson & Kraakman, The Mechanisms of Market Efficiency, 70 Va. L. Rev. 549 (1984).","PeriodicalId":83094,"journal":{"name":"The Journal of corporation law","volume":"28 1","pages":"691"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2003-03-18","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"68664105","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 12
Market vs. Regulatory Responses to Corporate Fraud: A Critique of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002 市场与监管对企业欺诈的反应:对2002年萨班斯-奥克斯利法案的批评
Pub Date : 2002-10-23 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.332681
Larry E. Ribstein
The crashes and frauds of Enron, WorldCom and other companies have reinvigorated the debate over regulating corporate governance. Many pundits have called for corporate regulation to restore confidence in the securities markets. These recommendations appear to be supported by the fact that neither the contracting devices that were supposed to control managers, nor efficient securities markets, worked to prevent or spot the problems. Congress responded with the Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002. But this article shows that, given the limited effectiveness of new regulation, its potential costs, and the power of markets to self-correct, new regulation of fraud in general, and Sarbanes-Oxley in particular, is unlikely to do a better job than markets.
安然(Enron)、世通(WorldCom)和其他公司的倒闭和欺诈,重新激起了有关监管公司治理的辩论。许多权威人士呼吁对公司进行监管,以恢复人们对证券市场的信心。这些建议似乎得到了这样一个事实的支持:无论是本应控制管理人员的合同机制,还是有效的证券市场,都未能防止或发现问题。作为回应,国会于2002年通过了《萨班斯-奥克斯利法案》。但这篇文章表明,考虑到新监管的有限有效性、潜在成本以及市场自我纠正的能力,针对欺诈的新监管,尤其是萨班斯-奥克斯利法案,不太可能比市场做得更好。
{"title":"Market vs. Regulatory Responses to Corporate Fraud: A Critique of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002","authors":"Larry E. Ribstein","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.332681","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.332681","url":null,"abstract":"The crashes and frauds of Enron, WorldCom and other companies have reinvigorated the debate over regulating corporate governance. Many pundits have called for corporate regulation to restore confidence in the securities markets. These recommendations appear to be supported by the fact that neither the contracting devices that were supposed to control managers, nor efficient securities markets, worked to prevent or spot the problems. Congress responded with the Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002. But this article shows that, given the limited effectiveness of new regulation, its potential costs, and the power of markets to self-correct, new regulation of fraud in general, and Sarbanes-Oxley in particular, is unlikely to do a better job than markets.","PeriodicalId":83094,"journal":{"name":"The Journal of corporation law","volume":"28 1","pages":"1"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2002-10-23","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.2139/SSRN.332681","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"68585405","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 264
Transatlantic Perspectives on Partnership Law: Risk and Instability 跨大西洋伙伴关系法的视角:风险与不稳定性
Pub Date : 2001-12-13 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.293860
Deborah A. DeMott
Partnership law in the United States and England has long differed on a basic question that has pervasive significance: if a partner wishes to terminate membership in a general partnership, is the partner bound by a prior agreement to remain a member of the partnership? English partnership has long made such agreements enforceable. In contrast, under U.S. partnership law, a partner who exits from a general partnership prior to an agreed-upon term or otherwise in contravention of the partnership agreement is subject to liability for breach of contract but has power to exit prematurely by dissolving the partnership or by dissociating from it. Partnership legislation has embodied this divergence since the English Partnership Act (1890) and the Uniform Partnership Act (1914). Subsequent changes in general partnership legislation - the Revised Uniform Partnership Act in the United States and recent reform proposals for England - continue to reflect the divergence. My thesis is that general partnership law in each country strikes a different balance between stability for the partnership association and risk over time as perceived by each individual partner. As a consequence general partnerships in the United States are less stable as business associations but the risks borne by individual partners are reduced. In contrast, joining a general partnership in England reflects more of a pre-commitment strategy to staying the course of membership, despite subsequent changes in the risks of continued association as perceived by partners over time. An additional consequence is that partnership law in each country contains doctrines that mitigate the potentially harsh consequences of permitting or forbidding a partner to exit from the partnership in contravention of the original partnership agreement. This contrast is relevant to evaluating the content of general partnership law in the United States, in which a rich menu of organizational choices is now available to organizers of business firms, because alternate organizational choices promise greater stability than does a general partnership. Moreover, the characteristics of firms that are organized or otherwise characterized as general partnerships is relevant to assessing the relative merits of the U.S. and U.K. approaches.
长期以来,美国和英国的合伙法律在一个具有普遍意义的基本问题上存在分歧:如果合伙人希望终止普通合伙企业的成员资格,该合伙人是否受到事先协议的约束,继续担任合伙企业的成员?长期以来,英国的合伙制使此类协议具有可执行性。相比之下,根据美国合伙法,在约定期限之前或违反合伙协议退出普通合伙企业的合伙人要承担违约责任,但有权通过解散合伙企业或脱离合伙企业的方式提前退出。自英国合伙法案(1890年)和统一合伙法案(1914年)以来,合伙立法体现了这种分歧。随后普通合伙立法的变化——美国的《统一合伙法修订案》和英国最近的改革建议——继续反映出这种分歧。我的论点是,每个国家的普通合伙法律在合伙人协会的稳定性和每个合伙人所感知的风险之间取得了不同的平衡。因此,在美国,普通合伙企业作为商业协会的稳定性较差,但个体合伙人承担的风险有所降低。相比之下,在英国加入普通合伙企业更多地反映了一种保持成员资格的预先承诺战略,尽管随着时间的推移,合伙人意识到继续合作的风险会发生变化。另一个后果是,每个国家的合伙法律都包含一些理论,以减轻允许或禁止合伙人违反原合伙协议退出合伙的潜在严重后果。这种对比与评估美国普通合伙法的内容有关,在美国,商业公司的组织者现在可以选择丰富的组织形式,因为其他组织形式的选择比普通合伙承诺更大的稳定性。此外,一般合伙企业的组织或其他特征与评估美国和英国方法的相对优点有关。
{"title":"Transatlantic Perspectives on Partnership Law: Risk and Instability","authors":"Deborah A. DeMott","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.293860","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.293860","url":null,"abstract":"Partnership law in the United States and England has long differed on a basic question that has pervasive significance: if a partner wishes to terminate membership in a general partnership, is the partner bound by a prior agreement to remain a member of the partnership? English partnership has long made such agreements enforceable. In contrast, under U.S. partnership law, a partner who exits from a general partnership prior to an agreed-upon term or otherwise in contravention of the partnership agreement is subject to liability for breach of contract but has power to exit prematurely by dissolving the partnership or by dissociating from it. Partnership legislation has embodied this divergence since the English Partnership Act (1890) and the Uniform Partnership Act (1914). Subsequent changes in general partnership legislation - the Revised Uniform Partnership Act in the United States and recent reform proposals for England - continue to reflect the divergence. My thesis is that general partnership law in each country strikes a different balance between stability for the partnership association and risk over time as perceived by each individual partner. As a consequence general partnerships in the United States are less stable as business associations but the risks borne by individual partners are reduced. In contrast, joining a general partnership in England reflects more of a pre-commitment strategy to staying the course of membership, despite subsequent changes in the risks of continued association as perceived by partners over time. An additional consequence is that partnership law in each country contains doctrines that mitigate the potentially harsh consequences of permitting or forbidding a partner to exit from the partnership in contravention of the original partnership agreement. This contrast is relevant to evaluating the content of general partnership law in the United States, in which a rich menu of organizational choices is now available to organizers of business firms, because alternate organizational choices promise greater stability than does a general partnership. Moreover, the characteristics of firms that are organized or otherwise characterized as general partnerships is relevant to assessing the relative merits of the U.S. and U.K. approaches.","PeriodicalId":83094,"journal":{"name":"The Journal of corporation law","volume":"26 1","pages":"879"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2001-12-13","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.2139/SSRN.293860","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"68438186","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 3
Pitfalls in Partnership Law Reform: Some United States Experience 合伙企业法改革的陷阱:美国的一些经验
Pub Date : 2001-08-01 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.281203
D. Weidner
This paper takes the postion that, based on the United States experience with the Revised Uniform Partnership Act, the two major pitfalls in partnership law reform are a failure to learn from history and a failure to state clear, concise and coherent principles. Among other examples of a failure to learn from history, the paper discusses the continued use of the word dissolution and belated provision for limited liability. Among other examples of a failure to state clear, concise and coherent principles, the paper discusses fiduciary duty and related rules and provisions on joint and several liability. The current mixed grill of statutory forms is itself too complex and insufficiently coherent, and can be made better only by harnessing a proper blend of expertise.
本文认为,根据美国《统一合伙法》修订的经验,合伙法改革存在的两大缺陷是没有从历史中吸取教训,没有阐明清晰、简洁和连贯的原则。在其他未能从历史中吸取教训的例子中,本文讨论了继续使用“解散”一词和对有限责任的迟来规定。在其他未能阐明清晰、简明和连贯原则的例子中,本文讨论了信义义务以及连带责任的相关规则和规定。目前法律形式的混合本身过于复杂,缺乏足够的一致性,只有利用适当的专业知识才能做得更好。
{"title":"Pitfalls in Partnership Law Reform: Some United States Experience","authors":"D. Weidner","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.281203","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.281203","url":null,"abstract":"This paper takes the postion that, based on the United States experience with the Revised Uniform Partnership Act, the two major pitfalls in partnership law reform are a failure to learn from history and a failure to state clear, concise and coherent principles. Among other examples of a failure to learn from history, the paper discusses the continued use of the word dissolution and belated provision for limited liability. Among other examples of a failure to state clear, concise and coherent principles, the paper discusses fiduciary duty and related rules and provisions on joint and several liability. The current mixed grill of statutory forms is itself too complex and insufficiently coherent, and can be made better only by harnessing a proper blend of expertise.","PeriodicalId":83094,"journal":{"name":"The Journal of corporation law","volume":"26 1","pages":"1031"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2001-08-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.2139/SSRN.281203","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"68343716","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Federalism, Regulatory Competition, and the Limited Liability Movement: The Coyote Howled and the Herd Stampeded 联邦制、监管竞争和有限责任运动:土狼嚎叫,兽群狂奔
Pub Date : 2001-07-01 DOI: 10.1093/acprof:oso/9780199264353.003.0008
J. W. Callison
I. INTRODUCTION Choice of business entity decisions historically have involved considering and balancing three factors: (1) the extent to which owners and managers are personally liable to business creditors and tort victims under the applicable commercial law; (2) the tax and regulatory treatment of the business entity, including whether the entity and its owners will be subject to single or double taxation; and (3) the owners' current investment preferences and need to attract additional capital to the entity.1 Focusing on these factors, United States business organization law has undergone fundamental change since 1988. The limited liability company (LLC) emerged as a significant new organizational form,2 and the traditional general partnership and limited partnership forms mutated to permit limited liability protection for owners that historically had unlimited personal liability.3 As a result, business owners are not forced to suffer the tax disadvantages resulting from state law incorporation in order to obtain corporation-like limited liability protection. This change resulted from an elaborate interplay between two separate spheres that influence the selection of U.S. business entities-federal income taxation and state business organization law. The momentum for this change rapidly accelerated when the Internal Revenue Service (IRS) pronounced that Wyoming LLCs, which provide limited liability protection to all owners and managers, would receive favorable partnership taxation.4 By 1996, all fifty states and the District of Columbia had enacted LLC statutes. Following on the heels of the LLC revolution, Texas created the limited liability partnership (LLP) in 1991,5 and thereby permitted general partners in professional partnerships to avoid joint and several malpractice liability by filing a registration statement and using the "LLP" appellation in the partnership name.6 The remaining 49 states and the District of Columbia quickly enacted LLP legislation, and several states extended the LLP concept to limited partnerships (LLLPs), in which general (but not limited) partners historically have joint and several liability for entity debts and obligations.7 Although the de-coupling of partnership tax classification from personal liability finally occurred in 1988, it had its antecedents in the IRS's relaxation of tax classification rules with respect to limited partnerships. After steady growth in the early 1990s, it climaxed in 1996 when the IRS issued regulations providing that most multiple member unincorporated business organizations are taxed as partnerships, unless the organization makes an affirmative election to be taxed as a corporation.8 When the regulations were issued, any requirement that unincorporated business organizations retain partnership-like business characteristics to obtain partnership federal income tax treatment disappeared. The recent history of this U.S. business organization law revolution started with Wyoming's en
从历史上看,企业实体决策的选择涉及考虑和平衡三个因素:(1)根据适用的商法,所有者和管理者对企业债权人和侵权行为受害者的个人责任程度;(2)企业实体的税收和监管待遇,包括企业实体及其所有者是否将被单一或双重征税;(3)所有者当前的投资偏好和为实体吸引额外资金的需要着眼于这些因素,美国商业组织法自1988年以来发生了根本性的变化。有限责任公司(LLC)作为一种重要的新组织形式出现,传统的普通合伙和有限合伙形式发生了变化,允许对历史上拥有无限个人责任的所有者进行有限责任保护因此,企业主不必为了获得类似于公司的有限责任保护而被迫遭受由州法律注册而产生的税收劣势。这种变化源于影响美国商业实体选择的两个独立领域——联邦所得税和州商业组织法——之间复杂的相互作用。当美国国税局(IRS)宣布怀俄明州有限责任公司(为所有所有者和经理提供有限责任保护)将获得优惠的合伙税时,这种变化的势头迅速加速到1996年,所有50个州和哥伦比亚特区都颁布了有限责任公司法规。继有限责任公司革命之后,德克萨斯州于1991年创建了有限责任合伙企业(LLP),从而允许专业合伙企业中的普通合伙人通过提交注册声明并在合伙企业名称中使用“LLP”称谓来避免共同和部分渎职责任其余49个州和哥伦比亚特区迅速制定了有限责任合伙立法,一些州将有限责任合伙的概念扩展到有限合伙企业(lllp),在有限合伙企业中,一般(但不是有限)合伙人历史上对实体债务和义务承担连带责任虽然合伙企业税收分类与个人责任的脱钩最终发生在1988年,但它在美国国税局放宽有限合伙企业税收分类规则时就有先例。在20世纪90年代初稳步增长之后,1996年达到顶峰,当时美国国税局颁布了规定,规定大多数由多个成员组成的非法人商业组织按合伙企业征税,除非该组织积极选择按公司征税这些法规颁布后,任何要求非法人商业组织保留类似合伙企业的商业特征以获得合伙企业联邦所得税待遇的要求都消失了。美国商业组织法的近代史始于怀俄明州的企业家们创立的有限责任公司替代制度,并由此对传统的联邦实体税收分类规则造成压力。联邦税务监管机构最终做出了回应,修改了分类规则,允许将有限责任公司作为合伙企业征税。这一变化的重点是联邦税法,而对州法律领域漠不关心。这些税收变化使各州的立法部门做出了大规模和迅速的反应,以消除个人对组织债务和义务的责任,从而加强各州的亲商环境随着各州立法机构争相创建有限责任公司、有限责任合伙公司和有限责任合伙公司,人们很少注意到将有限责任保护扩展到这些公司的理论或规范方面虽然一些评论家在讨论有限责任公司的出现时采取了一种胜利的州法律第一的态度,但12各州不加批判地采用有限责任作为对税收监管变化的反应,可以被视为一种“逐底竞争”。…
{"title":"Federalism, Regulatory Competition, and the Limited Liability Movement: The Coyote Howled and the Herd Stampeded","authors":"J. W. Callison","doi":"10.1093/acprof:oso/9780199264353.003.0008","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1093/acprof:oso/9780199264353.003.0008","url":null,"abstract":"I. INTRODUCTION Choice of business entity decisions historically have involved considering and balancing three factors: (1) the extent to which owners and managers are personally liable to business creditors and tort victims under the applicable commercial law; (2) the tax and regulatory treatment of the business entity, including whether the entity and its owners will be subject to single or double taxation; and (3) the owners' current investment preferences and need to attract additional capital to the entity.1 Focusing on these factors, United States business organization law has undergone fundamental change since 1988. The limited liability company (LLC) emerged as a significant new organizational form,2 and the traditional general partnership and limited partnership forms mutated to permit limited liability protection for owners that historically had unlimited personal liability.3 As a result, business owners are not forced to suffer the tax disadvantages resulting from state law incorporation in order to obtain corporation-like limited liability protection. This change resulted from an elaborate interplay between two separate spheres that influence the selection of U.S. business entities-federal income taxation and state business organization law. The momentum for this change rapidly accelerated when the Internal Revenue Service (IRS) pronounced that Wyoming LLCs, which provide limited liability protection to all owners and managers, would receive favorable partnership taxation.4 By 1996, all fifty states and the District of Columbia had enacted LLC statutes. Following on the heels of the LLC revolution, Texas created the limited liability partnership (LLP) in 1991,5 and thereby permitted general partners in professional partnerships to avoid joint and several malpractice liability by filing a registration statement and using the \"LLP\" appellation in the partnership name.6 The remaining 49 states and the District of Columbia quickly enacted LLP legislation, and several states extended the LLP concept to limited partnerships (LLLPs), in which general (but not limited) partners historically have joint and several liability for entity debts and obligations.7 Although the de-coupling of partnership tax classification from personal liability finally occurred in 1988, it had its antecedents in the IRS's relaxation of tax classification rules with respect to limited partnerships. After steady growth in the early 1990s, it climaxed in 1996 when the IRS issued regulations providing that most multiple member unincorporated business organizations are taxed as partnerships, unless the organization makes an affirmative election to be taxed as a corporation.8 When the regulations were issued, any requirement that unincorporated business organizations retain partnership-like business characteristics to obtain partnership federal income tax treatment disappeared. The recent history of this U.S. business organization law revolution started with Wyoming's en","PeriodicalId":83094,"journal":{"name":"The Journal of corporation law","volume":"26 1","pages":"951"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2001-07-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"60649341","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 9
An Economic Analysis of Shared Property in Partnership and Close Corporations Law 合伙与封闭式公司法中共有财产的经济学分析
Pub Date : 2001-07-01 DOI: 10.1093/acprof:oso/9780199264353.003.0003
J. Armour, M. Whincop
I. INTRODUCTION The small firm has engaged the attention of law reformers in the United States for the last decade. Close corporation reform continues in many states, and the revisions to uniform partnership law, resulting in the Revised Uniform Partnership Act (RUPA),1 have been well publicized. In addition to reform of "traditional" business forms, recent years have seen the emergence of new business forms in U.S. jurisdictions, such as the Limited Liability Company (LLC)2 and the Limited Liability Partnership (LLP).3 Similar reform efforts are now under way in Europe. In the United Kingdom, the recent Review of Company Law has made the needs of small companies one of its "core concerns."4 Partnership law is currently under review in the United Kingdom for the first time in over a hundred years5 and reforms are also imminent in other European jurisdictions such as the Netherlands.6 Furthermore, the proliferation of new statutory forms appears to be spreading to Europe with the introduction of the U.K. Limited Liability Partnerships Act.7 The task of the law reformer working in this area is a complex one. Small firms are very different from widely-held, exchange-traded firms, where wealth-maximizing governance institutions are obstructed by endemic collective action problems and high agency costs. The small firm differs radically in the capability of investors to be actively involved in the design of governance processes that lower agency costs.8 The lawmaker must focus on what role the law can uniquely serve in small firms without duplicating what parties can do for themselves. Economic analysis of law has conventionally approached this question by explaining how the relations between investors, creditors, and managers are contractual and illustrating the governance problems arising from these incomplete contracts.9 Its exponents often conclude that the functional role the law can serve in small firms is limited to the lower-order function of decreasing transaction costs by plugging gaps in contracts with suitable default rules.10 Yet this leaves a nagging question unanswered: Why does the state have a comparative advantage in the supply and enforcement of these terms over private interest groups and arbitrators, who respectively supply standard terms for, and adjudicate disputes arising under, other varieties of relational contract?11 When "rule competition"--both between jurisdictions and between public and private suppliers of terms-is included in the equation, the role of the statutory law reformer seems increasingly marginal. 12 Our answer to this problem rests in an appreciation of the law's role in giving proprietary effect to the entitlements that the participants share. With a few exceptions, law and economics scholarship has failed to consider the proprietary foundations of intrafirm governance. This neglect is surprising. These proprietary foundations are the most important instance where law performs a unique function, a function ne
在过去的十年里,这家小公司已经引起了美国法律改革者的注意。密切的公司改革在许多州继续进行,对统一合伙法的修订,产生了修订后的统一合伙法(RUPA),1已经得到了很好的宣传。除了“传统”商业形式的改革外,近年来在美国司法管辖区出现了新的商业形式,如有限责任公司(LLC)2和有限责任合伙(LLP) 3类似的改革努力目前正在欧洲进行。在英国,最近的公司法审查将小公司的需求作为其“核心关注”之一。4合伙法目前正在联合王国进行一百多年来的第一次审查,其他欧洲司法管辖区,如荷兰,也即将进行改革。6此外,随着英国《有限责任合伙法》的出台,新的法定形式的扩散似乎正在向欧洲蔓延。7在这一领域工作的法律改革者的任务是复杂的。小公司与广泛持有的交易所交易公司非常不同,后者的财富最大化治理机构受到普遍存在的集体行动问题和高代理成本的阻碍。7 .小公司在投资者积极参与降低代理成本的治理过程设计的能力上有根本的不同立法者必须关注法律在小公司中发挥的独特作用,而不是重复当事人可以为自己做的事情。法律的经济分析通常是通过解释投资者、债权人和管理者之间的关系是如何契约性的,并说明这些不完整的契约所产生的治理问题来解决这个问题的它的拥护者经常得出结论,法律在小公司中的功能作用仅限于用合适的违约规则填补合同空白,从而降低交易成本的低阶功能然而,这留下了一个悬而未决的问题:为什么国家在提供和执行这些条款方面比私人利益集团和仲裁员有比较优势,后者分别为其他类型的关系合同提供标准条款,并裁决在这些条款下产生的纠纷?当“规则竞争”——既包括司法管辖区之间的竞争,也包括公共和私人条款供应商之间的竞争——被纳入这个等式时,成文法改革者的作用似乎越来越边缘化。我们对这个问题的回答在于认识到法律在赋予当事人共有的权利所有权效力方面所起的作用。除了少数例外,法律和经济学学者未能考虑公司内部治理的专有基础。这种忽视令人惊讶。这些专有基础是法律发挥独特功能的最重要实例,这种功能是科斯贸易和私人提供都无法轻易模仿的对所有权的研究为将企业经济学的发展与法律学术结合起来提供了希望最后,小型公司的主要组织选择——紧密合作公司和合伙企业——根据这些公司给予组织权利的专有效应最有意义地区分开来。首先,应该明确的是,这种分析是一种延伸现有理论的内部批判。因此,它不考虑国家的社会目标,而只考虑促进私人政党的目标。这并不意味着其他社会目标被认为是无关紧要的。相反,专有分析比契约模型提供了更多的考虑范围,例如,分配问题然而,研究法律如何能最有效地促进各方的目标是有用的,原因有二。…
{"title":"An Economic Analysis of Shared Property in Partnership and Close Corporations Law","authors":"J. Armour, M. Whincop","doi":"10.1093/acprof:oso/9780199264353.003.0003","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1093/acprof:oso/9780199264353.003.0003","url":null,"abstract":"I. INTRODUCTION The small firm has engaged the attention of law reformers in the United States for the last decade. Close corporation reform continues in many states, and the revisions to uniform partnership law, resulting in the Revised Uniform Partnership Act (RUPA),1 have been well publicized. In addition to reform of \"traditional\" business forms, recent years have seen the emergence of new business forms in U.S. jurisdictions, such as the Limited Liability Company (LLC)2 and the Limited Liability Partnership (LLP).3 Similar reform efforts are now under way in Europe. In the United Kingdom, the recent Review of Company Law has made the needs of small companies one of its \"core concerns.\"4 Partnership law is currently under review in the United Kingdom for the first time in over a hundred years5 and reforms are also imminent in other European jurisdictions such as the Netherlands.6 Furthermore, the proliferation of new statutory forms appears to be spreading to Europe with the introduction of the U.K. Limited Liability Partnerships Act.7 The task of the law reformer working in this area is a complex one. Small firms are very different from widely-held, exchange-traded firms, where wealth-maximizing governance institutions are obstructed by endemic collective action problems and high agency costs. The small firm differs radically in the capability of investors to be actively involved in the design of governance processes that lower agency costs.8 The lawmaker must focus on what role the law can uniquely serve in small firms without duplicating what parties can do for themselves. Economic analysis of law has conventionally approached this question by explaining how the relations between investors, creditors, and managers are contractual and illustrating the governance problems arising from these incomplete contracts.9 Its exponents often conclude that the functional role the law can serve in small firms is limited to the lower-order function of decreasing transaction costs by plugging gaps in contracts with suitable default rules.10 Yet this leaves a nagging question unanswered: Why does the state have a comparative advantage in the supply and enforcement of these terms over private interest groups and arbitrators, who respectively supply standard terms for, and adjudicate disputes arising under, other varieties of relational contract?11 When \"rule competition\"--both between jurisdictions and between public and private suppliers of terms-is included in the equation, the role of the statutory law reformer seems increasingly marginal. 12 Our answer to this problem rests in an appreciation of the law's role in giving proprietary effect to the entitlements that the participants share. With a few exceptions, law and economics scholarship has failed to consider the proprietary foundations of intrafirm governance. This neglect is surprising. These proprietary foundations are the most important instance where law performs a unique function, a function ne","PeriodicalId":83094,"journal":{"name":"The Journal of corporation law","volume":"26 1","pages":"983"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2001-07-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"60648885","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 11
The evolution of closely held business forms in Europe 欧洲少数人持股商业形式的演变
Pub Date : 2001-07-01 DOI: 10.1093/acprof:oso/9780199264353.003.0007
J. McCahery, E. Vermeulen
I. INTRODUCTION This Article grows out of the ongoing debate among European academics on the need to expand the menu of available business organization forms to meet the needs of firms at all levels. Advocates of such reforms claim that company law structures in Europe, which provide a highly developed legal framework and limited liability, are cumbersome and costly for closely held firms to apply. Commentators who favor reform suggest that lawmakers address these problems by devising new business organization statutes that are more varied, less complex, and can potentially enhance efficient outcomes. Traditionally, the business organization law available to small businesses has been structured around the needs of larger, publicly owned firms. In most jurisdictions, closely held business forms are burdened by a number of regulatory requirements which cause firms to incur substantial costs in carrying out their normal business activities. Moreover, the imposition of many of the European Community's harmonized company law provisions on small firms is viewed as disproportionate and over-regulatory, and tends to impede the development of an efficient supply of legal rules. The current debate on the regulation of closely held firms can be explained in terms of a tradeoff between the need for creditor protection in case of firm failure and the commitment to supply legal rules which enable owners to maximize wealth.1 European scholars who express concern about the importance of mandatory requirements as a mechanism to protect creditors and other interests in the firm have justified harmonized rules as a means to avoid a race to the bottom.2 According to this view the mandatory rules, such as minimum capital requirements, disclosure rules, and accounting rules, play a fundamental role in the development of corporate law.3 This position is rhetorically forceful because it relies on the idea of uniformity to provide a basis for creditor protection, but it is conceptually limited by the bargaining problems that creditors inevitably face. The law and economics perspective stands in contrast to the European Community's uniform approach. A large body of work has focused on the costs and benefits of uniformity. On the one hand, uniform rules have the advantage of simplicity and lower administrative costs. Moreover, uniform rules are more appealing to the extent that the benefits of regulation are the same for all firms. On the other hand, uniform rules lead to higher costs for different types of firms. If firms are heterogeneous, efficient regulation calls for the provision of diverse menus of rules in order to reduce the risk of suboptimal uniformity. In the E.C. context, the common thread in this body of work has been the effort to demonstrate that harmonized rules are cumbersome and costly measures which are not sufficient to regulate externality problems. For instance, minimum capital requirements aimed at protecting the welfare of creditors are costly and
本文源于欧洲学术界正在进行的一场辩论,即有必要扩大现有企业组织形式的范围,以满足各层次企业的需求。这种改革的倡导者声称,欧洲的公司法结构提供了高度发达的法律框架和有限责任,对于少数人持股的公司来说,适用这种结构既繁琐又昂贵。支持改革的评论人士建议,立法者通过制定更加多样化、不那么复杂、可能提高效率的新商业组织法规来解决这些问题。传统上,适用于小企业的商业组织法是围绕大型上市公司的需求制定的。在大多数司法管辖区,少数人持有的商业形式受到许多监管要求的限制,导致公司在开展正常业务活动时产生大量成本。此外,将欧洲共同体的许多统一公司法规定强加于小公司被认为是不成比例的和管制过度的,而且往往阻碍有效提供法律规则的发展。当前关于监管少数人持股公司的辩论可以解释为在公司倒闭时需要债权人保护和承诺提供使所有者能够实现财富最大化的法律规则之间的权衡欧洲学者对强制性要求作为一种保护债权人和公司其他利益的机制的重要性表示担忧,他们认为协调一致的规则是避免逐底竞争的一种手段根据这一观点,强制性规则,如最低资本要求、披露规则和会计规则,在公司法的发展中起着根本性的作用这一立场在修辞上是强有力的,因为它依赖于统一的理念来为债权人提供保护的基础,但它在概念上受到债权人不可避免地面临的讨价还价问题的限制。法律和经济学的观点与欧洲共同体的统一做法形成对比。大量的工作集中在统一的成本和收益上。一方面,统一规则具有简单、管理成本低的优点。此外,统一的规则更有吸引力,因为监管的好处对所有公司都是一样的。另一方面,统一的规则导致不同类型的公司成本更高。如果公司是异质的,有效的监管要求提供不同的规则菜单,以减少次优一致性的风险。在欧共体的背景下,这项工作的共同主线是努力证明协调规则是繁琐和昂贵的措施,不足以调节外部性问题。例如,旨在保护债权人福利的最低资本要求是代价高昂和随意的限制,干扰了私人秩序因此,私人各方在市场中获得优越保护的能力表明,在某些情况下,欧盟强制性法律框架不能成为限制封闭式公司外部性的有效方法。最近,由于产品和资本市场的压力,要求为中小型企业提供最具竞争力的商业法规,设计针对少数公司需要的法律规则的相对优点得到了刺激十多年来,学者们一直在讨论封闭型公司法规的优势,但关于欧洲有限责任公司基于竞争的立法的讨论代表了一个新的起点。鉴于存在市场驱动的压力,垄断监管机构正被迫对其公司法制度进行改革。然而,在公司法缺乏选择自由的情况下,不能假设立法者会为不同类型的公司制定最优的商业法律形式。…
{"title":"The evolution of closely held business forms in Europe","authors":"J. McCahery, E. Vermeulen","doi":"10.1093/acprof:oso/9780199264353.003.0007","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1093/acprof:oso/9780199264353.003.0007","url":null,"abstract":"I. INTRODUCTION This Article grows out of the ongoing debate among European academics on the need to expand the menu of available business organization forms to meet the needs of firms at all levels. Advocates of such reforms claim that company law structures in Europe, which provide a highly developed legal framework and limited liability, are cumbersome and costly for closely held firms to apply. Commentators who favor reform suggest that lawmakers address these problems by devising new business organization statutes that are more varied, less complex, and can potentially enhance efficient outcomes. Traditionally, the business organization law available to small businesses has been structured around the needs of larger, publicly owned firms. In most jurisdictions, closely held business forms are burdened by a number of regulatory requirements which cause firms to incur substantial costs in carrying out their normal business activities. Moreover, the imposition of many of the European Community's harmonized company law provisions on small firms is viewed as disproportionate and over-regulatory, and tends to impede the development of an efficient supply of legal rules. The current debate on the regulation of closely held firms can be explained in terms of a tradeoff between the need for creditor protection in case of firm failure and the commitment to supply legal rules which enable owners to maximize wealth.1 European scholars who express concern about the importance of mandatory requirements as a mechanism to protect creditors and other interests in the firm have justified harmonized rules as a means to avoid a race to the bottom.2 According to this view the mandatory rules, such as minimum capital requirements, disclosure rules, and accounting rules, play a fundamental role in the development of corporate law.3 This position is rhetorically forceful because it relies on the idea of uniformity to provide a basis for creditor protection, but it is conceptually limited by the bargaining problems that creditors inevitably face. The law and economics perspective stands in contrast to the European Community's uniform approach. A large body of work has focused on the costs and benefits of uniformity. On the one hand, uniform rules have the advantage of simplicity and lower administrative costs. Moreover, uniform rules are more appealing to the extent that the benefits of regulation are the same for all firms. On the other hand, uniform rules lead to higher costs for different types of firms. If firms are heterogeneous, efficient regulation calls for the provision of diverse menus of rules in order to reduce the risk of suboptimal uniformity. In the E.C. context, the common thread in this body of work has been the effort to demonstrate that harmonized rules are cumbersome and costly measures which are not sufficient to regulate externality problems. For instance, minimum capital requirements aimed at protecting the welfare of creditors are costly and ","PeriodicalId":83094,"journal":{"name":"The Journal of corporation law","volume":"2003 1","pages":"191-239"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2001-07-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"60649182","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 20
Limited Liability Partnerships in the United Kingdom-Do They Have a Role for Small Firms? 英国的有限责任合伙企业——它们对小企业有作用吗?
Pub Date : 2001-07-01 DOI: 10.1093/acprof:oso/9780199264353.003.0010
J. Freedman
I. INTRODUCTION The emergence of a new legal form, the limited liability partnership (LLP), in the United Kingdom, in 2001, may be depicted by some as part of a general, evolutionary movement towards new limited liability vehicles, influenced by such moves in the United States.1 Some are also suggesting that this new legal form, the first such innovation in the United Kingdom for over a century, will provide a more suitable vehicle for small, owner-managed firms than the ordinary limited company.2 This view of the LLP's development and potential will be questioned here. It will be shown that the U.K. LLP resulted entirely from political pressure from professional firms for limited liability in respect to their activities and from their unwillingness to incorporate. Although this new legal form has now been made available to all firms, not just the professions, it has not been designed with small trading businesses in mind, nor in response to small business concerns. The LLP legislation is complex and leaves much uncertainty, for example on the question of liability. It offers possibilities for tax reduction, but as such may distort commercial decisions due to this lack of tax neutrality between different legal forms. It will be argued that the LLP is an unsuitable vehicle for most small, owner managed, non-professional firms, at least in its present form and state of development. It will be some time, if ever, before it is of value to this type of small firm. Its importance should not be exaggerated. Prior to work on the LLP commencing, the Law Commission and Department of Trade and Industry (DTI) had both concluded, after consultation, that no new small business vehicle with limited liability was needed,3 The U.K. limited company (the usual form of incorporation in the United Kingdom, used by small and large, private and public firms alike) is already flexible. The tax pressures that resulted in the growth of the LLP and the LLC in the United States, for example, do not apply in the United Kingdom. The Law Commission was reviewing general partnership law during the time the LLP was under consideration. In addition, a major review of company law was under way (the Company Law Review), which included amongst its tasks a review of the appropriateness and need for simplification of company law for small, private firms. Regrettably, the LLP proposals, consultation, and implementation were conducted by the Department of Trade and Industry on a "fast track" outside either of these other law reform exercises. This fragmented approach to business law reform is not ideal. In order to provide a framework and reference point for the discussion that follows, Part II of this article briefly examines the needs of small businesses in relation to legal structure and outlines the arguments against the notion that the LLP will be an important new vehicle for ordinary small businesses. Part III then examines the pressures that led to the introduction of the LLP in
2001年,英国出现了一种新的法律形式——有限责任合伙企业(LLP),一些人可能将其描述为受美国此类举措的影响,向新的有限责任公司发展的普遍演变运动的一部分。一些人还认为,这种新的法律形式是英国一个多世纪以来的第一次此类创新,将为小型企业提供更合适的工具。业主管理的公司比普通的有限责任公司这种关于LLP的发展和潜力的观点在这里将受到质疑。本文将表明,英国有限责任合伙完全是由于专业公司在其活动方面的有限责任的政治压力和他们不愿意合并而产生的。虽然这种新的法律形式现在已经适用于所有公司,而不仅仅是专业公司,但它的设计并没有考虑到小型贸易企业,也没有考虑到小型企业的担忧。LLP的立法是复杂的,留下了很多不确定性,例如在责任问题上。它提供了减税的可能性,但由于不同法律形式之间缺乏税收中立性,因此可能会扭曲商业决策。有人认为,对于大多数小型的、所有者管理的非专业公司来说,LLP是一种不合适的工具,至少在目前的形式和发展状态下是这样。这将是一段时间,如果有的话,是有价值的这种类型的小公司。它的重要性不应被夸大。在LLP的工作开始之前,法律委员会和贸易和工业部(DTI)在咨询后都得出结论,不需要新的有限责任的小型商业工具,3英国有限公司(在英国,小型和大型,私营和上市公司都使用的常见公司形式)已经很灵活。例如,导致美国LLP和LLC增长的税收压力在英国并不适用。在审议LLP期间,法律委员会正在审查普通合伙法。此外,正在对公司法进行一项重大审查(公司法审查),其任务之一是审查为小型私营公司简化公司法的适当性和必要性。遗憾的是,LLP的提案、咨询和实施都是由贸易和工业部在这些其他法律改革活动之外的“快速通道”上进行的。这种分散的商业法改革方法并不理想。为了为接下来的讨论提供一个框架和参考点,本文的第二部分简要地考察了小企业在法律结构方面的需求,并概述了反对LLP将成为普通小企业重要新工具的观点。第三部分考察了导致英国引入LLP的压力,第四部分评估了由此产生的法律工具的特征。第五部分的结论认为,这种新的法律生物不是产生有效结果的进化和竞争过程的结果,而是对压力的政治反应的结果,这种压力产生了一种对小公司价值有限的奇怪法律工具。2有限责任公司、小型公司和有限责任合伙——综述A.有限责任合伙——向所有人开放的新公司形式。英国LLP最初是为了满足专业公司(主要是审计师)的感知需求而提出的,他们抱怨不切实际的期望和“财大鳄”综合症,因为他们无法限制自己的责任由于对立法进行了磋商和辩论,很明显,很难维持这种新的法律形式应限于某些受管制的专业人员群体的论点。…
{"title":"Limited Liability Partnerships in the United Kingdom-Do They Have a Role for Small Firms?","authors":"J. Freedman","doi":"10.1093/acprof:oso/9780199264353.003.0010","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1093/acprof:oso/9780199264353.003.0010","url":null,"abstract":"I. INTRODUCTION The emergence of a new legal form, the limited liability partnership (LLP), in the United Kingdom, in 2001, may be depicted by some as part of a general, evolutionary movement towards new limited liability vehicles, influenced by such moves in the United States.1 Some are also suggesting that this new legal form, the first such innovation in the United Kingdom for over a century, will provide a more suitable vehicle for small, owner-managed firms than the ordinary limited company.2 This view of the LLP's development and potential will be questioned here. It will be shown that the U.K. LLP resulted entirely from political pressure from professional firms for limited liability in respect to their activities and from their unwillingness to incorporate. Although this new legal form has now been made available to all firms, not just the professions, it has not been designed with small trading businesses in mind, nor in response to small business concerns. The LLP legislation is complex and leaves much uncertainty, for example on the question of liability. It offers possibilities for tax reduction, but as such may distort commercial decisions due to this lack of tax neutrality between different legal forms. It will be argued that the LLP is an unsuitable vehicle for most small, owner managed, non-professional firms, at least in its present form and state of development. It will be some time, if ever, before it is of value to this type of small firm. Its importance should not be exaggerated. Prior to work on the LLP commencing, the Law Commission and Department of Trade and Industry (DTI) had both concluded, after consultation, that no new small business vehicle with limited liability was needed,3 The U.K. limited company (the usual form of incorporation in the United Kingdom, used by small and large, private and public firms alike) is already flexible. The tax pressures that resulted in the growth of the LLP and the LLC in the United States, for example, do not apply in the United Kingdom. The Law Commission was reviewing general partnership law during the time the LLP was under consideration. In addition, a major review of company law was under way (the Company Law Review), which included amongst its tasks a review of the appropriateness and need for simplification of company law for small, private firms. Regrettably, the LLP proposals, consultation, and implementation were conducted by the Department of Trade and Industry on a \"fast track\" outside either of these other law reform exercises. This fragmented approach to business law reform is not ideal. In order to provide a framework and reference point for the discussion that follows, Part II of this article briefly examines the needs of small businesses in relation to legal structure and outlines the arguments against the notion that the LLP will be an important new vehicle for ordinary small businesses. Part III then examines the pressures that led to the introduction of the LLP in ","PeriodicalId":83094,"journal":{"name":"The Journal of corporation law","volume":"26 1","pages":"897"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2001-07-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"60649400","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 15
Bracketed Flexibility: Standards of Performance Level the Playing Field 括号内的灵活性:标准的表现水平的竞争环境
Pub Date : 2001-07-01 DOI: 10.1093/acprof:oso/9780199264353.003.0005
C. Dickerson
I. INTRODUCTION Standards of performance such as good faith and fiduciary duty make bargaining possible. Because standards of performance level the playing field, they enable the more vulnerable party to express its preferences and thus to bargain. The standards have this effect because they are both flexible and precise. Unfortunately, the standards of performance are under siege in the United States and in Europe. While some of the strongest criticism of the standards concerns their vagueness, their flexibility allows parties to negotiate meaningfully and thus to express their preferences. Consequently, far from being sources of distortion, the standards give a voice to those who otherwise would not be heard. To use a political analogy, the standards enable, in the commercial realm, the democratic voice championed by Amartya Sen. 1 This is an affirmative reason to have standards of performance. Although there is general agreement that the standards are flexible, the claim that they are precise is counterintuitive. While there is general acceptance of a floor-that is, of a minimum standard-the common complaint about the standards' vagueness presupposes the lack of a clear ceiling. In fact, actual behavior supported by law reveals that the standards of performance have an identifiable floor and a self-executing ceiling. By continuing the existence of a floor and a ceiling, I show that the standards are precise within a prescribed range; indeed, further specification would merely destroy the flexibility. The flexibility of the standards provides the subtlety; their precision provides the predictability. Despite the current challenge to the standards, United States law still supports them, and because the standards' flexibility and precision make bargaining possible, business law should continue that support. II. STANDARDS OF PERFORMANCE ARE FLEXIBLE AND DESIGNED To LEVEL THE PLAYING FIELD Standards of performance are flexible and designed to level the playing field. They play a larger, more important role than merely to reduce agency costs, the role often used to justify good faith or fiduciary duty.2 Standards of performance often make the bargain possible. A. Leveling the Playing Field Starting with an analogy to pollution, assume a downstream landowner who values clean water more than the upstream polluter values the right to pollute. Assume further that the downstream owner does not have the money to pay the upstream polluter to clean its effluents. In this context, the downstream owner is powerless. Regulation can level the playing field so that the downstream owner-before regulation, the weaker party-has the power to negotiate meaningfully. The downstream owner then can obtain the clean water that this owner values more than the polluter values the permission to pollute.3 Standards of performance similarly operate to level the playing field in the context of contracts and of business organizations. They do so by correcting for unequal power
诚信和信义义务等履约标准使议价成为可能。由于履行标准使竞争环境公平,它们使较脆弱的一方能够表达其偏好,从而进行讨价还价。标准之所以有这种效果,是因为它们既灵活又精确。不幸的是,在美国和欧洲,绩效标准受到了围攻。虽然对这些标准的一些最强烈的批评涉及它们的模糊性,但它们的灵活性使各方能够进行有意义的谈判,从而表达他们的偏好。因此,这些标准非但没有成为失真的来源,反而让那些本来不会被听到的人发出了声音。用一个政治上的类比来说,在商业领域,这些标准使Amartya sen所倡导的民主声音成为可能。这是设立绩效标准的一个积极理由。尽管人们普遍认为这些标准是灵活的,但声称它们是精确的是违反直觉的。虽然人们普遍接受最低标准——即最低标准——但对标准含糊的普遍抱怨预设了缺乏明确的上限。事实上,法律支持的实际行为表明,履行标准有一个可识别的下限和一个自动执行的上限。通过继续存在最低限度和最高限度,我表明这些标准在规定的范围内是精确的;实际上,进一步的规范只会破坏灵活性。标准的灵活性提供了微妙之处;它们的精确性提供了可预测性。尽管目前对标准的挑战,美国法律仍然支持它们,并且由于标准的灵活性和精确性使得讨价还价成为可能,商业法应该继续这种支持。2业绩标准是灵活的,旨在使竞争环境公平。它们所起的作用更大、更重要,而不仅仅是为了降低代理成本,而代理成本通常被用来证明诚信或信义义务的正当性业绩标准往往使讨价还价成为可能。从污染的类比开始,假设下游的土地所有者比上游的污染者更重视清洁水的价值。进一步假设下游所有者没有钱支付上游污染者清理其污水的费用。在这种情况下,下游所有者是无能为力的。监管可以创造公平的竞争环境,这样下游的所有者——在监管之前,弱势一方——就有能力进行有意义的谈判。然后,下游的所有者就可以获得清洁的水,这个所有者比污染者更重视污染的许可同样,绩效标准的作用是在合同和商业组织中创造公平的竞争环境。他们通过纠正不平等的权力和利益冲突来做到这一点。为了使标准有效地平衡领域,权力的冲突和不平等越大,适用的标准必须越高。下面的四个例子,两个来自合同法,两个来自非法人实体法,反映了这种直接关系,一方面是履约标准,另一方面是权力和冲突在我们开始讨论合同法之前,请注意,合同法与非法人企业相关,部分原因是合同在组织的形成中起着重要作用,部分原因是几十年来的“合同关系”类比在受合同法管辖的公平交易中,也就是说,在公平竞争的环境中,各方都被认为有自卫的能力。在这种情况下,任何高于机会主义标准的行为都符合合同法的善意,是适当的。…
{"title":"Bracketed Flexibility: Standards of Performance Level the Playing Field","authors":"C. Dickerson","doi":"10.1093/acprof:oso/9780199264353.003.0005","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1093/acprof:oso/9780199264353.003.0005","url":null,"abstract":"I. INTRODUCTION Standards of performance such as good faith and fiduciary duty make bargaining possible. Because standards of performance level the playing field, they enable the more vulnerable party to express its preferences and thus to bargain. The standards have this effect because they are both flexible and precise. Unfortunately, the standards of performance are under siege in the United States and in Europe. While some of the strongest criticism of the standards concerns their vagueness, their flexibility allows parties to negotiate meaningfully and thus to express their preferences. Consequently, far from being sources of distortion, the standards give a voice to those who otherwise would not be heard. To use a political analogy, the standards enable, in the commercial realm, the democratic voice championed by Amartya Sen. 1 This is an affirmative reason to have standards of performance. Although there is general agreement that the standards are flexible, the claim that they are precise is counterintuitive. While there is general acceptance of a floor-that is, of a minimum standard-the common complaint about the standards' vagueness presupposes the lack of a clear ceiling. In fact, actual behavior supported by law reveals that the standards of performance have an identifiable floor and a self-executing ceiling. By continuing the existence of a floor and a ceiling, I show that the standards are precise within a prescribed range; indeed, further specification would merely destroy the flexibility. The flexibility of the standards provides the subtlety; their precision provides the predictability. Despite the current challenge to the standards, United States law still supports them, and because the standards' flexibility and precision make bargaining possible, business law should continue that support. II. STANDARDS OF PERFORMANCE ARE FLEXIBLE AND DESIGNED To LEVEL THE PLAYING FIELD Standards of performance are flexible and designed to level the playing field. They play a larger, more important role than merely to reduce agency costs, the role often used to justify good faith or fiduciary duty.2 Standards of performance often make the bargain possible. A. Leveling the Playing Field Starting with an analogy to pollution, assume a downstream landowner who values clean water more than the upstream polluter values the right to pollute. Assume further that the downstream owner does not have the money to pay the upstream polluter to clean its effluents. In this context, the downstream owner is powerless. Regulation can level the playing field so that the downstream owner-before regulation, the weaker party-has the power to negotiate meaningfully. The downstream owner then can obtain the clean water that this owner values more than the polluter values the permission to pollute.3 Standards of performance similarly operate to level the playing field in the context of contracts and of business organizations. They do so by correcting for unequal power ","PeriodicalId":83094,"journal":{"name":"The Journal of corporation law","volume":"26 1","pages":"1001"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2001-07-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"60649497","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Berle and Means Reconsidered at the Century's Turn 在世纪之交重新考虑伯利和手段
Pub Date : 2001-01-31 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.255999
W. Bratton
This paper reconsiders Berle and Means' The Modern Corporation and Private Property in the context of contemporary corporate legal theory. Although the book lost its paradigmatic status in the field two decades ago, it retains an enviable place at the forefront of policy discussions. The paper seeks to explain this unusual longevity, in a three-part discussion. The first part places the book in the context of the legal theory of its day by comparing work of John Dewey on the theory of the firm and William O. Douglas on corporate reorganization. This discussion highlights two progressive assumptions Berle and Means shared with these business law contemporaries?a confidence in the efficacy of judicial intervention to vindicate distributive policies and a distrust of the institution of contract. The second part takes up Berle and Means' description of the separation of ownership and control. It is here that Berle and Means still speak in an active voice. The split in the classical entrepreneurial function has come to be seen as a problem by observers on all points of twentieth century America's ideological spectrum, even as few have denied the large corporation's success as a producer. The problem has never been solved, despite strenuous efforts to assert the contrary in first-generation law and economics. Instead of clear cut solution of the problem, we instead have seen a process of accommodation and adjustment between the management-controlled corporation and the wider economy and society. The process, which began before the turn of the twentieth century, continues into the twenty first. More particularly, Berle and Means' description of the problem synchronizes neatly with contemporary views on corporate governance. It turns out that even the latest microeconomic theory of the firm in the incomplete contracts framework coexists in consonance with the book. The third part reconsiders the solution Berle and Means recommended for the problem of separated ownership and control, a judicially-enforced norm of trust. This has been eclipsed in business law. Even so, The Modern Corporation and Private Property hedges its prescriptive presentation carefully enough to retain a measure of plausibility in a contemporary reader's eyes. More importantly, the book's prescriptive miss follows less from the its analysis of corporate problems than from now-discarded progressive assumptions about regulation and contract. Finally, the book's failure accurately to predict the future course of corporate fiduciary law stems in part from a development Berle could not reasonably have been expected to anticipate--the rise of the Delaware courts to a dominant place in the making of corporate case law due to the ancillary disappearance of federal common law after Erie Railroad Co. v. Tompkins.
本文在当代公司法理论的背景下重新审视伯利和米恩斯的《现代公司与私有财产》。尽管这本书在20年前就失去了它在该领域的典范地位,但它在政策讨论的前沿仍保持着令人羡慕的地位。这篇论文试图用三部分的讨论来解释这种不同寻常的长寿。第一部分通过比较约翰·杜威关于公司理论的著作和威廉·道格拉斯关于公司重组的著作,将本书置于当时法律理论的背景中。这一讨论突出了Berle和Means与这些商法同时代人共享的两个进步假设。对司法干预为分配政策辩护的有效性的信心和对契约制度的不信任。第二部分回顾了Berle和Means对所有权和控制权分离的描述。正是在这里,伯利和米恩斯仍然用积极的声音说话。尽管很少有人否认大公司作为生产者的成功,但20世纪美国各个意识形态领域的观察家都认为,传统企业职能的分裂是一个问题。尽管在第一代法律和经济学中极力主张相反的观点,但这个问题从未得到解决。我们看到的不是问题的明确解决,而是管理层控制的公司与更广泛的经济和社会之间的适应和调整过程。这一进程始于20世纪初,一直持续到21世纪。更具体地说,Berle和Means对这个问题的描述与当代对公司治理的看法完全一致。事实证明,在不完全契约框架下,即使是最新的企业微观经济理论也与这本书一致。第三部分重新考虑Berle和Means对所有权和控制权分离问题的解决方案,这是一种司法强制执行的信任规范。这一点在商法中已经黯然失色。即便如此,《现代公司与私有财产》对其规定性的表述进行了足够仔细的对冲,在当代读者的眼中保留了一定程度的合理性。更重要的是,这本书的规范性缺失与其说来自对公司问题的分析,不如说是来自现已被抛弃的关于监管和契约的渐进假设。最后,本书未能准确预测公司信托法的未来走向,部分原因在于伯利无法合理地预料到的一种发展——在伊利铁路公司诉汤普金斯案(Erie Railroad Co. v. Tompkins)之后,由于联邦普通法的从属地位消失,特拉华州法院在制定公司判例法方面崛起为主导地位。
{"title":"Berle and Means Reconsidered at the Century's Turn","authors":"W. Bratton","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.255999","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.255999","url":null,"abstract":"This paper reconsiders Berle and Means' The Modern Corporation and Private Property in the context of contemporary corporate legal theory. Although the book lost its paradigmatic status in the field two decades ago, it retains an enviable place at the forefront of policy discussions. The paper seeks to explain this unusual longevity, in a three-part discussion. The first part places the book in the context of the legal theory of its day by comparing work of John Dewey on the theory of the firm and William O. Douglas on corporate reorganization. This discussion highlights two progressive assumptions Berle and Means shared with these business law contemporaries?a confidence in the efficacy of judicial intervention to vindicate distributive policies and a distrust of the institution of contract. The second part takes up Berle and Means' description of the separation of ownership and control. It is here that Berle and Means still speak in an active voice. The split in the classical entrepreneurial function has come to be seen as a problem by observers on all points of twentieth century America's ideological spectrum, even as few have denied the large corporation's success as a producer. The problem has never been solved, despite strenuous efforts to assert the contrary in first-generation law and economics. Instead of clear cut solution of the problem, we instead have seen a process of accommodation and adjustment between the management-controlled corporation and the wider economy and society. The process, which began before the turn of the twentieth century, continues into the twenty first. More particularly, Berle and Means' description of the problem synchronizes neatly with contemporary views on corporate governance. It turns out that even the latest microeconomic theory of the firm in the incomplete contracts framework coexists in consonance with the book. The third part reconsiders the solution Berle and Means recommended for the problem of separated ownership and control, a judicially-enforced norm of trust. This has been eclipsed in business law. Even so, The Modern Corporation and Private Property hedges its prescriptive presentation carefully enough to retain a measure of plausibility in a contemporary reader's eyes. More importantly, the book's prescriptive miss follows less from the its analysis of corporate problems than from now-discarded progressive assumptions about regulation and contract. Finally, the book's failure accurately to predict the future course of corporate fiduciary law stems in part from a development Berle could not reasonably have been expected to anticipate--the rise of the Delaware courts to a dominant place in the making of corporate case law due to the ancillary disappearance of federal common law after Erie Railroad Co. v. Tompkins.","PeriodicalId":83094,"journal":{"name":"The Journal of corporation law","volume":"26 1","pages":"737"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2001-01-31","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"68203562","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 60
期刊
The Journal of corporation law
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1