首页 > 最新文献

Stanford technology law review : STLR : an online high-technology law journal from Stanford Law School最新文献

英文 中文
Proof of Work as it Relates to the Theory of the Firm 与企业理论相关的工作量证明
C. Wright
One of the little-known aspects of bitcoin is the nature of the proof of work system. There are many people, especially those who support a UASF or PoW change that believe a distributed system should be completed as a mesh. In this, they confuse centralised systems with centrality. The truth of the matter, no matter which proof of work system is implemented, they all follow a maximal growth curve that reflects the nature of the firm is detailed in 1937 by Ronald Coase. In this paper, we address the issues of using alternate proof of work systems with regards to either incorporating alternate functions in an extension of simply securing the network against the use of proof of work systems in an attempt to create a one person one vote scenario in place of economic incentivisation.
比特币鲜为人知的一个方面是工作量证明系统的性质。有很多人,特别是那些支持UASF或PoW变更的人,认为分布式系统应该作为一个网格来完成。在这一点上,他们混淆了中心化系统和中心化系统。事实的真相是,无论实行哪一种工作量证明制度,它们都遵循反映公司性质的最大增长曲线,罗纳德·科斯在1937年详细说明了这一点。在本文中,我们解决了使用替代工作证明系统的问题,既可以在扩展中纳入替代功能,也可以简单地保护网络免受使用工作证明系统的影响,以试图创建一人一票的场景来代替经济激励。
{"title":"Proof of Work as it Relates to the Theory of the Firm","authors":"C. Wright","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.2993312","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2993312","url":null,"abstract":"One of the little-known aspects of bitcoin is the nature of the proof of work system. There are many people, especially those who support a UASF or PoW change that believe a distributed system should be completed as a mesh. In this, they confuse centralised systems with centrality. The truth of the matter, no matter which proof of work system is implemented, they all follow a maximal growth curve that reflects the nature of the firm is detailed in 1937 by Ronald Coase. In this paper, we address the issues of using alternate proof of work systems with regards to either incorporating alternate functions in an extension of simply securing the network against the use of proof of work systems in an attempt to create a one person one vote scenario in place of economic incentivisation.","PeriodicalId":90732,"journal":{"name":"Stanford technology law review : STLR : an online high-technology law journal from Stanford Law School","volume":"21 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2017-06-27","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"73113032","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 5
Recent Developments in Patent Law (Spring 2017) 专利法最新进展(2017年春季)
Mark A. Lemley, M. Laupheimer, James C. Yoon
This paper summarizes the significant developments in patent law in the twelve months ending in April 2017.
本文总结了截至2017年4月的12个月内专利法的重大发展。
{"title":"Recent Developments in Patent Law (Spring 2017)","authors":"Mark A. Lemley, M. Laupheimer, James C. Yoon","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.2959553","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2959553","url":null,"abstract":"This paper summarizes the significant developments in patent law in the twelve months ending in April 2017.","PeriodicalId":90732,"journal":{"name":"Stanford technology law review : STLR : an online high-technology law journal from Stanford Law School","volume":"31 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2017-04-27","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"82360706","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Predictably Expensive: A Critical Look at Patent Litigation in the Eastern District of Texas 可预见的昂贵:对德克萨斯州东区专利诉讼的批判
B. Love, James C. Yoon
In this Article, we compare U.S. patent litigation across districts and consider possible explanations for the Eastern District of Texas’ popularity with patent plaintiffs. Rather than any one explanation, we conclude that what makes the Eastern District so attractive to patent plaintiffs is the accumulated effect of several marginal advantages — particularly with respect to the relative timing of discovery deadlines, transfer decisions, and claim construction — that make it predictably expensive for accused infringers to defend patent suits filed in East Texas. These findings tend to support ongoing efforts to pass patent reform legislation that would presumptively stay discovery in patent suits pending claim construction and motions to transfer or dismiss. However, we also observe that courts in the Eastern District of Texas have exercised their discretion in ways that dampen the effect of prior legislative and judicial reforms that were aimed (at least in part) at deterring abusive patent suits. Given courts’ broad discretion to control how cases proceed, this additional finding suggests that restricting venue in patent cases may well be the single most effective reform available to Congress or the courts to limit patentees’ ability to impose unnecessary and unwarranted costs on companies accused of patent infringement.
在本文中,我们比较了美国各地区的专利诉讼,并考虑了德克萨斯州东区受专利原告欢迎的可能解释。我们得出的结论是,东部地区对专利原告如此有吸引力的原因是几种边际优势的累积效应——特别是在发现截止日期的相对时间、转移决定和索赔构建方面——这使得被控侵权人在东德克萨斯州提起的专利诉讼的辩护成本可想而知。这些发现倾向于支持正在进行的通过专利改革立法的努力,这些立法可能会在专利诉讼中保留发现,等待权利要求的构建和转移或驳回的动议。然而,我们也注意到,德克萨斯州东区的法院在行使其自由裁量权的方式上,抑制了先前旨在(至少部分地)阻止滥用专利诉讼的立法和司法改革的效果。鉴于法院有广泛的自由裁量权来控制案件如何进行,这一额外的发现表明,限制专利案件的审理地点可能是国会或法院可以采取的最有效的改革措施,以限制专利权人向被控侵犯专利的公司施加不必要和不合理成本的能力。
{"title":"Predictably Expensive: A Critical Look at Patent Litigation in the Eastern District of Texas","authors":"B. Love, James C. Yoon","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.2835799","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.2835799","url":null,"abstract":"In this Article, we compare U.S. patent litigation across districts and consider possible explanations for the Eastern District of Texas’ popularity with patent plaintiffs. Rather than any one explanation, we conclude that what makes the Eastern District so attractive to patent plaintiffs is the accumulated effect of several marginal advantages — particularly with respect to the relative timing of discovery deadlines, transfer decisions, and claim construction — that make it predictably expensive for accused infringers to defend patent suits filed in East Texas. These findings tend to support ongoing efforts to pass patent reform legislation that would presumptively stay discovery in patent suits pending claim construction and motions to transfer or dismiss. However, we also observe that courts in the Eastern District of Texas have exercised their discretion in ways that dampen the effect of prior legislative and judicial reforms that were aimed (at least in part) at deterring abusive patent suits. Given courts’ broad discretion to control how cases proceed, this additional finding suggests that restricting venue in patent cases may well be the single most effective reform available to Congress or the courts to limit patentees’ ability to impose unnecessary and unwarranted costs on companies accused of patent infringement.","PeriodicalId":90732,"journal":{"name":"Stanford technology law review : STLR : an online high-technology law journal from Stanford Law School","volume":"20 1","pages":"1"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2017-01-03","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"42063359","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 12
Uma Análise Econômica Do Direito Do Consumidor: Como Leis Consumeristas Prejudicam Os Mais Pobres Sem Beneficiar Consumidores (An Economic Analysis of Consumer Law: How Legislation Harms the Poor without Protecting the Consumers) 《消费者法的经济分析:立法如何在不保护消费者的情况下伤害穷人》(消费者法的经济分析:立法如何在不保护消费者的情况下伤害穷人)
B. Bodart
Portuguese Abstract: O Direito do Consumidor e tradicionalmente compreendido no Brasil como unico mecanismo capaz de proteger o consumidor como sujeito vulneravel no mercado de consumo. Sob essa logica, multiplicam-se leis e regulamentos destinados a tutelar os interesses dos consumidores. Entretanto, as principais tecnicas adotadas falham em atingir os objetivos propostos, concentram mercados e excluem consumidores de menor poder aquisitivo, dentre outras consequencias nao intencionais. O presente artigo analisa pesquisas empiricas para demonstrar os problemas que essas tecnicas apresentam. Ao final, sao propostas alternativas ao sistema de protecao ao consumidor centralizado na legislacao.English Abstract: Consumer Law is traditionally regarded in Brazil as the only mechanism able to protect consumers as vulnerable actors within the market. Following this rationale, the number of laws and regulations, intended to safeguard consumers’ interests, continues to grow. However, the main regulatory techniques: fail to achieve the proposed goals, concentrate markets, and exclude low-income consumers from them, on top of other unintended consequences. The paper identifies issues with these techniques based on empirical research and elaborates on alternatives to the state-centered consumer protection system.
摘要:在巴西,消费者法传统上被理解为唯一能够保护消费者作为消费市场中脆弱主体的机制。在这种逻辑下,旨在保护消费者利益的法律法规成倍增加。然而,采用的主要技术未能实现拟议的目标,集中市场,排除购买力较低的消费者,以及其他意想不到的后果。本文分析了实证研究,以证明这些技术存在的问题。最后,提出了以立法为中心的消费者保护体系的替代方案。在巴西,消费者法传统上被认为是能够保护消费者作为市场中的弱势行动者的唯一机制。根据这一理由,旨在保障消费者利益的法律和条例的数量继续增加。然而,主要的监管技术:未能实现拟议的目标,集中市场,并将低收入消费者排除在这些目标之外,以及其他意想不到的后果。本文在实证研究的基础上确定了这些技术的问题,并阐述了以国家为中心的消费者保护制度的替代方案。
{"title":"Uma Análise Econômica Do Direito Do Consumidor: Como Leis Consumeristas Prejudicam Os Mais Pobres Sem Beneficiar Consumidores (An Economic Analysis of Consumer Law: How Legislation Harms the Poor without Protecting the Consumers)","authors":"B. Bodart","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.2870931","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2870931","url":null,"abstract":"Portuguese Abstract: O Direito do Consumidor e tradicionalmente compreendido no Brasil como unico mecanismo capaz de proteger o consumidor como sujeito vulneravel no mercado de consumo. Sob essa logica, multiplicam-se leis e regulamentos destinados a tutelar os interesses dos consumidores. Entretanto, as principais tecnicas adotadas falham em atingir os objetivos propostos, concentram mercados e excluem consumidores de menor poder aquisitivo, dentre outras consequencias nao intencionais. O presente artigo analisa pesquisas empiricas para demonstrar os problemas que essas tecnicas apresentam. Ao final, sao propostas alternativas ao sistema de protecao ao consumidor centralizado na legislacao.English Abstract: Consumer Law is traditionally regarded in Brazil as the only mechanism able to protect consumers as vulnerable actors within the market. Following this rationale, the number of laws and regulations, intended to safeguard consumers’ interests, continues to grow. However, the main regulatory techniques: fail to achieve the proposed goals, concentrate markets, and exclude low-income consumers from them, on top of other unintended consequences. The paper identifies issues with these techniques based on empirical research and elaborates on alternatives to the state-centered consumer protection system.","PeriodicalId":90732,"journal":{"name":"Stanford technology law review : STLR : an online high-technology law journal from Stanford Law School","volume":"2 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2016-11-16","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"78524505","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Brief of Amici Curiae 56 Professors of Law and Economics in Support of Petition for Writ of Certiorari in TC Heartland LLC v. Kraft Foods Group Brands LLC, No. 16-341 法院之友56位法学和经济学教授支持TC Heartland有限责任公司诉卡夫食品集团品牌有限责任公司案调卷令请愿书摘要,第16-341号
Colleen V. Chien, Mark A. Lemley, B. Love, A. Rai
28 U.S.C. § 1400(b) provides that a defendant in a patent case may be sued where the defendant is incorporated or has a regular and established place of business and has infringed the patent. This Court made clear in Fourco Glass Co. v. Transmirra Prods. Corp., 353 U.S. 222, 223 (1957), that those were the only permissible venues for a patent case. But the Federal Circuit has rejected Fourco and the plain meaning of § 1400(b), instead permitting a patent plaintiff to file suit against a defendant anywhere there is personal jurisdiction over that defendant. The result has been rampant forum shopping, particularly by patent trolls. 44% of 2015 patent lawsuits were filed in a single district: the Eastern District of Texas, a forum with plaintiff-friendly rules and practices, and where few of the defendants are incorporated or have established places of business. And an estimated 86% of 2015 patent cases were filed somewhere other than the jurisdictions specified in the statute. Colleen V. Chien & Michael Risch, Recalibrating Patent Venue, Santa Clara Univ. Legal Studies Research Paper No. 10-1 (Sept. 1, 2016), Table 3. This Court should grant certiorari to review the meaning of 28 U.S.C. § 1400(b) because the Federal Circuit’s dubious interpretation of the statute plays an outsized and detrimental role, both legally and economically, in the patent system.
28 U.S.C.§1400(b)规定,专利案件中的被告可以在被告注册成立或拥有固定营业地并侵犯专利的情况下被起诉。本院在Fourco Glass Co.诉Transmirra Prods案中明确表示。公司,353 U.S. 222, 223(1957),这些是专利案件唯一允许的场所。但联邦巡回法院驳回了Fourco和第1400(b)条的明确含义,而是允许专利原告在任何对被告有属人管辖权的地方对被告提起诉讼。其结果是论坛抢购猖獗,尤其是专利流氓。2015年44%的专利诉讼都是在一个地区提起的:德克萨斯州东区,这是一个对原告友好的规则和惯例的论坛,而且很少有被告是公司或建立了营业场所。据估计,2015年86%的专利案件是在法规规定的司法管辖区以外的地方提交的。Colleen V. Chien & Michael Risch,重新校准专利地点,Santa Clara university,法律研究论文No. 10-1(2016年9月1日),表3。本院应批准调卷审查28 U.S.C.§1400(b)的含义,因为联邦巡回法院对该法规的可疑解释在专利制度中无论在法律上还是在经济上都发挥了巨大的有害作用。
{"title":"Brief of Amici Curiae 56 Professors of Law and Economics in Support of Petition for Writ of Certiorari in TC Heartland LLC v. Kraft Foods Group Brands LLC, No. 16-341","authors":"Colleen V. Chien, Mark A. Lemley, B. Love, A. Rai","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.2853696","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.2853696","url":null,"abstract":"28 U.S.C. § 1400(b) provides that a defendant in a patent case may be sued where the defendant is incorporated or has a regular and established place of business and has infringed the patent. This Court made clear in Fourco Glass Co. v. Transmirra Prods. Corp., 353 U.S. 222, 223 (1957), that those were the only permissible venues for a patent case. But the Federal Circuit has rejected Fourco and the plain meaning of § 1400(b), instead permitting a patent plaintiff to file suit against a defendant anywhere there is personal jurisdiction over that defendant. The result has been rampant forum shopping, particularly by patent trolls. 44% of 2015 patent lawsuits were filed in a single district: the Eastern District of Texas, a forum with plaintiff-friendly rules and practices, and where few of the defendants are incorporated or have established places of business. And an estimated 86% of 2015 patent cases were filed somewhere other than the jurisdictions specified in the statute. Colleen V. Chien & Michael Risch, Recalibrating Patent Venue, Santa Clara Univ. Legal Studies Research Paper No. 10-1 (Sept. 1, 2016), Table 3. This Court should grant certiorari to review the meaning of 28 U.S.C. § 1400(b) because the Federal Circuit’s dubious interpretation of the statute plays an outsized and detrimental role, both legally and economically, in the patent system.","PeriodicalId":90732,"journal":{"name":"Stanford technology law review : STLR : an online high-technology law journal from Stanford Law School","volume":"58 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2016-10-17","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"84196603","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Economic Transition and Entrepreneurship Development in China 中国经济转型与创业发展
Ying Zhang, Andre J. van Stel
One of the most prominent features of China’s transition from a centrally planned economy to a market-based economy is the emergence of entrepreneurship, although previous literature discusses this phenomenon descriptively rather than prescriptively. In this article, we consider entrepreneurship developments in China since the end of the 1970s and argue that the role of entrepreneurship in the economy has changed considerably over the last four decades. Our perception is that initially, China’s entrepreneurship development stemmed from China’s economic transition, but currently, entrepreneurship is both influenced by and influences economic development. We propose a conceptual model of the role of entrepreneurship in China’s contemporary economy, which we test using a unique database for 31 Chinese regions during the period from 1997 to 2009. Our analysis shows that two types of entrepreneurial organizations (siyingqiye and getihu) in China play important but distinct roles in stimulating China’s economic development.
中国从中央计划经济向市场经济转型的最显著特征之一是企业家精神的出现,尽管以前的文献对这一现象的讨论是描述性的,而不是规范性的。在这篇文章中,我们考虑了自20世纪70年代末以来中国的创业发展,并认为在过去的40年里,创业在经济中的作用发生了很大的变化。我们的看法是,最初,中国的创业发展源于中国的经济转型,但目前,创业既受到经济发展的影响,也影响着经济发展。本文提出了企业家精神在中国当代经济中的作用的概念模型,并利用1997 - 2009年中国31个地区的独特数据库对其进行了检验。我们的分析表明,在中国,四营齐业和个提户两种类型的创业组织在促进中国经济发展中发挥着重要但不同的作用。
{"title":"Economic Transition and Entrepreneurship Development in China","authors":"Ying Zhang, Andre J. van Stel","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3623292","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3623292","url":null,"abstract":"One of the most prominent features of China’s transition from a centrally planned economy to a market-based economy is the emergence of entrepreneurship, although previous literature discusses this phenomenon descriptively rather than prescriptively. In this article, we consider entrepreneurship developments in China since the end of the 1970s and argue that the role of entrepreneurship in the economy has changed considerably over the last four decades. Our perception is that initially, China’s entrepreneurship development stemmed from China’s economic transition, but currently, entrepreneurship is both influenced by and influences economic development. We propose a conceptual model of the role of entrepreneurship in China’s contemporary economy, which we test using a unique database for 31 Chinese regions during the period from 1997 to 2009. Our analysis shows that two types of entrepreneurial organizations (siyingqiye and getihu) in China play important but distinct roles in stimulating China’s economic development.","PeriodicalId":90732,"journal":{"name":"Stanford technology law review : STLR : an online high-technology law journal from Stanford Law School","volume":"83 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2016-09-09","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"86513545","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Price Discovery Dynamics of Corporate Credit Default Swaps and Bonds 企业信用违约掉期和债券的价格发现动态
Josephine Molleyres
This paper empirically analyzes in a time-varying context if the U.S. corporate Credit Default Swaps (CDS) and bond markets of 81 reference entities reflect the same information on their prices between October 2004 and December 2010. The analysis shows that the theoretical no-arbitrage relation between CDS and bond spreads holds during economic stable times, but is violated as soon as markets are exposed to economic turmoil as in the financial crisis starting in August 2007. The difference between CDS and bond spreads, called the basis, is more volatile the lower the firms are rated. The price discovery is unaffected by the reference entities' credit rating and is strongly time-varying. Nevertheless the CDS spreads lead the price discovery process. Price discovery is significantly influenced uniquely by counterparty risk only when economic risks achieve abnormal levels as during the 2007/2008 financial crisis. Other risks as interbank liquidity risk, global risk and financing costs aren't considered by CDS traders when markets are facing abnormal risks. The more the markets are exposed to counterparty risk, defined as the risk that the CDS seller defaults, the less the price discovery takes place in the CDS market and therefore the more the bond spreads tend to reflect credit risk more efficiently than the CDS spreads. Thus market participants have the tendency to abscond from the CDS market as soon as counterparty risk is elevated. Because price discovery still takes place in the CDS market, economic risks are strongly underestimated by market participants.
本文对2004年10月至2010年12月期间81个参考实体的美国企业信用违约互换(CDS)和债券市场是否反映相同的价格信息进行了时变背景下的实证分析。分析表明,理论上CDS和债券利差之间的无套利关系在经济稳定时期成立,但一旦市场暴露于经济动荡(如2007年8月开始的金融危机),就会被打破。信用违约掉期和债券息差之间的差额,也就是所谓的基差,越低评级的公司越不稳定。价格发现不受参考实体信用评级的影响,并且具有很强的时变性。然而,CDS价差引领了价格发现过程。只有当经济风险达到2007/2008年金融危机期间的异常水平时,价格发现才会受到交易对手风险的显著影响。当市场面临异常风险时,CDS交易者不会考虑银行间流动性风险、全球风险和融资成本等风险。市场越是暴露于交易对手风险(定义为CDS卖方违约的风险),CDS市场上的价格发现就越少,因此债券息差往往比CDS息差更能有效地反映信用风险。因此,一旦交易对手风险升高,市场参与者就有逃离CDS市场的倾向。由于CDS市场仍然存在价格发现,市场参与者严重低估了经济风险。
{"title":"Price Discovery Dynamics of Corporate Credit Default Swaps and Bonds","authors":"Josephine Molleyres","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.2817819","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2817819","url":null,"abstract":"This paper empirically analyzes in a time-varying context if the U.S. corporate Credit Default Swaps (CDS) and bond markets of 81 reference entities reflect the same information on their prices between October 2004 and December 2010. The analysis shows that the theoretical no-arbitrage relation between CDS and bond spreads holds during economic stable times, but is violated as soon as markets are exposed to economic turmoil as in the financial crisis starting in August 2007. The difference between CDS and bond spreads, called the basis, is more volatile the lower the firms are rated. The price discovery is unaffected by the reference entities' credit rating and is strongly time-varying. Nevertheless the CDS spreads lead the price discovery process. Price discovery is significantly influenced uniquely by counterparty risk only when economic risks achieve abnormal levels as during the 2007/2008 financial crisis. Other risks as interbank liquidity risk, global risk and financing costs aren't considered by CDS traders when markets are facing abnormal risks. The more the markets are exposed to counterparty risk, defined as the risk that the CDS seller defaults, the less the price discovery takes place in the CDS market and therefore the more the bond spreads tend to reflect credit risk more efficiently than the CDS spreads. Thus market participants have the tendency to abscond from the CDS market as soon as counterparty risk is elevated. Because price discovery still takes place in the CDS market, economic risks are strongly underestimated by market participants.","PeriodicalId":90732,"journal":{"name":"Stanford technology law review : STLR : an online high-technology law journal from Stanford Law School","volume":"1 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2016-08-03","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"88111905","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
The Medieval Expansion of Long-Distance Trade: Adam Smith on the Town's Escape from the Violent and Low-Growth Feudal Equilibrium 中世纪长距离贸易的扩张:亚当·斯密论城镇从暴力和低增长的封建均衡中逃脱
Barry R. Weingast
Most people in medieval Europe lived at subsistence in a violent feudal world. Adam Smith explained both the long-term stability of the feudal system and how the towns escaped this violence trap through political exchange that fostered their ability to enter long-distance trade, significant division of labor, and economic growth and development. Violence is central to Smith's approach to development, which Smith scholars have systematically under-appreciated. In the face of episodic violence, individuals had little incentives to be industrious, to save, or to invest. Smith argued that the medieval towns escaped the violence trap through trade expansion. In Smith's view, development required three mutually reinforcing elements – liberty; commerce, including long-distance trade; and security from all forms of violence.
在中世纪的欧洲,大多数人都生活在一个暴力的封建世界里,勉强糊口。亚当·斯密既解释了封建制度的长期稳定,也解释了城镇是如何通过政治交换摆脱暴力陷阱的。政治交换促进了城镇进入长途贸易、重大劳动分工和经济增长与发展的能力。暴力是斯密发展方法的核心,而这一点一直被史密斯学者系统性地低估了。面对偶发的暴力,个人几乎没有动力去勤劳、储蓄或投资。史密斯认为,中世纪城镇通过贸易扩张摆脱了暴力陷阱。在斯密看来,发展需要三个相互促进的要素——自由;商业,包括长途贸易;以及免受各种形式暴力侵害的安全。
{"title":"The Medieval Expansion of Long-Distance Trade: Adam Smith on the Town's Escape from the Violent and Low-Growth Feudal Equilibrium","authors":"Barry R. Weingast","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.2789131","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2789131","url":null,"abstract":"Most people in medieval Europe lived at subsistence in a violent feudal world. Adam Smith explained both the long-term stability of the feudal system and how the towns escaped this violence trap through political exchange that fostered their ability to enter long-distance trade, significant division of labor, and economic growth and development. Violence is central to Smith's approach to development, which Smith scholars have systematically under-appreciated. In the face of episodic violence, individuals had little incentives to be industrious, to save, or to invest. Smith argued that the medieval towns escaped the violence trap through trade expansion. In Smith's view, development required three mutually reinforcing elements – liberty; commerce, including long-distance trade; and security from all forms of violence.","PeriodicalId":90732,"journal":{"name":"Stanford technology law review : STLR : an online high-technology law journal from Stanford Law School","volume":"238 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2016-06-02","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"77023143","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 3
The Surprising Resilience of the Patent System 专利制度的惊人弹性
Mark A. Lemley
The patent system seems in the midst of truly dramatic change. The last twenty years have seen the rise of a new business model – the patent troll – that grew to become a majority of all patent lawsuits. They have seen a significant expansion in the number of patents granted and a fundamental change in the industries in which those patents are filed. They have seen the passage of the most important legislative reform in the last sixty years, a law that reoriented legal challenges to patents away from courts and toward the Patent and Trademark Office (PTO). And they have seen remarkable changes in nearly every important legal doctrine, from patent eligibility to obviousness to infringement to remedies. These changes have prompted alarm in a number of quarters. From the 1990s to the 2000s, as the number of patents and patent troll suits skyrocketed, technology companies and academics worried about the “crisis” in the patent system – a crisis of overprotection that might interfere with rather than promote innovation. By 2015, as patent reform took effect and the Supreme Court undid many of the Federal Circuit’s expansions of patent rights, it was patent owners who were speaking of a crisis in the patent system – a crisis of underprotection that might leave innovators without adequate protection. Depending on one’s perspective, then, the sky seems to have been falling on the patent system for some time. Despite the undeniable significance of these changes in both directions, something curious has happened to the fundamental characteristics of the patent ecosystem during this period: very little. Whether we look at the number of patent applications filed, the number of patents issued, the number of lawsuits filed, the patentee win rate in those lawsuits, or the market for patent licenses, the data show very little evidence that patent owners and challengers are behaving differently because of changes in the law. The patent system, then, seems surprisingly resilient to changes in the law. This is a puzzle. In this article, I document this phenomenon and give some thought to why the fundamental characteristics of the patent system seem resistant to even major changes in patent law and procedure. The results pose some profound questions not only for efforts at patent reform but for the role of the patent system in society as a whole.
专利制度似乎正处于真正戏剧性的变革之中。在过去的二十年里,我们看到了一种新的商业模式的兴起——专利巨魔——它已经成为所有专利诉讼的主要内容。他们看到了专利授权数量的显著增长,以及这些专利申请所在行业的根本变化。他们见证了过去60年来最重要的立法改革的通过,这部法律将专利的法律挑战从法院转向专利商标局(PTO)。他们看到几乎每一个重要的法律原则都发生了显著的变化,从专利资格到显而易见性,从侵权到补救措施。这些变化已在多个季度引起警觉。从20世纪90年代到21世纪初,随着专利和专利流氓诉讼数量的飙升,科技公司和学者担心专利制度中的“危机”——一种过度保护的危机,可能会干扰而不是促进创新。到2015年,随着专利改革生效,最高法院撤销了联邦巡回法院对专利权的许多扩展,专利所有者开始谈论专利制度的危机——保护不足的危机可能会让创新者得不到充分的保护。因此,从不同的角度来看,专利制度似乎已经垮了一段时间。尽管这两个方向的变化都具有不可否认的重要性,但在此期间,专利生态系统的基本特征发生了一些奇怪的变化:变化很少。无论我们看的是提交的专利申请数量、发布的专利数量、提起的诉讼数量、在这些诉讼中专利权人的胜率,还是专利许可市场,数据都显示,几乎没有证据表明专利所有者和挑战者的行为因法律的变化而有所不同。因此,专利制度似乎对法律的变化有着惊人的弹性。这是个谜题。在本文中,我记录了这一现象,并对为什么专利制度的基本特征似乎抵制专利法和程序的重大变化进行了一些思考。研究结果不仅对专利改革的努力,而且对专利制度在整个社会中的作用提出了一些深刻的问题。
{"title":"The Surprising Resilience of the Patent System","authors":"Mark A. Lemley","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.2784456","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2784456","url":null,"abstract":"The patent system seems in the midst of truly dramatic change. The last twenty years have seen the rise of a new business model – the patent troll – that grew to become a majority of all patent lawsuits. They have seen a significant expansion in the number of patents granted and a fundamental change in the industries in which those patents are filed. They have seen the passage of the most important legislative reform in the last sixty years, a law that reoriented legal challenges to patents away from courts and toward the Patent and Trademark Office (PTO). And they have seen remarkable changes in nearly every important legal doctrine, from patent eligibility to obviousness to infringement to remedies. These changes have prompted alarm in a number of quarters. From the 1990s to the 2000s, as the number of patents and patent troll suits skyrocketed, technology companies and academics worried about the “crisis” in the patent system – a crisis of overprotection that might interfere with rather than promote innovation. By 2015, as patent reform took effect and the Supreme Court undid many of the Federal Circuit’s expansions of patent rights, it was patent owners who were speaking of a crisis in the patent system – a crisis of underprotection that might leave innovators without adequate protection. Depending on one’s perspective, then, the sky seems to have been falling on the patent system for some time. Despite the undeniable significance of these changes in both directions, something curious has happened to the fundamental characteristics of the patent ecosystem during this period: very little. Whether we look at the number of patent applications filed, the number of patents issued, the number of lawsuits filed, the patentee win rate in those lawsuits, or the market for patent licenses, the data show very little evidence that patent owners and challengers are behaving differently because of changes in the law. The patent system, then, seems surprisingly resilient to changes in the law. This is a puzzle. In this article, I document this phenomenon and give some thought to why the fundamental characteristics of the patent system seem resistant to even major changes in patent law and procedure. The results pose some profound questions not only for efforts at patent reform but for the role of the patent system in society as a whole.","PeriodicalId":90732,"journal":{"name":"Stanford technology law review : STLR : an online high-technology law journal from Stanford Law School","volume":"26 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2016-05-25","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"89303812","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 14
Rejecting the Grand Bargain: What Happens When Large Companies Opt Out of Workers’ Compensation? 拒绝大交易:当大公司选择退出工人赔偿会发生什么?
Alison D. Morantz
The “grand bargain” of workers’ compensation, whereby workers relinquished the right to sue their employers in exchange for no-fault occupational injury insurance, was one of the great tort reforms of the Twentieth Century. However, there is one U.S. state that has always permitted employers to decline workers’ compensation coverage, and in which many firms (“nonsubscribers”) have chosen to do so: Texas. This study examines the impact of Texas nonsubscription on fifteen large, multistate nonsubscribers that provided their Texas employees with customized occupational injury insurance benefits (“private plans”) in lieu of workers’ compensation coverage between 1998 and 2010. As economic theory would lead one to expect, nonsubscription generated considerable cost savings. My preferred estimates suggest that costs per worker hour fell by about 44 percent. These savings were driven by a drop in the frequency of more serious claims involving replacement of lost wages, and by a decline in costs per claim. Both medical and wage-replacement costs fell substantially. Although the decline in wage-replacement costs was larger in percentage terms than the drop in medical costs, the latter was equally financially consequential since medical costs comprise a larger share of total costs. The second stage, which compares the effect of nonsubscription across different types of injuries, finds that non-traumatic injury claims were more responsive to nonsubscription than traumatic ones. In part, this disparity reflects the fact that private plans categorically exclude some non-traumatic injuries from the scope of coverage. Yet even those non-traumatic injuries that were not excluded from coverage declined more than traumatic injuries, consistent with aggressive claim screening by employers and/or a decline in over-claiming and over-utilization by employees in the nonsubscription environment. The third stage examines the effect of nonsubscription on severe, traumatic injuries, which are generally the least susceptible to reporting bias and moral hazard. The sizable and significant decline in such injuries is consistent with an improvement in real safety, although it could also be explained by aggressive claim screening. The final stage of the study probes whether four ubiquitous features of private plans – non-coverage of permanent partial disabilities, categorical exclusion of many diseases and some non-traumatic injuries, capped benefits, and lack of chiropractic care – explain the observed trends. Surprisingly, these features account for little of the estimated cost savings. Although many study participants describe limited provider choice and 24-hour reporting windows as major cost drivers, data limitations preclude me from identifying their respective impacts. Overall, my findings suggest an urgent need for policymakers to examine the economic and distributional effects of converting workers’ compensation from a cornerstone of the social welfare state into an op
工人赔偿的“大交易”,即工人放弃起诉雇主的权利,以换取无过错工伤保险,是20世纪最伟大的侵权改革之一。然而,美国有一个州一直允许雇主拒绝工人的赔偿保险,而且许多公司(“非订户”)选择这样做:德克萨斯州。本研究考察了1998年至2010年间,15家大型、多州的非参保者为其德克萨斯州员工提供定制的工伤保险福利(“私人计划”),以代替工人赔偿。正如经济理论所引导的那样,不订阅产生了可观的成本节约。我最喜欢的估计是,每工人小时的成本下降了约44%。这些节余的原因是涉及补偿损失的工资的较严重索赔要求的频率下降,以及每项索赔要求的费用下降。医疗和工资替代成本都大幅下降。虽然按百分比计算,工资重置费用的下降幅度大于医疗费用的下降幅度,但后者在财务上同样重要,因为医疗费用在总费用中所占比例更大。第二阶段,比较不同类型伤害的不订阅效果,发现非创伤性伤害索赔比创伤性伤害索赔对不订阅更有反应。在某种程度上,这种差异反映了这样一个事实,即私人保险计划明确地将一些非创伤性伤害排除在保险范围之外。然而,即使是那些没有被排除在保险范围之外的非创伤性伤害,其下降幅度也大于创伤性伤害,这与雇主积极的索赔筛选和/或非订阅环境下员工过度索赔和过度使用的下降是一致的。第三阶段考察不订阅对严重创伤性伤害的影响,这些伤害通常最不容易受到报道偏见和道德风险的影响。这类伤害的显著下降与实际安全性的提高是一致的,尽管这也可以解释为积极的索赔筛选。研究的最后阶段探讨了私人计划的四个普遍特征——不包括永久性部分残疾、完全排除许多疾病和一些非创伤性伤害、有上限的福利以及缺乏脊椎治疗——是否解释了观察到的趋势。令人惊讶的是,这些功能在估计的成本节约中只占很小一部分。尽管许多研究参与者将有限的供应商选择和24小时报告窗口描述为主要的成本驱动因素,但数据限制使我无法确定它们各自的影响。总的来说,我的研究结果表明,政策制定者迫切需要研究将工人赔偿从社会福利国家的基石转变为与私人提供的工伤保险形式并存的可选项目的经济和分配效应。
{"title":"Rejecting the Grand Bargain: What Happens When Large Companies Opt Out of Workers’ Compensation?","authors":"Alison D. Morantz","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.2750134","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2750134","url":null,"abstract":"The “grand bargain” of workers’ compensation, whereby workers relinquished the right to sue their employers in exchange for no-fault occupational injury insurance, was one of the great tort reforms of the Twentieth Century. However, there is one U.S. state that has always permitted employers to decline workers’ compensation coverage, and in which many firms (“nonsubscribers”) have chosen to do so: Texas. This study examines the impact of Texas nonsubscription on fifteen large, multistate nonsubscribers that provided their Texas employees with customized occupational injury insurance benefits (“private plans”) in lieu of workers’ compensation coverage between 1998 and 2010. As economic theory would lead one to expect, nonsubscription generated considerable cost savings. My preferred estimates suggest that costs per worker hour fell by about 44 percent. These savings were driven by a drop in the frequency of more serious claims involving replacement of lost wages, and by a decline in costs per claim. Both medical and wage-replacement costs fell substantially. Although the decline in wage-replacement costs was larger in percentage terms than the drop in medical costs, the latter was equally financially consequential since medical costs comprise a larger share of total costs. The second stage, which compares the effect of nonsubscription across different types of injuries, finds that non-traumatic injury claims were more responsive to nonsubscription than traumatic ones. In part, this disparity reflects the fact that private plans categorically exclude some non-traumatic injuries from the scope of coverage. Yet even those non-traumatic injuries that were not excluded from coverage declined more than traumatic injuries, consistent with aggressive claim screening by employers and/or a decline in over-claiming and over-utilization by employees in the nonsubscription environment. The third stage examines the effect of nonsubscription on severe, traumatic injuries, which are generally the least susceptible to reporting bias and moral hazard. The sizable and significant decline in such injuries is consistent with an improvement in real safety, although it could also be explained by aggressive claim screening. The final stage of the study probes whether four ubiquitous features of private plans – non-coverage of permanent partial disabilities, categorical exclusion of many diseases and some non-traumatic injuries, capped benefits, and lack of chiropractic care – explain the observed trends. Surprisingly, these features account for little of the estimated cost savings. Although many study participants describe limited provider choice and 24-hour reporting windows as major cost drivers, data limitations preclude me from identifying their respective impacts. Overall, my findings suggest an urgent need for policymakers to examine the economic and distributional effects of converting workers’ compensation from a cornerstone of the social welfare state into an op","PeriodicalId":90732,"journal":{"name":"Stanford technology law review : STLR : an online high-technology law journal from Stanford Law School","volume":"38 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2016-03-18","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"90158285","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 6
期刊
Stanford technology law review : STLR : an online high-technology law journal from Stanford Law School
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1