首页 > 最新文献

Industrial Organization & Regulation eJournal最新文献

英文 中文
Local Electricity Distribution in Italy: Comparative Efficiency Analysis and Methodological Cross-Checking 意大利地方电力分配:比较效率分析和方法交叉检验
Pub Date : 1999-01-12 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.158815
G. Scarsi
This paper analyzes the efficiency of Italy's local electricity distributors according to two different measurement techniques. Distribution zones belonging to the national monopolist (ENEL) are compared with municipally-owned utilities (MUNIs) which serve individual towns and are usually owned by City Councils (with a few of them currently undergoing privatization). ENEL-MUNI comparisons are displayed subject to a number of caveats, and statistical techniques are used in order to cross-check the results stemming from different methodologies. The paper's main finding is that comparative efficiency analysis failed to spot any systematic efficiency superiority of ENEL's local units over municipal utilities. Overall efficiency comparison outcomes were mixed, thus suggesting that a case-by-case approach should be adopted by Italy's regulatory and governmental authorities when dealing with the territorial reform of electricity distribution. Similarly, any ownership transfers and/or mergers involving ENEL?s units and MUNIs should depend on the varied efficiency records which were detected according to different regional and economic scenarios.
本文采用两种不同的计量方法对意大利地方配电机构的效率进行了分析。属于国家垄断者(ENEL)的配送区与市政拥有的公用事业(MUNIs)相比,市政拥有的公用事业服务于各个城镇,通常由市议会拥有(其中一些目前正在进行私有化)。ENEL-MUNI比较的显示受到一些注意事项的限制,并使用统计技术来交叉检查来自不同方法的结果。本文的主要发现是,比较效率分析未能发现ENEL的地方单位比市政公用事业公司有任何系统效率优势。总体效率比较结果好坏参半,因此,意大利的监管机构和政府当局在处理电力分配的领土改革时应采取具体情况具体分析的方法。同样,是否有涉及ENEL的所有权转让和/或合并?根据根据不同区域和经济情况所发现的不同效率记录,各单位和市政管理机构应有所不同。
{"title":"Local Electricity Distribution in Italy: Comparative Efficiency Analysis and Methodological Cross-Checking","authors":"G. Scarsi","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.158815","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.158815","url":null,"abstract":"This paper analyzes the efficiency of Italy's local electricity distributors according to two different measurement techniques. Distribution zones belonging to the national monopolist (ENEL) are compared with municipally-owned utilities (MUNIs) which serve individual towns and are usually owned by City Councils (with a few of them currently undergoing privatization). ENEL-MUNI comparisons are displayed subject to a number of caveats, and statistical techniques are used in order to cross-check the results stemming from different methodologies. The paper's main finding is that comparative efficiency analysis failed to spot any systematic efficiency superiority of ENEL's local units over municipal utilities. Overall efficiency comparison outcomes were mixed, thus suggesting that a case-by-case approach should be adopted by Italy's regulatory and governmental authorities when dealing with the territorial reform of electricity distribution. Similarly, any ownership transfers and/or mergers involving ENEL?s units and MUNIs should depend on the varied efficiency records which were detected according to different regional and economic scenarios.","PeriodicalId":151613,"journal":{"name":"Industrial Organization & Regulation eJournal","volume":"11 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"1999-01-12","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"125466893","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 22
Pricing Over the Product Cycle: The Transition from the 486 to the Pentium Processor 产品周期中的定价:从486到奔腾处理器的过渡
Pub Date : 1999-01-01 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.159083
G. Deltas, Eleftherios Zacharias
Using a high frequency data-set of advertised prices in the personal computer industry, we find that firms which introduced Pentium computers late in the "buy Direct" segment of the market command a higher price premium compared to early entrants. This is true even among firms which have the same price premium for their 486 computers, but is more pronounced for high quality firms. Over time, the difference in the Pentium price premia of the late versus the early entrants decline to levels of the difference in the corresponding 486 price premia. The decline in the relative Pentium price premia contributes to a decline in overall price dispersion, while price dispersion for 486 computers remains constant. These results suggest that late entrants reap short run rents from these consumers that are loyal enough to them to have waited until their entry in order to purchase. They also suggest a rapidly declining price premium for quality over the product cycle. In light of these findings, brand coefficients in hedonistic regressions using high frequency data should not be interpreted as capturing unobserved quality only.
使用个人电脑行业广告价格的高频数据集,我们发现在“直接购买”细分市场中较晚推出奔腾电脑的公司比早期进入者获得更高的价格溢价。即使在486电脑有相同溢价的公司中也是如此,但在高质量的公司中更为明显。随着时间的推移,较晚进入者与较早进入者的奔腾价格溢价差下降到相应的486价格溢价差的水平。奔腾相对价格溢价的下降有助于整体价格分散度的下降,而486电脑的价格分散度保持不变。这些结果表明,后期进入者从这些消费者那里获得了短期的租金,这些消费者对他们足够忠诚,直到他们进入才购买。它们还表明,在整个产品周期中,质量的价格溢价正在迅速下降。根据这些发现,使用高频数据的享乐主义回归中的品牌系数不应被解释为仅捕获未观察到的质量。
{"title":"Pricing Over the Product Cycle: The Transition from the 486 to the Pentium Processor","authors":"G. Deltas, Eleftherios Zacharias","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.159083","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.159083","url":null,"abstract":"Using a high frequency data-set of advertised prices in the personal computer industry, we find that firms which introduced Pentium computers late in the \"buy Direct\" segment of the market command a higher price premium compared to early entrants. This is true even among firms which have the same price premium for their 486 computers, but is more pronounced for high quality firms. Over time, the difference in the Pentium price premia of the late versus the early entrants decline to levels of the difference in the corresponding 486 price premia. The decline in the relative Pentium price premia contributes to a decline in overall price dispersion, while price dispersion for 486 computers remains constant. These results suggest that late entrants reap short run rents from these consumers that are loyal enough to them to have waited until their entry in order to purchase. They also suggest a rapidly declining price premium for quality over the product cycle. In light of these findings, brand coefficients in hedonistic regressions using high frequency data should not be interpreted as capturing unobserved quality only.","PeriodicalId":151613,"journal":{"name":"Industrial Organization & Regulation eJournal","volume":"20 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"1999-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"122520103","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
A Quantitative Approach to Measure Quality-Based Competitiveness of an Organization 衡量组织质量竞争力的定量方法
Pub Date : 1999-01-01 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.160263
Ashok Kumar, J. Motwani, K. Stecke
The operations strategy literature has identified four primary dimensions on which a firm competes with another. These are: price, quality, flexibility, and delivery dependability. Of these, quality is perhaps the most critical dimension in terms of the influence a competitive dimension exercises on the competitiveness of a firm. In this paper, we propose a quantitative measure--Quality-Competitiveness Index (QCI)--to determine the degree to which a firm's quality practices and policies are instrumental in improving its competitiveness. The QCI can be effectively employed for benchmarking among competing firms. More importantly, however, the process involved in the determination of a QCI is itself an educative one. It brings weaknesses and strengths of a company with respect to its quality practices and policies to the surfaces with pinpoint accuracy and can, therefore, be usefully employed to improve its quality competitiveness in an effective manner.
经营战略文献已经确定了一个公司与另一个公司竞争的四个主要方面。它们是:价格、质量、灵活性和交货可靠性。其中,就竞争因素对企业竞争力的影响而言,质量可能是最关键的因素。在本文中,我们提出了一种定量度量——质量竞争力指数(QCI)——来确定企业的质量实践和政策在提高其竞争力方面的作用程度。QCI可以有效地用于竞争企业之间的基准。然而,更重要的是,确定质量ci的过程本身就是一个教育过程。它将公司在质量实践和政策方面的弱点和优势以精确的精度呈现出来,因此可以有效地用于提高其质量竞争力。
{"title":"A Quantitative Approach to Measure Quality-Based Competitiveness of an Organization","authors":"Ashok Kumar, J. Motwani, K. Stecke","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.160263","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.160263","url":null,"abstract":"The operations strategy literature has identified four primary dimensions on which a firm competes with another. These are: price, quality, flexibility, and delivery dependability. Of these, quality is perhaps the most critical dimension in terms of the influence a competitive dimension exercises on the competitiveness of a firm. In this paper, we propose a quantitative measure--Quality-Competitiveness Index (QCI)--to determine the degree to which a firm's quality practices and policies are instrumental in improving its competitiveness. The QCI can be effectively employed for benchmarking among competing firms. More importantly, however, the process involved in the determination of a QCI is itself an educative one. It brings weaknesses and strengths of a company with respect to its quality practices and policies to the surfaces with pinpoint accuracy and can, therefore, be usefully employed to improve its quality competitiveness in an effective manner.","PeriodicalId":151613,"journal":{"name":"Industrial Organization & Regulation eJournal","volume":"38 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"1999-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"131879863","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
The Lives of the Painters of Modern Life: the Careers of Artists in France from Impressionism to Cubism 现代生活画家的生活:法国艺术家的职业生涯从印象派到立体派
Pub Date : 1999-01-01 DOI: 10.3386/W6888
David W. Galenson
Modern painting began in France during the nineteenth century. Using transactions from art auctions for the work of 50 leading painters who worked in France during the first century of modern art, I estimate the relationship between the value of a painting and the artist's age at the date of its execution. The econometric estimates show that artists born before 1850 - including Manet, C‚zanne, and Degas - typically produced their most valuable work late in their careers, whereas artists born after 1850 - including Picasso, L‚ger, and Braque - were more likely to have done their most valuable work at early ages. Comparison of these results to evidence drawn from art history textbooks furthermore demonstrates that these artists' most valuable work has also been that most highly regarded by scholars. I argue that the change over time in the shape of these artists' age-price profiles was a result of changes in the nature of painting during the late nineteenth century, as painting increasingly became an activity in which innovation was a principal determinant of an artist's importance.
现代绘画起源于19世纪的法国。通过对现代艺术的第一个世纪在法国工作的50位主要画家作品的拍卖交易,我估计了一幅画的价值与艺术家创作之日的年龄之间的关系。计量经济学估计表明,1850年以前出生的艺术家——包括马奈、C、尚和德加——通常在他们职业生涯的后期创作了他们最有价值的作品,而1850年以后出生的艺术家——包括毕加索、L、格尔和布拉克——更有可能在早期完成了他们最有价值的作品。将这些结果与艺术史教科书中的证据进行比较,进一步表明这些艺术家最有价值的作品也受到了学者们的高度重视。我认为,随着时间的推移,这些艺术家的年龄-价格轮廓的变化是19世纪后期绘画性质变化的结果,因为绘画越来越成为一种活动,其中创新是艺术家重要性的主要决定因素。
{"title":"The Lives of the Painters of Modern Life: the Careers of Artists in France from Impressionism to Cubism","authors":"David W. Galenson","doi":"10.3386/W6888","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.3386/W6888","url":null,"abstract":"Modern painting began in France during the nineteenth century. Using transactions from art auctions for the work of 50 leading painters who worked in France during the first century of modern art, I estimate the relationship between the value of a painting and the artist's age at the date of its execution. The econometric estimates show that artists born before 1850 - including Manet, C‚zanne, and Degas - typically produced their most valuable work late in their careers, whereas artists born after 1850 - including Picasso, L‚ger, and Braque - were more likely to have done their most valuable work at early ages. Comparison of these results to evidence drawn from art history textbooks furthermore demonstrates that these artists' most valuable work has also been that most highly regarded by scholars. I argue that the change over time in the shape of these artists' age-price profiles was a result of changes in the nature of painting during the late nineteenth century, as painting increasingly became an activity in which innovation was a principal determinant of an artist's importance.","PeriodicalId":151613,"journal":{"name":"Industrial Organization & Regulation eJournal","volume":"84 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"1999-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"124976234","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 12
Factor Adjustment, Quality Change, and Productivity Growth for U.S. Manufacturing 美国制造业的要素调整、质量变化和生产率增长
Pub Date : 1999-01-01 DOI: 10.3386/W6877
J. Bernstein, T. Mamuneas, P. Pashardes
This paper accounts for quality improvements and adjustment costs in all inputs to U.S. manufacturing production. Adjustment processes for non-capital inputs are slower than previously recognized. Annual adjustment percentages are: labor 77, capital 30, energy 20, and materials 21. Factor prices should be adjusted for quality improvements to reflect higher marginal products. The percentage increases in marginal products from quality improvements are: labor 0.25, capital 0.30, energy 2.13, and materials 0.92. Observed input growth should be adjusted for quality improvements. Unadjusted input growth causes efficiency-based productivity growth rates to exceed observed productivity growth in the slowdown period of 1974 - 1995.
本文考虑了美国制造业生产中所有投入的质量改进和调整成本。非资本投入的调整进程比以前认识到的要慢。年度调整百分比为:人工77%,资本30%,能源20%,材料21%。要素价格应根据质量改进进行调整,以反映更高的边际产品。质量改进带来的边际产品增长百分比为:劳动力增长0.25,资本增长0.30,能源增长2.13,材料增长0.92。观察到的投入增长应根据质量改进进行调整。未经调整的投入增长导致以效率为基础的生产率增长率超过1974 - 1995年经济放缓期间观察到的生产率增长率。
{"title":"Factor Adjustment, Quality Change, and Productivity Growth for U.S. Manufacturing","authors":"J. Bernstein, T. Mamuneas, P. Pashardes","doi":"10.3386/W6877","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.3386/W6877","url":null,"abstract":"This paper accounts for quality improvements and adjustment costs in all inputs to U.S. manufacturing production. Adjustment processes for non-capital inputs are slower than previously recognized. Annual adjustment percentages are: labor 77, capital 30, energy 20, and materials 21. Factor prices should be adjusted for quality improvements to reflect higher marginal products. The percentage increases in marginal products from quality improvements are: labor 0.25, capital 0.30, energy 2.13, and materials 0.92. Observed input growth should be adjusted for quality improvements. Unadjusted input growth causes efficiency-based productivity growth rates to exceed observed productivity growth in the slowdown period of 1974 - 1995.","PeriodicalId":151613,"journal":{"name":"Industrial Organization & Regulation eJournal","volume":"20 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"1999-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"128471346","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2
When Industries Become More Productive, Do Firms? 当工业变得更有效率时,企业会吗?
Pub Date : 1999-01-01 DOI: 10.3386/W6893
J. Levinsohn, Amil Petrin
This paper investigates two explanations for why industries might become more productive over time. The first explanation, termed the real productivity case,' is one in which firms become more productive and this leads to more productive industries. The second explanation, termed the rationalization case,' is one in which firm productivity is constant, but productive firms expand while less productive firms either shrink or exit. Each case has very different implications for factor markets, long term growth prospects, and public policy regarding productivity. Further, one can only distinguish between these two cases with plant- or firm-level data. We investigate the empirical relevance of the two cases using the Chilean manufacturing census. We find that the rationalization case explains much of the measured increase in industry productivity. When industry productivity fails, the rationalization case appears much less important. We also contribute to the applied econometric literature on productivity estimation as we show that the value-added production function is especially well-suited to a simple extension of recent methods developed by Oiley and Pakes.
本文研究了两种解释,为什么工业可能会随着时间的推移而变得更有效率。第一种解释被称为“实际生产率案例”,在这种情况下,企业的生产率提高,从而导致行业的生产率提高。第二种解释被称为“合理化案例”,在这种情况下,企业生产率是恒定的,但生产率高的企业扩张,而生产率低的企业要么收缩,要么退出。每种情况对要素市场、长期增长前景和有关生产率的公共政策都有非常不同的影响。此外,人们只能用工厂或公司级别的数据来区分这两种情况。我们利用智利制造业普查调查了这两个案例的经验相关性。我们发现,合理化案例在很大程度上解释了工业生产率的测量增长。当工业生产率下降时,合理化的情况就显得不那么重要了。我们还为生产力估计的应用计量经济学文献做出了贡献,因为我们表明,增值生产函数特别适合于对奥利和帕克斯最近开发的方法的简单扩展。
{"title":"When Industries Become More Productive, Do Firms?","authors":"J. Levinsohn, Amil Petrin","doi":"10.3386/W6893","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.3386/W6893","url":null,"abstract":"This paper investigates two explanations for why industries might become more productive over time. The first explanation, termed the real productivity case,' is one in which firms become more productive and this leads to more productive industries. The second explanation, termed the rationalization case,' is one in which firm productivity is constant, but productive firms expand while less productive firms either shrink or exit. Each case has very different implications for factor markets, long term growth prospects, and public policy regarding productivity. Further, one can only distinguish between these two cases with plant- or firm-level data. We investigate the empirical relevance of the two cases using the Chilean manufacturing census. We find that the rationalization case explains much of the measured increase in industry productivity. When industry productivity fails, the rationalization case appears much less important. We also contribute to the applied econometric literature on productivity estimation as we show that the value-added production function is especially well-suited to a simple extension of recent methods developed by Oiley and Pakes.","PeriodicalId":151613,"journal":{"name":"Industrial Organization & Regulation eJournal","volume":"6 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"1999-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"132710556","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 47
Sunk Costs, Windows of Profit Opportunities, and the Dynamics of Entry 沉没成本、获利机会之窗和进入动力学
Pub Date : 1998-12-15 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.143028
G. Götz
This paper adds two elements to a standard model of monopolistic competition: First, the number of potential entrants is limited in each period and increases only over time. Second, the potential entrants differ with respect to the consumers' valuation of the variant they could offer. It is shown that the resulting simple model exhibits a rich dynamic structure covering cases like the product life cycle, a path dependent equilibrium and the traditional textbook case of entry. The welfare analysis confirms the view that you can't have too much entry.
本文在垄断竞争的标准模型中增加了两个要素:第一,潜在进入者的数量在每个时期都是有限的,并且只会随着时间的推移而增加。其次,潜在的进入者在消费者对他们所能提供的变体的评价方面存在差异。结果表明,所得到的简单模型具有丰富的动态结构,涵盖了产品生命周期、路径依赖均衡和传统教科书中的进入案例。福利分析证实了你不能有太多的进入。
{"title":"Sunk Costs, Windows of Profit Opportunities, and the Dynamics of Entry","authors":"G. Götz","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.143028","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.143028","url":null,"abstract":"This paper adds two elements to a standard model of monopolistic competition: First, the number of potential entrants is limited in each period and increases only over time. Second, the potential entrants differ with respect to the consumers' valuation of the variant they could offer. It is shown that the resulting simple model exhibits a rich dynamic structure covering cases like the product life cycle, a path dependent equilibrium and the traditional textbook case of entry. The welfare analysis confirms the view that you can't have too much entry.","PeriodicalId":151613,"journal":{"name":"Industrial Organization & Regulation eJournal","volume":"12 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"1998-12-15","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"122361030","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 17
Critical Mass Effect and Restructuring in the Transition Towards a Market Economy 向市场经济转型中的临界质量效应和结构调整
Pub Date : 1998-12-03 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.142031
P. Sacco, C. Scarpa
Restructuring firms in a transition economy produces a sort of network externality, in that the profitability of restructuring depends on the number of firms that already adopted this strategy. We investigate under what conditions a "critical mass" exists, i.e., a situation in which such externality is positive and restructuring spurs imitation, possibly leading to the eventual transformation of the whole economy. We find a critical mass effect when the main effect of restructuring is an increase in value added (i.e., aggregate demand) rather than an increase in the firm's ability to compete against rival home firms. The critical mass case becomes the typical one when competition spurs firms' efficiency.
转型经济中的企业重组产生了一种网络外部性,因为重组的盈利能力取决于已经采用这一战略的企业数量。我们研究在什么条件下存在“临界质量”,即这种外部性是积极的,重组刺激模仿的情况,可能导致整个经济的最终转型。我们发现,当重组的主要效果是增加附加值(即总需求)而不是增加公司与国内竞争对手竞争的能力时,就会产生临界质量效应。临界质量案例成为竞争刺激企业效率的典型案例。
{"title":"Critical Mass Effect and Restructuring in the Transition Towards a Market Economy","authors":"P. Sacco, C. Scarpa","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.142031","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.142031","url":null,"abstract":"Restructuring firms in a transition economy produces a sort of network externality, in that the profitability of restructuring depends on the number of firms that already adopted this strategy. We investigate under what conditions a \"critical mass\" exists, i.e., a situation in which such externality is positive and restructuring spurs imitation, possibly leading to the eventual transformation of the whole economy. We find a critical mass effect when the main effect of restructuring is an increase in value added (i.e., aggregate demand) rather than an increase in the firm's ability to compete against rival home firms. The critical mass case becomes the typical one when competition spurs firms' efficiency.","PeriodicalId":151613,"journal":{"name":"Industrial Organization & Regulation eJournal","volume":"1 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"1998-12-03","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"131985832","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 13
The Strategic Use of Tying to Preserve and Create Market Power in Evolving Industries 在不断发展的行业中,战略性地使用捆绑来保持和创造市场力量
Pub Date : 1998-12-01 DOI: 10.2307/3087430
D. Carlton, Michael Waldman
This article investigates how the tying of complementary products can be used to preserve and create monopoly positions. We first show how a monopolist of a product in the current period can use tying to preserve its monopoly in the future. We then show how a monopolist in one market can employ tying to extend its monopoly into a newly emerging market. Our analysis explains how a dominant firm can use tying to remain dominant in an industry undergoing rapid technological change. The analysis focuses on entry costs and network externalities. We also relate our analysis to the Microsoft case.
本文研究了如何利用互补产品的捆绑来保持和创造垄断地位。我们首先展示了当前产品的垄断者如何使用捆绑来保持其未来的垄断地位。然后,我们展示了一个市场的垄断者如何利用捆绑将其垄断延伸到一个新兴市场。我们的分析解释了一个占主导地位的公司如何利用捆绑在一个经历快速技术变革的行业中保持主导地位。分析的重点是进入成本和网络外部性。我们也将我们的分析与微软的案例联系起来。
{"title":"The Strategic Use of Tying to Preserve and Create Market Power in Evolving Industries","authors":"D. Carlton, Michael Waldman","doi":"10.2307/3087430","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2307/3087430","url":null,"abstract":"This article investigates how the tying of complementary products can be used to preserve and create monopoly positions. We first show how a monopolist of a product in the current period can use tying to preserve its monopoly in the future. We then show how a monopolist in one market can employ tying to extend its monopoly into a newly emerging market. Our analysis explains how a dominant firm can use tying to remain dominant in an industry undergoing rapid technological change. The analysis focuses on entry costs and network externalities. We also relate our analysis to the Microsoft case.","PeriodicalId":151613,"journal":{"name":"Industrial Organization & Regulation eJournal","volume":"5 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"1998-12-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"115236736","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 436
Firm Size and Determinants of Foreign Direct Investment 企业规模与外商直接投资的决定因素
Pub Date : 1998-12-01 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.154611
Y. Kinoshita
This paper studies the locational determinants of foreign direct investment (FDI) by Japanese manufacturing firms in seven Asian countries by utilizing the 1993 survey data. I show that different size- groups of firms react to different factors in the host country in making the foreign investment decisions. Low labor cost and sufficient infrastructure encourage small firms to invest in a certain country while, for large firms, market size of the host country and strategic considerations (e.g. whether competitors invested in the country or not) are most important for their locational decisions. Overall, availability of cheap labor is not necessarily an important factor for Japanese FDI in Asia.
本文利用1993年的调查数据,研究了日本制造业企业在7个亚洲国家的对外直接投资的区位决定因素。我表明,不同规模的公司集团在作出对外投资决策时,对东道国的不同因素作出反应。低廉的劳动力成本和充足的基础设施鼓励小公司在某个国家投资,而对于大公司来说,东道国的市场规模和战略考虑(例如竞争对手是否在该国投资)对其选址决策最重要。总的来说,廉价劳动力的可用性不一定是日本在亚洲直接投资的重要因素。
{"title":"Firm Size and Determinants of Foreign Direct Investment","authors":"Y. Kinoshita","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.154611","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.154611","url":null,"abstract":"This paper studies the locational determinants of foreign direct investment (FDI) by Japanese manufacturing firms in seven Asian countries by utilizing the 1993 survey data. I show that different size- groups of firms react to different factors in the host country in making the foreign investment decisions. Low labor cost and sufficient infrastructure encourage small firms to invest in a certain country while, for large firms, market size of the host country and strategic considerations (e.g. whether competitors invested in the country or not) are most important for their locational decisions. Overall, availability of cheap labor is not necessarily an important factor for Japanese FDI in Asia.","PeriodicalId":151613,"journal":{"name":"Industrial Organization & Regulation eJournal","volume":"22 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"1998-12-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"114805612","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 18
期刊
Industrial Organization & Regulation eJournal
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1