首页 > 最新文献

Industrial Organization & Regulation eJournal最新文献

英文 中文
Are There High-Tech Industries or Only High-Tech Firms? Evidence from New Technology-Based Firms 有高科技产业还是只有高科技公司?来自新技术企业的证据
Pub Date : 1998-12-01 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.143867
J. Baldwin, Guy Gellatly
Considerable attention has been directed at understanding the structural changes that are generating an increased need for skilled workers. These changes are perceived to be the result of developments associated with the emergence of the new knowledge economy, whose potential is often linked to the growth of new technology-based firms (NTBFs). Where are these firms to be found? Related work on changes in technology and innovativeness has been accompanied by the creation of taxonomies that classify industries as high-tech or high-knowledge, based primarily on the characteristics of large firms. There is a temptation to use these taxonomies to identify new technology-based firms only within certain sectors. This paper uses a special survey that collected data on new firms to argue that this would be unwise. The paper investigates the limitations of existing classification schemes that might be used to classify industries as high- or low-tech, as advanced or otherwise. Characteristically unidimensional in scope, many of these taxonomies employ conceptual and operational measures that are narrow and incomplete. Consequently, previous rankings that identify sectors as high- or low-tech using these measures obscure the degree of innovativeness and human capital formation exhibited by certain industries. In a policy environment wherein emotive 'scoreboard' classifications have direct effects on resource allocation, the social costs of misclassification are potentially significant. Using a comparative methodology, this study investigates the role that conceptualization plays in devising taxonomies of high- and low-tech industries. Far from producing definitive classifications, existing measures of technological advancement are found to be wanting when their underpinnings are examined closely. Our objective in the current analysis is to examine the limitations of standard classification schemes, particularly when applied to new small firms, and to suggest an alternative framework based on a competency-model of the firm.
相当多的注意力集中在了解产生对熟练工人需求增加的结构变化上。这些变化被认为是与新知识经济的出现相关的发展的结果,其潜力往往与新技术公司(ntbf)的增长有关。在哪里可以找到这些公司?关于技术变化和创新性的相关工作一直伴随着分类法的创建,这些分类法主要根据大公司的特点将工业分类为高科技或高知识。人们倾向于使用这些分类法来识别某些行业内的新技术公司。本文通过一项收集新公司数据的特殊调查来论证这是不明智的。本文调查了现有分类方案的局限性,这些分类方案可能用于将工业分类为高技术或低技术,先进或其他。这些分类法的范围通常是单维的,许多分类法采用的概念和操作度量是狭窄和不完整的。因此,以前使用这些措施确定高技术或低技术部门的排名模糊了某些行业的创新程度和人力资本形成的程度。在一个情绪化的“计分板”分类对资源分配有直接影响的政策环境中,错误分类的社会成本可能很大。本研究采用比较方法,探讨概念化在高新技术产业和低技术产业分类中所起的作用。如果仔细研究现有的技术进步衡量标准的基础,就会发现它们远远不能产生明确的分类。在当前的分析中,我们的目标是检查标准分类方案的局限性,特别是在适用于新的小型公司时,并根据公司的能力模型提出另一种框架。
{"title":"Are There High-Tech Industries or Only High-Tech Firms? Evidence from New Technology-Based Firms","authors":"J. Baldwin, Guy Gellatly","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.143867","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.143867","url":null,"abstract":"Considerable attention has been directed at understanding the structural changes that are generating an increased need for skilled workers. These changes are perceived to be the result of developments associated with the emergence of the new knowledge economy, whose potential is often linked to the growth of new technology-based firms (NTBFs). Where are these firms to be found? Related work on changes in technology and innovativeness has been accompanied by the creation of taxonomies that classify industries as high-tech or high-knowledge, based primarily on the characteristics of large firms. There is a temptation to use these taxonomies to identify new technology-based firms only within certain sectors. This paper uses a special survey that collected data on new firms to argue that this would be unwise. The paper investigates the limitations of existing classification schemes that might be used to classify industries as high- or low-tech, as advanced or otherwise. Characteristically unidimensional in scope, many of these taxonomies employ conceptual and operational measures that are narrow and incomplete. Consequently, previous rankings that identify sectors as high- or low-tech using these measures obscure the degree of innovativeness and human capital formation exhibited by certain industries. In a policy environment wherein emotive 'scoreboard' classifications have direct effects on resource allocation, the social costs of misclassification are potentially significant. Using a comparative methodology, this study investigates the role that conceptualization plays in devising taxonomies of high- and low-tech industries. Far from producing definitive classifications, existing measures of technological advancement are found to be wanting when their underpinnings are examined closely. Our objective in the current analysis is to examine the limitations of standard classification schemes, particularly when applied to new small firms, and to suggest an alternative framework based on a competency-model of the firm.","PeriodicalId":151613,"journal":{"name":"Industrial Organization & Regulation eJournal","volume":"48 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"1998-12-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"131398531","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 50
Multiproduct Competition between Congestible Networks 拥挤网络之间的多产品竞争
Pub Date : 1998-11-27 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.136739
R. Gibbens, R. Mason, R. Steinberg
This paper analyses competition between firms who sell multiple products in the presence of negative externalities. The model involves two networks who each may offer several service classes. Service classes are generated by forming sub-networks differentiated by their congestion levels. The level of congestion on a sub-network is determined by its capacity and the number of users, i.e., quality of demand-dependent. This paper shows that networks will choose to offer only one service class, and thus not to form distinct sub-networks, in equilibrium. In addition to contributing to the theory of multiproduct competition, the paper addresses applied problems. For example, the results suggest that current proposals to implement pricing on the Internet will not be viable under competition.
本文分析了在负外部性存在的情况下,销售多种产品的企业之间的竞争。该模型涉及两个网络,每个网络可能提供几个服务类别。服务分类是通过形成按拥塞程度区分的子网来产生的。子网络的拥塞程度取决于它的容量和用户数量,即需求依赖的质量。本文表明,在均衡状态下,网络只会选择提供一种服务类别,因此不会形成不同的子网。除了对多产品竞争理论做出贡献外,本文还解决了应用问题。例如,调查结果显示,目前在互联网上实施定价的建议在竞争下是不可行的。
{"title":"Multiproduct Competition between Congestible Networks","authors":"R. Gibbens, R. Mason, R. Steinberg","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.136739","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.136739","url":null,"abstract":"This paper analyses competition between firms who sell multiple products in the presence of negative externalities. The model involves two networks who each may offer several service classes. Service classes are generated by forming sub-networks differentiated by their congestion levels. The level of congestion on a sub-network is determined by its capacity and the number of users, i.e., quality of demand-dependent. This paper shows that networks will choose to offer only one service class, and thus not to form distinct sub-networks, in equilibrium. In addition to contributing to the theory of multiproduct competition, the paper addresses applied problems. For example, the results suggest that current proposals to implement pricing on the Internet will not be viable under competition.","PeriodicalId":151613,"journal":{"name":"Industrial Organization & Regulation eJournal","volume":"39 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"1998-11-27","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"129743032","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 12
Protecting the Digital Consumer: The Limits of Cyberspace Utopianism 保护数字消费者:网络空间乌托邦主义的极限
Pub Date : 1998-11-14 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.139452
J. Rothchild
Within the next few years, business-to-consumer electronic commerce will amount to tens of billions of dollars a year. Inevitably, a significant portion of that turnover will consist of transactions in which dishonest sellers attempt to defraud consumers by the use of deceptive marketing practices. An issue of growing importance is whether, and to what extent, the existing consumer protection regulatory regime may appropriately be applied to electronic commerce. This article rebuts the utopian thesis that government regulation of the Internet is neither necessary nor desirable, arguing, to the contrary, that governments retain their traditional regulatory role with respect to consumer transactions regardless of the means of communication used in carrying out such transactions. Certain novel characteristics of the online medium, however, make it impossible, or at least inadvisable, to apply the existing consumer protection regulatory regime to online transactions without making certain adjustments. Furthermore, co-regulation, consisting of coordinated efforts by governments and the private sector, should play a prominent role in controlling online deceptive marketing practices. The article concludes with a proposed set of guidelines for governments and the private sector to follow in their efforts to control online fraud.
在未来几年内,企业对消费者的电子商务每年将达到数百亿美元。不可避免地,这一营业额的很大一部分将由不诚实的销售者试图通过使用欺骗性的营销手段来欺骗消费者的交易组成。一个日益重要的问题是,现行的消费者保障规管制度是否可以适当地适用于电子商务,以及适用到何种程度。这篇文章反驳了乌托邦式的论点,即政府对互联网的监管既没有必要也不可取,相反,政府保留了对消费者交易的传统监管角色,而不管在进行此类交易时使用的通信手段如何。然而,网络媒介的某些新特征使得不进行某些调整就不可能或至少不可取地将现有的消费者保护监管制度应用于网络交易。此外,由政府和私营部门协调努力组成的共同监管,应该在控制网上欺骗性营销行为方面发挥突出作用。文章最后提出了一套指导方针,供政府和私营部门在控制网络欺诈方面遵循。
{"title":"Protecting the Digital Consumer: The Limits of Cyberspace Utopianism","authors":"J. Rothchild","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.139452","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.139452","url":null,"abstract":"Within the next few years, business-to-consumer electronic commerce will amount to tens of billions of dollars a year. Inevitably, a significant portion of that turnover will consist of transactions in which dishonest sellers attempt to defraud consumers by the use of deceptive marketing practices. An issue of growing importance is whether, and to what extent, the existing consumer protection regulatory regime may appropriately be applied to electronic commerce. This article rebuts the utopian thesis that government regulation of the Internet is neither necessary nor desirable, arguing, to the contrary, that governments retain their traditional regulatory role with respect to consumer transactions regardless of the means of communication used in carrying out such transactions. Certain novel characteristics of the online medium, however, make it impossible, or at least inadvisable, to apply the existing consumer protection regulatory regime to online transactions without making certain adjustments. Furthermore, co-regulation, consisting of coordinated efforts by governments and the private sector, should play a prominent role in controlling online deceptive marketing practices. The article concludes with a proposed set of guidelines for governments and the private sector to follow in their efforts to control online fraud.","PeriodicalId":151613,"journal":{"name":"Industrial Organization & Regulation eJournal","volume":"20 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"1998-11-14","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"132999835","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 28
Heroic Plants: Persistently Rapid Job Creators in the Longitudinal Research Database--Their Distinguishing Characteristics and Contribution to Employment Growth 英雄植物:纵向研究数据库中持续快速的就业创造者——它们的显著特征及其对就业增长的贡献
Pub Date : 1998-11-08 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.131438
N. Musick
Heroic Plant research shows that persistently-rapid job creation by a select group of plants can be an important source of overall employment growth in manufacturing. Establishments in SICs 34 - 38 whose residual growth (after controlling for differences in plant age, size, industry, etc.) ranks in the top quarter of establishment growth rates across both 1977-1982 and 1982-1987, account for roughly 25% of total job creation by plants operating throughout this time. While these exceptional job creators tend to participate especially in growing sectors of the economy (favoring, for example, commercial over industrial markets), they are active across a variety of product markets, production processes and price ranges. Thus, sustained job growth does not appear simply to be a sectoral phenomenon within particular industries. Neither does Heroic Plant job creation appear to be the result of random shocks to establishment growth. Rather, in spite of the difficulties in measuring performance characteristics using time-series data, Heroic Plants display numerous characteristics of successful plants. For example, when their exceptional growth begins to be tracked (1977), these establishments are more capital intensive and productive, and they pay higher wages, than do plants whose growth will be less rapid and/or persistent during the next decade. They also distinguish themselves by larger gross investment ratios (relative to their current employment, value added or capital stock). In 1987, Heroic Plants are more productive than other establishments, in spite of their labor-intensive operations. These plants share with other persistent (although less rapid) growers an above-average tendency to use advanced technologies in 1988. Heroic Plants also pay lower wages to production workers than do other establishments, raising questions about the division of returns, between management and workers, from superior business performance.
英雄式工厂的研究表明,一些选定的工厂持续快速地创造就业机会,可以成为制造业整体就业增长的重要来源。在1977-1982年和1982-1987年期间,中国34 - 38地区的企业的剩余增长率(在控制了工厂年龄、规模、行业等差异之后)均位于企业增长率的前四分之一,在这段时间内,这些企业创造的就业机会约占工厂总创造就业机会的25%。虽然这些杰出的就业创造者往往特别参与经济增长部门(例如,商业市场比工业市场更受青睐),但他们在各种产品市场、生产过程和价格范围内都很活跃。因此,持续的就业增长似乎并不仅仅是特定行业内的部门现象。英雄工厂创造的就业机会似乎也不是企业增长受到随机冲击的结果。相反,尽管使用时间序列数据测量性能特征存在困难,但英雄植物显示了成功植物的许多特征。例如,当他们的特殊增长开始被追踪时(1977年),这些企业的资本密集度更高,生产率更高,他们支付的工资高于那些在未来十年内增长速度和/或持久性较低的工厂。它们还以较高的总投资比率(相对于当前就业、增加值或资本存量)脱颖而出。1987年,英雄工厂的生产效率比其他工厂高,尽管他们的操作是劳动密集型的。1988年,这些植物与其他持续种植(尽管速度较慢)的种植者一样,使用先进技术的趋势高于平均水平。英雄工厂支付给生产工人的工资也低于其他企业,这引发了管理层和工人之间从卓越的经营业绩中分配回报的问题。
{"title":"Heroic Plants: Persistently Rapid Job Creators in the Longitudinal Research Database--Their Distinguishing Characteristics and Contribution to Employment Growth","authors":"N. Musick","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.131438","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.131438","url":null,"abstract":"Heroic Plant research shows that persistently-rapid job creation by a select group of plants can be an important source of overall employment growth in manufacturing. Establishments in SICs 34 - 38 whose residual growth (after controlling for differences in plant age, size, industry, etc.) ranks in the top quarter of establishment growth rates across both 1977-1982 and 1982-1987, account for roughly 25% of total job creation by plants operating throughout this time. While these exceptional job creators tend to participate especially in growing sectors of the economy (favoring, for example, commercial over industrial markets), they are active across a variety of product markets, production processes and price ranges. Thus, sustained job growth does not appear simply to be a sectoral phenomenon within particular industries. Neither does Heroic Plant job creation appear to be the result of random shocks to establishment growth. Rather, in spite of the difficulties in measuring performance characteristics using time-series data, Heroic Plants display numerous characteristics of successful plants. For example, when their exceptional growth begins to be tracked (1977), these establishments are more capital intensive and productive, and they pay higher wages, than do plants whose growth will be less rapid and/or persistent during the next decade. They also distinguish themselves by larger gross investment ratios (relative to their current employment, value added or capital stock). In 1987, Heroic Plants are more productive than other establishments, in spite of their labor-intensive operations. These plants share with other persistent (although less rapid) growers an above-average tendency to use advanced technologies in 1988. Heroic Plants also pay lower wages to production workers than do other establishments, raising questions about the division of returns, between management and workers, from superior business performance.","PeriodicalId":151613,"journal":{"name":"Industrial Organization & Regulation eJournal","volume":"127 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"1998-11-08","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"124611374","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Economic Reform of the Electricity Industries of Central and Eastern Europe 中欧和东欧电力工业的经济改革
Pub Date : 1998-11-01 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.142358
J. Stern, Junior R. Davis
The purpose of this paper is the following: firstly, to chart how much economic reform of CEE electricity industries has taken place to date; secondly, to discuss why progress has been so limited; and, thirdly, to consider the prospects over the next few years. In charting the economic progress to date, we will consider and discuss progress in electricity price unbundling and rebalancing; in utility commercialisation; in industry and market restructuring and liberalisation; and in privatisation, as well as the development of economic regulation. For the reasons outlined above, we will explore the pricing issues in some detail as they are essential for understanding the difficulties in making progress in the other aspects of economic reform. The analysis concentrates on the 10 countries with which the EU has an Association Agreement and who are stated candidates for EU membership (the EU 10).
本文的目的是:首先,绘制中东欧电力行业迄今为止进行了多少经济改革的图表;其次,讨论为什么进展如此有限;第三,考虑未来几年的前景。在描绘迄今为止的经济进展时,我们将考虑和讨论电价分拆和再平衡方面的进展;在公用事业商业化方面;在工业和市场重组和自由化方面;并在私有化,以及经济调控的发展。由于上述原因,我们将详细探讨价格问题,因为这是理解经济改革其他方面取得进展的困难所必需的。分析集中在与欧盟有联系国协议的10个国家,这些国家是欧盟成员国的候选国(欧盟10国)。
{"title":"Economic Reform of the Electricity Industries of Central and Eastern Europe","authors":"J. Stern, Junior R. Davis","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.142358","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.142358","url":null,"abstract":"The purpose of this paper is the following: firstly, to chart how much economic reform of CEE electricity industries has taken place to date; secondly, to discuss why progress has been so limited; and, thirdly, to consider the prospects over the next few years. In charting the economic progress to date, we will consider and discuss progress in electricity price unbundling and rebalancing; in utility commercialisation; in industry and market restructuring and liberalisation; and in privatisation, as well as the development of economic regulation. For the reasons outlined above, we will explore the pricing issues in some detail as they are essential for understanding the difficulties in making progress in the other aspects of economic reform. The analysis concentrates on the 10 countries with which the EU has an Association Agreement and who are stated candidates for EU membership (the EU 10).","PeriodicalId":151613,"journal":{"name":"Industrial Organization & Regulation eJournal","volume":"4 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"1998-11-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"124018896","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 26
Recent Canadian Evidence on Job Quality by Firm Size 最近加拿大公司规模对工作质量的影响
Pub Date : 1998-11-01 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.139788
René Morissette
We provide recent evidence on job characteristics by firm size in Canada. Using a variety of household surveys, we assemble a wide set of facts on wages, fringe benefits and work schedules in small and large firms. We show that the wage gap between small and large firms has reamined fairly stable over the past decade. After controlling for observable worker characteristics and industry-specific effects, large firms pay 15-20% more than small firms. Pension plan coverage remains at least four times higher in large firms than in small firms. While the gap in pension coverage between small and large firms has not increased over time for men, there is some evidence that it has increased for women. We assess the extent to which work schedules vary between small and large firms. Our results indicate that compared to workers in large firms, employees of small firms work at least as many weekly hours. Furthermore, they are more likely to work more than five days per week. This implies that the firm size wage premium cannot be explained by a longer workweek in large firms. As long as workers prefer working during the day, the greater frequency of shift work in large, goods-producing companies is one dimension along which work schedules are less desirable in large firms. According to the theory of compensating differentials, the size-wage differential may partially reflect the willingness of large firms to compensate workers for shift work. We test this hypothesis and conclude that shift work has virtually no effect on the firm size wage premium. Our results emphasize the need to look at several dimensions of work to assess how job quality varies between small and large firms.
我们提供了加拿大公司规模的工作特征的最新证据。通过各种家庭调查,我们收集了关于小公司和大公司的工资、附加福利和工作时间表的大量事实。我们表明,在过去十年中,小型企业和大型企业之间的工资差距保持相当稳定。在控制了可观察到的工人特征和行业特定效应之后,大公司比小公司多支付15-20%的工资。大公司的养老金计划覆盖率至少是小公司的四倍。虽然小型和大型公司之间的养老金覆盖面差距并没有随着时间的推移而扩大,但有一些证据表明,女性的差距已经扩大。我们评估了小公司和大公司之间工作时间表的差异程度。我们的研究结果表明,与大公司的员工相比,小公司的员工每周至少工作同样多的时间。此外,他们更有可能每周工作超过五天。这意味着公司规模的工资溢价不能用大公司较长的工作周来解释。只要工人喜欢在白天工作,大型产品生产公司的轮班工作频率更高,这是大公司不太喜欢工作时间表的一个方面。根据补偿差异理论,规模工资差异可能部分反映了大公司对轮班工作的补偿意愿。我们检验了这一假设,并得出结论,轮班工作实际上对企业规模的工资溢价没有影响。我们的研究结果强调需要从工作的几个方面来评估工作质量在小公司和大公司之间的差异。
{"title":"Recent Canadian Evidence on Job Quality by Firm Size","authors":"René Morissette","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.139788","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.139788","url":null,"abstract":"We provide recent evidence on job characteristics by firm size in Canada. Using a variety of household surveys, we assemble a wide set of facts on wages, fringe benefits and work schedules in small and large firms. We show that the wage gap between small and large firms has reamined fairly stable over the past decade. After controlling for observable worker characteristics and industry-specific effects, large firms pay 15-20% more than small firms. Pension plan coverage remains at least four times higher in large firms than in small firms. While the gap in pension coverage between small and large firms has not increased over time for men, there is some evidence that it has increased for women. We assess the extent to which work schedules vary between small and large firms. Our results indicate that compared to workers in large firms, employees of small firms work at least as many weekly hours. Furthermore, they are more likely to work more than five days per week. This implies that the firm size wage premium cannot be explained by a longer workweek in large firms. As long as workers prefer working during the day, the greater frequency of shift work in large, goods-producing companies is one dimension along which work schedules are less desirable in large firms. According to the theory of compensating differentials, the size-wage differential may partially reflect the willingness of large firms to compensate workers for shift work. We test this hypothesis and conclude that shift work has virtually no effect on the firm size wage premium. Our results emphasize the need to look at several dimensions of work to assess how job quality varies between small and large firms.","PeriodicalId":151613,"journal":{"name":"Industrial Organization & Regulation eJournal","volume":"93 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"1998-11-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"117301141","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 11
Collusion and Price Rigidity 共谋与价格刚性
Pub Date : 1998-11-01 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.140490
S. Athey, K. Bagwell, C. Sanchirico
We consider an infinitely repeated Bertrand game, in which prices are publicly observed and each firm receives a privately observed, i.i.d. cost shock in each period. We focus on symmetric perfect public equilibria, wherein any "punishments" are borne equally by all firms. We identify a tradeoff that is associated with collusive pricing schemes in which the price to be charged by each firm is strictly increasing in its cost level: such "fully sorting" schemes offer efficiency benefits, as they ensure that the lowest-cost firm makes the current sale, but they also imply an informational cost (distorted pricing and/or equilibrium-path price wars), since a higher-cost firm must be deterred from mimicking a lower-cost firm by charging a lower price. A rigid-pricing scheme, where a firm's collusive price is independent of its current cost position, sacrifices efficiency benefits but also diminishes the informational cost. For a wide range of settings, the optimal symmetric collusive scheme requires (i) the absence of equilibrium-path price wars and (ii) a rigid price. If firms are sufficiently impatient, however, the rigid-pricing scheme cannot be enforced, and the collusive price of lower-cost firms may be distorted downward in order to diminish the incentive to cheat. When the model is modified to include i.i.d. public demand shocks, the downward pricing distortion that accompanies a firm's lower-cost realization may occur only when current demand is high. Copyright 2004, Wiley-Blackwell.
我们考虑一个无限重复的伯特兰博弈,其中价格是公开观察到的,每个公司在每个时期都受到一个私下观察到的成本冲击。我们关注对称的完美公共均衡,其中任何“惩罚”都由所有公司平均承担。我们确定了一种与合谋定价方案相关的权衡,其中每个公司收取的价格在其成本水平上都是严格增加的:这种“完全分类”方案提供了效率效益,因为它们确保成本最低的公司进行当前销售,但它们也意味着信息成本(扭曲定价和/或均衡路径价格战),因为高成本公司必须通过收取更低的价格来阻止模仿低成本公司。在刚性定价方案中,企业的合谋价格独立于其当前的成本状况,既牺牲了效率效益,也降低了信息成本。对于广泛的设置,最优对称共谋方案要求(i)没有均衡路径价格战和(ii)刚性价格。然而,如果企业足够缺乏耐心,刚性定价方案就无法执行,低成本企业的合谋价格可能会被扭曲,以减少欺骗的动机。当模型被修正为包含i.i.d公共需求冲击时,伴随着企业低成本实现的向下定价扭曲可能只在当前需求高时才会发生。版权所有,Wiley-Blackwell。
{"title":"Collusion and Price Rigidity","authors":"S. Athey, K. Bagwell, C. Sanchirico","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.140490","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.140490","url":null,"abstract":"We consider an infinitely repeated Bertrand game, in which prices are publicly observed and each firm receives a privately observed, i.i.d. cost shock in each period. We focus on symmetric perfect public equilibria, wherein any \"punishments\" are borne equally by all firms. We identify a tradeoff that is associated with collusive pricing schemes in which the price to be charged by each firm is strictly increasing in its cost level: such \"fully sorting\" schemes offer efficiency benefits, as they ensure that the lowest-cost firm makes the current sale, but they also imply an informational cost (distorted pricing and/or equilibrium-path price wars), since a higher-cost firm must be deterred from mimicking a lower-cost firm by charging a lower price. A rigid-pricing scheme, where a firm's collusive price is independent of its current cost position, sacrifices efficiency benefits but also diminishes the informational cost. For a wide range of settings, the optimal symmetric collusive scheme requires (i) the absence of equilibrium-path price wars and (ii) a rigid price. If firms are sufficiently impatient, however, the rigid-pricing scheme cannot be enforced, and the collusive price of lower-cost firms may be distorted downward in order to diminish the incentive to cheat. When the model is modified to include i.i.d. public demand shocks, the downward pricing distortion that accompanies a firm's lower-cost realization may occur only when current demand is high. Copyright 2004, Wiley-Blackwell.","PeriodicalId":151613,"journal":{"name":"Industrial Organization & Regulation eJournal","volume":"56 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"1998-11-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"122120641","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 387
Experimentation and Signal Dampening in Agency--The Ratchet Effect Revisited 代理中的实验和信号衰减——重新审视棘轮效应
Pub Date : 1998-11-01 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.149310
Thomas D. Jeitschko, Leonard J. Mirman, Egas M. Salgueiro
The dynamics of incentive contracts under asymmetric information have long been an important topic in economics. We address this topic in this paper by considering a stochastic, two-period principal-agent relationship, in which the true state of the world can take on two possible values and is the same in each period. We study contracts that are short term, so that after the first period the principal designs a second contract, taking the information available about the state of the world at that stage into account--that is, the standard framework in which the "ratchet effect" occurs. Two significant changes emerge when compared to deterministic environments: First, if production is sufficiently noisy, a fully separating first period contract is optimal. The second change is that, unlike the deterministic setting where the high type's target is fixed over time, in a stochastic environment, the high type's target is ratcheted upward in the course of the interaction. This is the result of two opposing incentives of the principal: First, the principal experiments in order to increase the flow of information; and second, the principal attempts to dampen the first period signal to reduce up-front payments.
信息不对称条件下的激励契约动力学问题一直是经济学中的一个重要课题。本文通过考虑一个随机的、两周期的委托代理关系来解决这个问题,其中世界的真实状态可以取两个可能的值,并且在每个周期中都是相同的。我们研究短期契约,以便在第一阶段之后,考虑到该阶段世界状态的可用信息——即“棘轮效应”发生的标准框架,委托人设计第二个契约。与确定性环境相比,出现了两个重大变化:首先,如果生产足够嘈杂,则完全分离的第一阶段合同是最优的。第二个变化是,与确定性设置不同,高类型的目标随着时间的推移是固定的,在随机环境中,高类型的目标在相互作用的过程中是向上的。这是校长两种相反动机的结果:第一,校长为了增加信息流而进行实验;第二,校长试图抑制第一阶段的信号,以减少预付款项。
{"title":"Experimentation and Signal Dampening in Agency--The Ratchet Effect Revisited","authors":"Thomas D. Jeitschko, Leonard J. Mirman, Egas M. Salgueiro","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.149310","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.149310","url":null,"abstract":"The dynamics of incentive contracts under asymmetric information have long been an important topic in economics. We address this topic in this paper by considering a stochastic, two-period principal-agent relationship, in which the true state of the world can take on two possible values and is the same in each period. We study contracts that are short term, so that after the first period the principal designs a second contract, taking the information available about the state of the world at that stage into account--that is, the standard framework in which the \"ratchet effect\" occurs. Two significant changes emerge when compared to deterministic environments: First, if production is sufficiently noisy, a fully separating first period contract is optimal. The second change is that, unlike the deterministic setting where the high type's target is fixed over time, in a stochastic environment, the high type's target is ratcheted upward in the course of the interaction. This is the result of two opposing incentives of the principal: First, the principal experiments in order to increase the flow of information; and second, the principal attempts to dampen the first period signal to reduce up-front payments.","PeriodicalId":151613,"journal":{"name":"Industrial Organization & Regulation eJournal","volume":"28 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"1998-11-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"121089683","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 3
Two-Part Access Pricing and Imperfect Competition 两部分接入定价与不完全竞争
Pub Date : 1998-11-01 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.122131
T. Valletti
This paper considers a vertically separated industry with an upstream monopolist who supplies an essential input to two downstream Cournot firms. This situation is relevant to a number of sectors, including the telecommunications industry where trunk operators must have access to the local network of an incumbent firm to provide their long-distance service. The paper analyzes two-part access pricing and input price discrimination under different regulatory settings, and it finds that discrimination may produce adverse welfare effects when it is practiced by the unregulated upstream firm.
本文考虑一个垂直分离的行业,其上游垄断者为两个下游古诺公司提供必要的投入。这种情况与若干部门有关,包括电信行业,其中干线运营商必须能够进入现有公司的当地网络以提供长途服务。本文分析了不同监管设置下的两部分准入定价和投入价格歧视,发现当不受监管的上游企业实施歧视时,歧视可能产生不利的福利效应。
{"title":"Two-Part Access Pricing and Imperfect Competition","authors":"T. Valletti","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.122131","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.122131","url":null,"abstract":"This paper considers a vertically separated industry with an upstream monopolist who supplies an essential input to two downstream Cournot firms. This situation is relevant to a number of sectors, including the telecommunications industry where trunk operators must have access to the local network of an incumbent firm to provide their long-distance service. The paper analyzes two-part access pricing and input price discrimination under different regulatory settings, and it finds that discrimination may produce adverse welfare effects when it is practiced by the unregulated upstream firm.","PeriodicalId":151613,"journal":{"name":"Industrial Organization & Regulation eJournal","volume":"1 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"1998-11-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"125863541","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 13
Market Experimentation in a Dynamic Differentiated-Goods Duopoly 动态差异化商品双寡头垄断的市场实验
Pub Date : 1998-10-01 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.137440
Godfrey Keller, Sven Rady
We study the evolution of prices in a symmetric duopoly where firms are uncertain about the degree of product differentiation. Customers sometimes perceive the products as close substitutes, sometimes as highly differentiated. Firms learn about their competitive environment from the quantities sold and a background signal. As the information of the market outcomes increases with the price differential, there is scope for active learning. In a setting with linear demand curves, we derive firms' pricing strategies as payoff-symmetric mixed or correlated Markov perfect equilibria of a stochastic differential game where the common posterior belief is the natural state variable. When information has low value, firms charge the same price as would be set by myopic players, and there is no price dispersion. When firms value information more highly, on the other hand, they actively learn by creating price dispersion. This market experimentation is transient, and most likely to be observed when the firms' environment changes sufficiently often, but not too frequently.
我们研究了对称双寡头市场中企业产品差异化程度不确定的价格演变。顾客有时认为产品是相近的替代品,有时则认为产品是高度差异化的。公司从销售数量和背景信号中了解竞争环境。由于市场结果的信息随着价差的增加而增加,因此存在主动学习的余地。在具有线性需求曲线的情况下,我们将企业的定价策略导出为一个随机微分博弈的收益对称混合或相关马尔可夫完美均衡,其中共同后置信念是自然状态变量。当信息价值较低时,企业收取的价格与短视参与者设定的价格相同,不存在价格分散。另一方面,当企业更重视信息时,它们会通过制造价格差异来主动学习。这种市场实验是短暂的,当公司的环境变化足够频繁时,这种实验最有可能被观察到,但不是太频繁。
{"title":"Market Experimentation in a Dynamic Differentiated-Goods Duopoly","authors":"Godfrey Keller, Sven Rady","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.137440","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.137440","url":null,"abstract":"We study the evolution of prices in a symmetric duopoly where firms are uncertain about the degree of product differentiation. Customers sometimes perceive the products as close substitutes, sometimes as highly differentiated. Firms learn about their competitive environment from the quantities sold and a background signal. As the information of the market outcomes increases with the price differential, there is scope for active learning. In a setting with linear demand curves, we derive firms' pricing strategies as payoff-symmetric mixed or correlated Markov perfect equilibria of a stochastic differential game where the common posterior belief is the natural state variable. When information has low value, firms charge the same price as would be set by myopic players, and there is no price dispersion. When firms value information more highly, on the other hand, they actively learn by creating price dispersion. This market experimentation is transient, and most likely to be observed when the firms' environment changes sufficiently often, but not too frequently.","PeriodicalId":151613,"journal":{"name":"Industrial Organization & Regulation eJournal","volume":"24 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"1998-10-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"115646073","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 8
期刊
Industrial Organization & Regulation eJournal
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1