首页 > 最新文献

Journal of Econometrics最新文献

英文 中文
Some children left behind: Variation in the effects of an educational intervention 一些留守儿童:教育干预效果的差异
IF 9.9 3区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-07-01 DOI: 10.1016/j.jeconom.2021.12.010
Julie Buhl-Wiggers , Jason T. Kerwin , Juan Muñoz-Morales , Jeffrey Smith , Rebecca Thornton

We document substantial variation in the effects of a highly-effective literacy program in northern Uganda. The program increases test scores by 1.4 SDs on average, but standard statistical bounds show that the impact standard deviation exceeds 1.0 SD. This implies that the variation in effects across our students is wider than the spread of mean effects across all randomized evaluations of developing country education interventions in the literature. This very effective program does indeed leave some students behind. At the same time, we do not learn much from our analyses that attempt to determine which students benefit more or less from the program. We reject rank preservation, and the weaker assumption of stochastic increasingness leaves wide bounds on quantile-specific average treatment effects. Neither conventional nor machine-learning approaches to estimating systematic heterogeneity capture more than a small fraction of the variation in impacts given our available candidate moderators.

我们记录了乌干达北部一项高效扫盲计划效果的巨大差异。该计划使考试成绩平均提高了 1.4 个标准差,但标准统计界限显示,影响标准差超过了 1.0 个标准差。这意味着,我们的学生之间的效果差异比文献中所有发展中国家教育干预随机评估的平均效果差异都要大。这个非常有效的项目确实让一些学生落在后面。与此同时,我们并没有从试图确定哪些学生从该项目中获益更多或更少的分析中获益良多。我们否定了等级保留,而较弱的随机递增假设也为特定量级的平均治疗效果留下了较大的界限。考虑到我们现有的候选调节因子,无论是传统方法还是机器学习方法,在估计系统异质性时都只能捕捉到影响变化的一小部分。
{"title":"Some children left behind: Variation in the effects of an educational intervention","authors":"Julie Buhl-Wiggers ,&nbsp;Jason T. Kerwin ,&nbsp;Juan Muñoz-Morales ,&nbsp;Jeffrey Smith ,&nbsp;Rebecca Thornton","doi":"10.1016/j.jeconom.2021.12.010","DOIUrl":"10.1016/j.jeconom.2021.12.010","url":null,"abstract":"<div><p>We document substantial variation in the effects of a highly-effective literacy program<span><span> in northern Uganda<span>. The program increases test scores by 1.4 SDs on average, but standard statistical bounds show that the impact standard deviation exceeds 1.0 SD. This implies that the variation in effects across our students is wider than the spread of mean effects across all randomized evaluations of developing country education interventions in the literature. This very effective program does indeed leave some students behind. At the same time, we do not learn much from our analyses that attempt to determine which students benefit more or less from the program. We reject rank preservation, and the weaker assumption of stochastic increasingness leaves wide bounds on quantile-specific average </span></span>treatment effects. Neither conventional nor machine-learning approaches to estimating systematic heterogeneity capture more than a small fraction of the variation in impacts given our available candidate moderators.</span></p></div>","PeriodicalId":15629,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Econometrics","volume":"243 1","pages":"Article 105256"},"PeriodicalIF":9.9,"publicationDate":"2024-07-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"141978515","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Reprint of: Profiling the plight of disconnected youth in America 重印本:剖析美国失联青年的困境
IF 9.9 3区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-07-01 DOI: 10.1016/j.jeconom.2024.105820
Thomas MaCurdy , David Glick , Sonam Sherpa , Sriniketh Nagavarapu

In a successful transition from youth to adulthood, individuals pass through a sequence of roles involving school, work, and family formation that culminate in their becoming self-sufficient adults. However, some “disconnected” youth spend extended periods of time outside of any role that constitutes an element of the pathway towards adult independence. Assisting these youth requires a systematic understanding of what “disconnection” means, how many disconnected youth there are, who these youth are, and how the scale of the problem has evolved over time. Using the National Longitudinal Surveys of Youth for 1997 and 1979, we address these issues by creating concrete definitions of “disconnection spells” using rich data on youths’ enrollment, work, and personal histories. We estimate a multi-state duration model to account for right censoring and to understand differences across salient sub-groups. Our estimates imply that in the early 2000s, almost 19% and 25% of young men and young women, respectively, experienced a disconnection spell by age 23 using our basic definition. These rates are substantially higher for certain sub-groups defined by race/ethnicity, parental education, and government aid receipt, rising as high as 30+% by age 23. Approximately 60% of youth with a disconnection spell have it last longer than a year, and close to 10% have it last longer than 4 years. However, once reconnected, a majority of youth go at least three years without a re-disconnection spell. Patterns of initial disconnection changed markedly from the 1980s to the 2000s, as young women saw a 12 percentage point decline over time. Moreover, the Black-White gap in disconnection has fallen for women, but increased for men. Our profile of disconnection experiences provides a starting point for government agencies aiming to understand where, how, and with whom to intervene to prevent lengthy disconnection spells.

在从青年成功过渡到成年的过程中,每个人都会经历一连串的角色,包括上学、工作和组建家庭,最终成为自给自足的成年人。然而,有些 "失联 "青年在很长一段时间内都没有扮演任何角色,而这些角色正是通往成人独立之路的一个要素。要帮助这些青少年,就需要系统地了解 "失联 "的含义、失联青少年的数量、这些青少年的身份以及随着时间的推移问题的规模是如何演变的。利用 1997 年和 1979 年的全国青少年纵向调查,我们通过使用有关青少年入学、工作和个人历史的丰富数据来创建 "失联时间 "的具体定义,从而解决这些问题。我们估算了一个多州持续时间模型,以考虑正确的普查,并了解各显著子群体之间的差异。我们的估算结果表明,在 2000 年代初,根据我们的基本定义,分别有近 19% 和 25% 的青年男性和青年女性在 23 岁之前经历过失联。对于按种族/民族、父母教育程度和接受政府援助情况界定的某些亚群体来说,这一比例要高得多,到 23 岁时,这一比例高达 30%以上。约有 60% 的失联青少年的失联时间超过一年,近 10% 的失联时间超过四年。然而,一旦重新联系上,大多数青少年至少在三年内不会再次中断联系。从 20 世纪 80 年代到 2000 年代,初次失联的模式发生了显著变化,年轻女性的失联率下降了 12 个百分点。此外,女性与黑人和白人在断绝联系方面的差距有所缩小,但男性的差距却有所扩大。我们对断开连接经历的描述为政府机构提供了一个起点,这些机构旨在了解在哪里、如何以及与谁进行干预,以防止出现长时间的断开连接。
{"title":"Reprint of: Profiling the plight of disconnected youth in America","authors":"Thomas MaCurdy ,&nbsp;David Glick ,&nbsp;Sonam Sherpa ,&nbsp;Sriniketh Nagavarapu","doi":"10.1016/j.jeconom.2024.105820","DOIUrl":"10.1016/j.jeconom.2024.105820","url":null,"abstract":"<div><p>In a successful transition from youth to adulthood, individuals pass through a sequence of roles involving school, work, and family formation that culminate in their becoming self-sufficient adults. However, some “disconnected” youth spend extended periods of time outside of any role that constitutes an element of the pathway towards adult independence. Assisting these youth requires a systematic understanding of what “disconnection” means, how many disconnected youth there are, who these youth are, and how the scale of the problem has evolved over time. Using the National Longitudinal Surveys of Youth for 1997 and 1979, we address these issues by creating concrete definitions of “disconnection spells” using rich data on youths’ enrollment, work, and personal histories. We estimate a multi-state duration model to account for right censoring and to understand differences across salient sub-groups. Our estimates imply that in the early 2000s, almost 19% and 25% of young men and young women, respectively, experienced a disconnection spell by age 23 using our basic definition. These rates are substantially higher for certain sub-groups defined by race/ethnicity, parental education, and government aid receipt, rising as high as 30+% by age 23. Approximately 60% of youth with a disconnection spell have it last longer than a year, and close to 10% have it last longer than 4 years. However, once reconnected, a majority of youth go at least three years without a re-disconnection spell. Patterns of initial disconnection changed markedly from the 1980s to the 2000s, as young women saw a 12 percentage point decline over time. Moreover, the Black-White gap in disconnection has fallen for women, but increased for men. Our profile of disconnection experiences provides a starting point for government agencies aiming to understand where, how, and with whom to intervene to prevent lengthy disconnection spells.</p></div>","PeriodicalId":15629,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Econometrics","volume":"243 1","pages":"Article 105820"},"PeriodicalIF":9.9,"publicationDate":"2024-07-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"141978517","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
You are what your parents expect: Height and local reference points 你就是你父母所期望的:身高和当地参考点
IF 9.9 3区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-07-01 DOI: 10.1016/j.jeconom.2021.09.020
Fan Wang , Esteban Puentes , Jere R. Behrman , Flávio Cunha

Recent estimates are that about 150 million children under five years of age are stunted, with substantial negative consequences for their schooling, cognitive skills, health, and economic productivity. Therefore, understanding what determines such growth retardation is significant for designing public policies that aim to address this issue. We build a model for nutritional choices and health with reference-dependent preferences. Parents care about the health of their children relative to some reference population. In our empirical model, we use height as the health outcome that parents target. Reference height is an equilibrium object determined by earlier cohorts’ parents’ nutritional choices in the same village. We explore the exogenous variation in reference height produced by a protein-supplementation experiment in Guatemala to estimate our model’s parameters. We use our model to decompose the impact of the protein intervention on height into price and reference-point effects. We find that the changes in reference points account for 65% of the height difference between two-year-old children in experimental and control villages in the sixth annual cohort born after the initiation of the intervention.

据最新估计,约有 1.5 亿五岁以下儿童发育迟缓,这对他们的学业、认知技能、健康和经济生产力造成了严重的负面影响。因此,了解这种生长迟缓的决定因素对于制定旨在解决这一问题的公共政策意义重大。我们建立了一个营养选择和健康模型,该模型具有依赖参考的偏好。父母关心的是子女相对于某个参照人群的健康状况。在我们的实证模型中,我们将身高作为父母的健康目标。参考身高是由同村前几代父母的营养选择决定的均衡对象。我们利用危地马拉蛋白质补充实验所产生的参考身高的外生变化来估计模型参数。我们利用模型将蛋白质干预对身高的影响分解为价格效应和参考点效应。我们发现,在干预措施启动后出生的第六年组群中,实验村和对照村两岁儿童身高差异的 65% 是由参考点的变化造成的。
{"title":"You are what your parents expect: Height and local reference points","authors":"Fan Wang ,&nbsp;Esteban Puentes ,&nbsp;Jere R. Behrman ,&nbsp;Flávio Cunha","doi":"10.1016/j.jeconom.2021.09.020","DOIUrl":"10.1016/j.jeconom.2021.09.020","url":null,"abstract":"<div><p>Recent estimates are that about 150 million children under five years of age are stunted, with substantial negative consequences for their schooling, cognitive skills, health, and economic productivity. Therefore, understanding what determines such growth retardation is significant for designing public policies that aim to address this issue. We build a model for nutritional choices and health with reference-dependent preferences. Parents care about the health of their children relative to some reference population. In our empirical model, we use height as the health outcome that parents target. Reference height is an equilibrium object determined by earlier cohorts’ parents’ nutritional choices in the same village. We explore the exogenous variation in reference height produced by a protein-supplementation experiment in Guatemala to estimate our model’s parameters. We use our model to decompose the impact of the protein intervention on height into price and reference-point effects. We find that the changes in reference points account for 65% of the height difference between two-year-old children in experimental and control villages in the sixth annual cohort born after the initiation of the intervention.</p></div>","PeriodicalId":15629,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Econometrics","volume":"243 1","pages":"Article 105269"},"PeriodicalIF":9.9,"publicationDate":"2024-07-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"141978514","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Eliciting willingness-to-pay to decompose beliefs and preferences that determine selection into competition in lab experiments 在实验室实验中激发支付意愿,以分解决定竞争选择的信念和偏好
IF 9.9 3区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-07-01 DOI: 10.1016/j.jeconom.2023.105652

This paper develops a partial-identification methodology for analyzing self-selection into alternative compensation schemes in a laboratory environment. We formulate a model of self-selection in which individuals select the compensation scheme with the largest expected valuation, which depends on individual- and scheme-specific beliefs and non-monetary preferences. We characterize the resulting sharp identified sets for individual-specific willingness-to-pay, subjective beliefs, and preferences, and develop conditions on the experimental design under which these identified sets are informative. We apply our methods to examine gender differences in preference for winner-take-all compensation schemes. We find that what has commonly been attributed to a gender difference in preference for performing in a competition is instead explained by men being more confident than women in their probability of winning a future (though not necessarily a past) competition.

本文开发了一种部分识别方法,用于分析在实验室环境中对备选补偿方案的自我选择。我们建立了一个自我选择模型,在该模型中,个人选择预期估值最大的补偿方案,而预期估值取决于个人和方案的特定信念和非货币偏好。我们描述了由此产生的针对特定个体的支付意愿、主观信念和偏好的尖锐识别集,并制定了实验设计条件,在这些条件下,这些识别集具有参考价值。我们运用我们的方法研究了性别对赢家通吃补偿方案的偏好差异。我们发现,通常被归因于在竞争中表现偏好的性别差异的原因是,男性比女性对自己在未来(但不一定是过去)竞争中获胜的概率更有信心。
{"title":"Eliciting willingness-to-pay to decompose beliefs and preferences that determine selection into competition in lab experiments","authors":"","doi":"10.1016/j.jeconom.2023.105652","DOIUrl":"10.1016/j.jeconom.2023.105652","url":null,"abstract":"<div><p>This paper develops a partial-identification methodology for analyzing self-selection into alternative compensation schemes in a laboratory environment. We formulate a model of self-selection in which individuals select the compensation scheme with the largest expected valuation, which depends on individual- and scheme-specific beliefs and non-monetary preferences. We characterize the resulting sharp identified sets for individual-specific willingness-to-pay, subjective beliefs, and preferences, and develop conditions on the experimental design under which these identified sets are informative. We apply our methods to examine gender differences in preference for winner-take-all compensation schemes. We find that what has commonly been attributed to a gender difference in preference for performing in a competition is instead explained by men being more confident than women in their probability of winning a future (though not necessarily a past) competition.</p></div>","PeriodicalId":15629,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Econometrics","volume":"243 1","pages":"Article 105652"},"PeriodicalIF":9.9,"publicationDate":"2024-07-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"139677574","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Robust inference for moment condition models without rational expectations 无理性预期的时刻条件模型的稳健推断
IF 9.9 3区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-07-01 DOI: 10.1016/j.jeconom.2023.105653

Applied researchers using structural models under rational expectations (RE) often confront empirical evidence of misspecification. In this paper we consider a generic dynamic model that is posed as a vector of unconditional moment restrictions. We suppose that the model is globally misspecified under RE, and thus empirically flawed in a way that is not econometrically subtle. We relax the RE restriction by allowing subjective beliefs to differ from the data-generating probability (DGP) model while still maintaining that the moment conditions are satisfied under the subjective beliefs of economic agents. We use statistical measures of divergence relative to RE to bound the set of subjective probabilities. This form of misspecification alters econometric identification and inferences in a substantial way, leading us to construct robust confidence sets for various set identified functionals.

使用理性预期(RE)结构模型的应用研究人员经常会遇到规范错误的经验证据。在本文中,我们考虑了一个通用动态模型,该模型是由一个无条件矩限制向量构成的。我们假定该模型在 RE 条件下存在全局性的规范错误,因此在经验上存在缺陷,而这种缺陷在计量经济学上并不明显。我们放宽 RE 限制,允许主观信念与数据生成概率(DGP)模型不同,同时仍保持矩条件在经济行为主体的主观信念下得到满足。我们使用相对于 RE 的发散统计量来约束主观概率集。这种形式的误规范在很大程度上改变了计量经济学的识别和推断,从而使我们为各种集合识别函数构建了稳健的置信集。
{"title":"Robust inference for moment condition models without rational expectations","authors":"","doi":"10.1016/j.jeconom.2023.105653","DOIUrl":"10.1016/j.jeconom.2023.105653","url":null,"abstract":"<div><p>Applied researchers using structural models under rational expectations (RE) often confront empirical evidence of misspecification. In this paper we consider a generic dynamic model that is posed as a vector of unconditional moment restrictions. We suppose that the model is globally misspecified under RE, and thus empirically flawed in a way that is not econometrically subtle. We relax the RE restriction by allowing subjective beliefs to differ from the data-generating probability (DGP) model while still maintaining that the moment conditions are satisfied under the subjective beliefs of economic agents. We use statistical measures of divergence relative to RE to bound the set of subjective probabilities. This form of misspecification alters econometric identification and inferences in a substantial way, leading us to construct robust confidence sets for various set identified functionals.</p></div>","PeriodicalId":15629,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Econometrics","volume":"243 1","pages":"Article 105653"},"PeriodicalIF":9.9,"publicationDate":"2024-07-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S030440762300369X/pdfft?md5=b8b310f0a20d522dbd2241e9e32687c6&pid=1-s2.0-S030440762300369X-main.pdf","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"139589951","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"OA","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Introduction to the annals issue in honor of James J Heckman 纪念詹姆斯-J-赫克曼年刊导言
IF 9.9 3区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-07-01 DOI: 10.1016/j.jeconom.2024.105818
Xiaohong Chen, Edward Vytlacil
{"title":"Introduction to the annals issue in honor of James J Heckman","authors":"Xiaohong Chen,&nbsp;Edward Vytlacil","doi":"10.1016/j.jeconom.2024.105818","DOIUrl":"10.1016/j.jeconom.2024.105818","url":null,"abstract":"","PeriodicalId":15629,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Econometrics","volume":"243 1","pages":"Article 105818"},"PeriodicalIF":9.9,"publicationDate":"2024-07-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"141847456","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Econometric causality: The central role of thought experiments 计量经济学的因果关系:思想实验的核心作用
IF 9.9 3区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-07-01 DOI: 10.1016/j.jeconom.2024.105719
James Heckman , Rodrigo Pinto

This paper examines the econometric causal model and the interpretation of empirical evidence based on thought experiments that was developed by Ragnar Frisch and Trygve Haavelmo. We compare the econometric causal model with two currently popular causal frameworks: the Neyman–Rubin causal model and the Do-Calculus. The Neyman–Rubin causal model is based on the language of potential outcomes and was largely developed by statisticians. Instead of being based on thought experiments, it takes statistical experiments as its foundation. The Do-Calculus, developed by Judea Pearl and co-authors, relies on Directed Acyclic Graphs (DAGs) and is a popular causal framework in computer science and applied mathematics. We make the case that economists who uncritically use these frameworks often discard the substantial benefits of the econometric causal model to the detriment of more informative analyses. We illustrate the versatility and capabilities of the econometric framework using causal models developed in economics.

本文研究了拉格纳-弗里施(Ragnar Frisch)和特里格夫-哈维尔莫(Trygve Haavelmo)基于思想实验开发的计量经济学因果模型和对经验证据的解释。我们将计量经济学因果模型与目前流行的两个因果框架进行了比较:奈曼-鲁宾因果模型和 Do-Calculus 因果模型。奈曼-鲁宾因果模型基于潜在结果语言,主要由统计学家开发。它不是以思想实验为基础,而是以统计实验为基础。由 Judea Pearl 和合著者开发的 Do-Calculus 依赖于有向无环图 (DAG),是计算机科学和应用数学领域流行的因果框架。我们提出的理由是,不加批判地使用这些框架的经济学家往往会丢弃计量经济学因果模型的巨大优势,从而不利于进行更有价值的分析。我们使用经济学中开发的因果模型来说明计量经济学框架的多功能性和能力。
{"title":"Econometric causality: The central role of thought experiments","authors":"James Heckman ,&nbsp;Rodrigo Pinto","doi":"10.1016/j.jeconom.2024.105719","DOIUrl":"10.1016/j.jeconom.2024.105719","url":null,"abstract":"<div><p><span>This paper examines the econometric causal model and the interpretation of empirical evidence based on </span>thought experiments<span> that was developed by Ragnar Frisch and Trygve Haavelmo. We compare the econometric causal model with two currently popular causal frameworks: the Neyman–Rubin causal model and the Do-Calculus. The Neyman–Rubin causal model is based on the language of potential outcomes and was largely developed by statisticians. Instead of being based on thought experiments, it takes statistical experiments as its foundation. The Do-Calculus, developed by Judea Pearl and co-authors, relies on Directed Acyclic Graphs (DAGs) and is a popular causal framework in computer science and applied mathematics. We make the case that economists who uncritically use these frameworks often discard the substantial benefits of the econometric causal model to the detriment of more informative analyses. We illustrate the versatility and capabilities of the econometric framework using causal models developed in economics.</span></p></div>","PeriodicalId":15629,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Econometrics","volume":"243 1","pages":"Article 105719"},"PeriodicalIF":9.9,"publicationDate":"2024-07-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"141978518","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Earnings dynamics and intergenerational transmission of skill 收入动态和技能的代际传承
IF 9.9 3区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-07-01 DOI: 10.1016/j.jeconom.2021.12.009
Lance Lochner , Youngmin Park

This paper develops and estimates a two-factor model of intergenerational skill transmission when earnings inequality reflects differences in individual skills and other non-skill shocks. We consider heterogeneity in both initial skills and skill growth rates, allowing variation in skill growth to change over the lifecycle. Using administrative tax data on two linked generations of Canadians covering 37 years, we exploit covariances in log earnings (at different ages) both across and within generations to identify and estimate the intergenerational correlation structure for initial skills and skill growth rates, lifecycle skill growth profiles, and the dynamics of non-skill earnings shocks.

We estimate low intergenerational elasticities (IGEs) for earnings in Canada; however, skill IGEs are typically 2–3 times larger due to considerable (and persistent) variation in earnings conditional on skills. Both earnings and skill IGEs decline for more recent child cohorts and are lower for children born to younger fathers. Intergenerational transmission of both initial skills and skill growth rates explains up to 40% of children’s skill variation. Skills become a more important determinant of earnings over the first part of workers’ careers; however, intergenerational transmission of skills becomes less important as children age, because skill growth rates are not well-predicted by parental skills. Parents’ initial skills and skill growth rates are equally important determinants of children’s skills, largely because both strongly influence children’s initial skills.

Finally, we study intergenerational mobility for the 35 largest cities in Canada, documenting the extent to which considerable differences in earnings and skill IGEs vary with the extent of local heterogeneity in parental skills vs. earnings instability.

当收入不平等反映了个人技能和其他非技能冲击的差异时,本文建立并估算了一个关于代际技能传递的双因素模型。我们考虑了初始技能和技能增长率的异质性,允许技能增长的变化随生命周期而变化。我们利用加拿大两代人 37 年的税收管理数据,利用代际和代内对数收入(不同年龄)的协方差,识别并估算了初始技能和技能增长率的代际相关结构、生命周期技能增长曲线以及非技能收入冲击的动态变化。在较新的子女群中,收入和技能的跨代弹性都有所下降,父亲年龄较小的子女的收入和技能跨代弹性也较低。初始技能和技能增长率的代际传递可解释高达 40% 的子女技能差异。在工人职业生涯的前半段,技能成为决定收入的一个更重要的因素;然而,随着儿童年龄的增长,技能的代际传递变得不那么重要了,因为父母的技能并不能很好地预测技能增长率。最后,我们研究了加拿大 35 个最大城市的代际流动性,记录了当地父母技能与收入不稳定性的异质性在多大程度上导致了收入和技能 IGE 的巨大差异。
{"title":"Earnings dynamics and intergenerational transmission of skill","authors":"Lance Lochner ,&nbsp;Youngmin Park","doi":"10.1016/j.jeconom.2021.12.009","DOIUrl":"10.1016/j.jeconom.2021.12.009","url":null,"abstract":"<div><p>This paper develops and estimates a two-factor model of intergenerational skill transmission when earnings inequality reflects differences in individual skills and other non-skill shocks. We consider heterogeneity in both initial skills and skill growth rates, allowing variation in skill growth to change over the lifecycle. Using administrative tax data on two linked generations of Canadians covering 37 years, we exploit covariances in log earnings (at different ages) both across and within generations to identify and estimate the intergenerational correlation structure for initial skills and skill growth rates, lifecycle skill growth profiles, and the dynamics of non-skill earnings shocks.</p><p>We estimate low intergenerational elasticities (IGEs) for earnings in Canada; however, skill IGEs are typically 2–3 times larger due to considerable (and persistent) variation in earnings conditional on skills. Both earnings and skill IGEs decline for more recent child cohorts and are lower for children born to younger fathers. Intergenerational transmission of both initial skills and skill growth rates explains up to 40% of children’s skill variation. Skills become a more important determinant of earnings over the first part of workers’ careers; however, intergenerational transmission of skills becomes less important as children age, because skill growth rates are not well-predicted by parental skills. Parents’ initial skills and skill growth rates are equally important determinants of children’s skills, largely because both strongly influence children’s initial skills.</p><p>Finally, we study intergenerational mobility for the 35 largest cities in Canada, documenting the extent to which considerable differences in earnings and skill IGEs vary with the extent of local heterogeneity in parental skills vs. earnings instability.</p></div>","PeriodicalId":15629,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Econometrics","volume":"243 1","pages":"Article 105255"},"PeriodicalIF":9.9,"publicationDate":"2024-07-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"141978516","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Gender pension gaps in a private retirement accounts system: A dynamic model of household labor supply and savings 私人退休账户体系中的性别养老金差距:家庭劳动力供给和储蓄的动态模型
IF 9.9 3区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-07-01 DOI: 10.1016/j.jeconom.2022.08.005
Clement Joubert , Petra E. Todd

This paper develops and estimates a dynamic model of individuals’ and couples’ labor supply, savings, and retirement decisions to analyze how the design of Chile’s privatized pension system and a reform undertaken in 2008 affect gender pension gaps and old-age poverty. Chile has one of the longest-running private retirements accounts systems in the world, which has served as a model for many countries. The paper estimates the dynamic model using pre-reform data and compares the model’s short-term forecasts with reduced form estimates of the reform’s causal impacts. The model provides accurate forecasts, so it is used to evaluate how actual and counterfactual changes in the pension system design affect men’s and women’s labor supply and savings decisions, pension receipts, and program costs over a longer time horizon. The results show that three design features significantly reduce gender pension gaps: expanding minimum pension benefit eligibility, providing a per-child pension bonus, and increasing women’s retirement age to be equal to men’s. Overall, the 2008 pension reform largely achieved its goals of reducing gender gaps and old age poverty, although the new system costs double that of the old system.

本文建立并估算了一个关于个人和夫妇的劳动力供给、储蓄和退休决策的动态模型,以分析智利私有化养老金制度的设计和 2008 年进行的改革如何影响性别养老金差距和老年贫困。智利是世界上运行时间最长的私人退休账户体系之一,为许多国家树立了典范。本文利用改革前的数据对动态模型进行了估算,并将模型的短期预测与改革因果影响的简化估算进行了比较。该模型提供了准确的预测,因此可用于评估养老金制度设计中的实际变化和反事实变化如何在更长的时间跨度内影响男性和女性的劳动力供给和储蓄决策、养老金收入和项目成本。结果表明,有三个设计特点大大缩小了养老金方面的性别差距:扩大最低养老金领取资格、提供按子女计算的养老金奖金,以及提高女性退休年龄,使其与男性退休年龄相同。总体而言,2008 年的养老金改革在很大程度上实现了缩小性别差距和减少老年贫困的目标,尽管新制度的成本是旧制度的两倍。
{"title":"Gender pension gaps in a private retirement accounts system: A dynamic model of household labor supply and savings","authors":"Clement Joubert ,&nbsp;Petra E. Todd","doi":"10.1016/j.jeconom.2022.08.005","DOIUrl":"10.1016/j.jeconom.2022.08.005","url":null,"abstract":"<div><p>This paper develops and estimates a dynamic model of individuals’ and couples’ labor supply, savings, and retirement decisions to analyze how the design of Chile’s privatized pension system and a reform undertaken in 2008 affect gender pension gaps and old-age poverty. Chile has one of the longest-running private retirements accounts systems in the world, which has served as a model for many countries. The paper estimates the dynamic model using pre-reform data and compares the model’s short-term forecasts with reduced form estimates of the reform’s causal impacts. The model provides accurate forecasts, so it is used to evaluate how actual and counterfactual changes in the pension system design affect men’s and women’s labor supply and savings decisions, pension receipts, and program costs over a longer time horizon. The results show that three design features significantly reduce gender pension gaps: expanding minimum pension benefit eligibility, providing a per-child pension bonus, and increasing women’s retirement age to be equal to men’s. Overall, the 2008 pension reform largely achieved its goals of reducing gender gaps and old age poverty, although the new system costs double that of the old system.</p></div>","PeriodicalId":15629,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Econometrics","volume":"243 1","pages":"Article 105337"},"PeriodicalIF":9.9,"publicationDate":"2024-07-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"141978512","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Human capital and migration: A cautionary tale 人力资本与移民:一个警世故事
IF 9.9 3区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-07-01 DOI: 10.1016/j.jeconom.2024.105720

We analyze the impact that the option of migration might have on human capital accumulation. We show that, when the return to education for migrants is lower in the destination than in the origin, the overall incentive to accumulate human capital is reduced as restrictions on migration are relaxed. We use panel data from the Chinese Household Income Project to document that the return to education for rural individuals is lower in urban areas than in rural areas. We then use a difference-in-differences design to show that the 1983 reform that eliminated the strong restriction that existed for rural–urban migration resulted in a reduction of 0.4 years of schooling for rural people in China. Guided by these results, we estimate a life-cycle dynamic discrete choice model of education decisions and circular rural–urban migration in which individuals differ in observable characteristics and unobservable cognitive and non-cognitive skills. We validate the model by showing it is able to replicate the impact estimates from the difference-in-differences specification. Our simulations show that, while it would take a small subsidy (conditional on staying in school) to undo about 40% of the negative effects of the 1983 policy on rural education, the annual subsidy would need to be half of annual earnings to undo the effects entirely.

我们分析了移民选择可能对人力资本积累产生的影响。我们的研究表明,当移民的教育回报率在目的地低于原籍地时,随着移民限制的放宽,人力资本积累的整体动力就会降低。我们利用中国家庭收入项目的面板数据,证明农村人口的教育回报率在城市地区低于农村地区。然后,我们利用差分设计表明,1983 年的改革取消了对农村人口向城市迁移的严格限制,导致中国农村人口的受教育年限减少了 0.4 年。在这些结果的指导下,我们估计了一个关于教育决策和城乡循环迁移的生命周期动态离散选择模型,在这个模型中,个体在可观察特征和不可观察的认知和非认知技能方面存在差异。我们对模型进行了验证,结果表明该模型能够复制差分模型的影响估计值。我们的模拟结果表明,虽然需要少量补贴(以留在学校为条件)才能消除 1983 年政策对农村教育产生的约 40% 的负面影响,但每年的补贴需要达到年收入的一半才能完全消除影响。
{"title":"Human capital and migration: A cautionary tale","authors":"","doi":"10.1016/j.jeconom.2024.105720","DOIUrl":"10.1016/j.jeconom.2024.105720","url":null,"abstract":"<div><p>We analyze the impact that the option of migration might have on human capital<span> accumulation. We show that, when the return to education for migrants is lower in the destination than in the origin, the overall incentive to accumulate human capital is reduced as restrictions on migration are relaxed. We use panel data from the Chinese Household Income Project to document that the return to education for rural individuals is lower in urban areas than in rural areas. We then use a difference-in-differences design to show that the 1983 reform that eliminated the strong restriction that existed for rural–urban migration resulted in a reduction of 0.4 years of schooling for rural people in China. Guided by these results, we estimate a life-cycle dynamic discrete choice model of education decisions and circular rural–urban migration in which individuals differ in observable characteristics and unobservable cognitive and non-cognitive skills. We validate the model by showing it is able to replicate the impact estimates from the difference-in-differences specification. Our simulations show that, while it would take a small subsidy (conditional on staying in school) to undo about 40% of the negative effects of the 1983 policy on rural education, the annual subsidy would need to be half of annual earnings to undo the effects entirely.</span></p></div>","PeriodicalId":15629,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Econometrics","volume":"243 1","pages":"Article 105720"},"PeriodicalIF":9.9,"publicationDate":"2024-07-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"140400420","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
期刊
Journal of Econometrics
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1