首页 > 最新文献

English & Commonwealth Law eJournal最新文献

英文 中文
What Can We Expect to Gain from Reforming the Insolvent Trading Remedy? 我们能从破产交易补救措施的改革中获得什么?
Pub Date : 2015-01-01 DOI: 10.1111/1468-2230.12106
Richard Williams
This paper argues that reform of the wrongful trading remedy in section 214 of the Insolvency Act 1986 is unlikely to yield significant increases in civil recovery for creditors of insolvent companies. The paper argues that the widely held view that procedural restrictions in the provision have unduly limited the application of the remedy are without foundation and, likewise, that there is little evidence that current modest levels of litigation under the provision demonstrate underperformance in the sanction relative to the scale of the misconduct against which it is directed. The paper draws on a wide range of analytical and empirical evidence to argue that the scope for application of the sanction is inherently limited by factors independent of the particular rules within the statutory remedy.
本文认为,对《1986年破产法》第214条中的不法交易救济的改革不太可能显著增加破产公司债权人的民事追索权。该文件认为,普遍认为该条款中的程序限制过度限制了补救措施的适用的观点是没有根据的,同样,几乎没有证据表明,目前根据该条款进行的适度诉讼表明,相对于该条款所针对的不当行为的规模,制裁的表现不佳。本文借鉴了广泛的分析和经验证据,认为制裁的适用范围本质上受到与法定救济中的具体规则无关的因素的限制。
{"title":"What Can We Expect to Gain from Reforming the Insolvent Trading Remedy?","authors":"Richard Williams","doi":"10.1111/1468-2230.12106","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1111/1468-2230.12106","url":null,"abstract":"This paper argues that reform of the wrongful trading remedy in section 214 of the Insolvency Act 1986 is unlikely to yield significant increases in civil recovery for creditors of insolvent companies. The paper argues that the widely held view that procedural restrictions in the provision have unduly limited the application of the remedy are without foundation and, likewise, that there is little evidence that current modest levels of litigation under the provision demonstrate underperformance in the sanction relative to the scale of the misconduct against which it is directed. The paper draws on a wide range of analytical and empirical evidence to argue that the scope for application of the sanction is inherently limited by factors independent of the particular rules within the statutory remedy.","PeriodicalId":255520,"journal":{"name":"English & Commonwealth Law eJournal","volume":"70 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2015-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"126960519","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 11
Good Faith in English Contract Law: A 'Contagious Disease of Alien Origin' 英国合同法中的诚信:一种“外来传染病”
Pub Date : 2014-12-02 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.2654752
A. Sinanan
This paper seeks to address the current position of good faith within English contract law. It contradicts the proposition that good faith is a “contagious disease of alien origin” by instead suggesting that the principles introduced by good faith and relational contract theory are simply a mutative development on classical contract theory. In so doing, the paper suggests that these principles simply seek to uphold the objectives of classical contract theory of facilitating economic exchange, albeit by different means. It rationalizes this development according to the theory of creative destruction, that in dynamic processes, objectives may only be achieved by the destruction of the old processes. The paper further considers the suppositions introduced by this paper in both a theoretical and practical context in relation to English contract law jurisprudence.
本文旨在探讨诚信在英国合同法中的地位。它与诚信是一种"外来传染病"的主张相矛盾,相反,它认为诚信和关系契约理论所引入的原则仅仅是对古典契约理论的一种变异发展。在这样做的过程中,本文表明,这些原则只是试图维护促进经济交换的古典契约理论的目标,尽管通过不同的手段。它根据创造性破坏理论使这种发展合理化,即在动态过程中,目标只能通过破坏旧过程来实现。本文进一步从理论和实践两方面考虑本文所提出的假设与英国合同法法学的关系。
{"title":"Good Faith in English Contract Law: A 'Contagious Disease of Alien Origin'","authors":"A. Sinanan","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.2654752","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2654752","url":null,"abstract":"This paper seeks to address the current position of good faith within English contract law. It contradicts the proposition that good faith is a “contagious disease of alien origin” by instead suggesting that the principles introduced by good faith and relational contract theory are simply a mutative development on classical contract theory. In so doing, the paper suggests that these principles simply seek to uphold the objectives of classical contract theory of facilitating economic exchange, albeit by different means. It rationalizes this development according to the theory of creative destruction, that in dynamic processes, objectives may only be achieved by the destruction of the old processes. The paper further considers the suppositions introduced by this paper in both a theoretical and practical context in relation to English contract law jurisprudence.","PeriodicalId":255520,"journal":{"name":"English & Commonwealth Law eJournal","volume":"25 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2014-12-02","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"127466262","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Enlisting the Public in the Policing of Immigration 让市民参与管理入境事务
Pub Date : 2014-12-01 DOI: 10.1093/BJC/AZU102
A. Aliverti
As border policing is no longer circumscribed to external borders and increasingly performed inland, in Britain migration work relies on the assistance of a range of unorthodox partners, including the public. The unearthing of the ‘community’ as a crucial partner to police a myriad of public safety issues, including migration, begs the question of what are the implications of mobilizing citizenship for law enforcement? This paper argues that enlisting the public in migration law enforcement yields important civic by-products: it ‘creates’ citizens and citizenship. It imparts civic training by instilling a sense of civic responsibility in law and order maintenance, and in doing so it intends to recreate social cohesion across a deeply fragmented society.
由于边境监管不再局限于外部边界,而是越来越多地在内陆开展工作,英国的移民工作依赖于包括公众在内的一系列非正统合作伙伴的协助。“社区”作为监管包括移民在内的众多公共安全问题的关键合作伙伴的发现,引出了一个问题:动员公民参与执法的含义是什么?本文认为,让公众参与移民执法会产生重要的公民副产品:它“创造”了公民和公民身份。它通过在维护法律和秩序方面灌输公民责任感来进行公民培训,并在这样做的过程中,它打算在一个严重分裂的社会中重建社会凝聚力。
{"title":"Enlisting the Public in the Policing of Immigration","authors":"A. Aliverti","doi":"10.1093/BJC/AZU102","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1093/BJC/AZU102","url":null,"abstract":"As border policing is no longer circumscribed to external borders and increasingly performed inland, in Britain migration work relies on the assistance of a range of unorthodox partners, including the public. The unearthing of the ‘community’ as a crucial partner to police a myriad of public safety issues, including migration, begs the question of what are the implications of mobilizing citizenship for law enforcement? This paper argues that enlisting the public in migration law enforcement yields important civic by-products: it ‘creates’ citizens and citizenship. It imparts civic training by instilling a sense of civic responsibility in law and order maintenance, and in doing so it intends to recreate social cohesion across a deeply fragmented society.","PeriodicalId":255520,"journal":{"name":"English & Commonwealth Law eJournal","volume":"1 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2014-12-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"130791632","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 39
The Unchanging ‘Debenture’ 不变的“债券”
Pub Date : 2014-11-01 DOI: 10.1017/S0008197314000993
Hans Tjio
The English Court of Appeal in Fons Hf v Corporal Ltd. [2014] EWCA Civ 304 has recently confirmed that the phrase “debenture” when used in a charge agreement should be given its ordinary wide meaning. Some caution should be attached to this holding. Although the word “debenture” commonly appears in legislation or in private contractual documents, the precise meaning that should be ascribed to the word varies with the context.
英国上诉法院在Fons Hf v Corporal Ltd. [2014] EWCA Civ 304中最近确认,在押记协议中使用的短语“debenture”应赋予其通常的广义含义。对于这种持有,应该谨慎一些。虽然“债券”一词通常出现在立法或私人合同文件中,但该词的确切含义因上下文而异。
{"title":"The Unchanging ‘Debenture’","authors":"Hans Tjio","doi":"10.1017/S0008197314000993","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1017/S0008197314000993","url":null,"abstract":"The English Court of Appeal in Fons Hf v Corporal Ltd. [2014] EWCA Civ 304 has recently confirmed that the phrase “debenture” when used in a charge agreement should be given its ordinary wide meaning. Some caution should be attached to this holding. Although the word “debenture” commonly appears in legislation or in private contractual documents, the precise meaning that should be ascribed to the word varies with the context.","PeriodicalId":255520,"journal":{"name":"English & Commonwealth Law eJournal","volume":"24 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2014-11-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"132131845","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Health Check: The NHS and Market Reforms 健康检查:国民保健服务和市场改革
Pub Date : 2014-10-30 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3903899
K. Niemietz
Since the early 2000s, the NHS has improved according to most measures of quality and performance. Survival rates for major diseases have increased, waiting lists have been shortened, and the prevalence of hospital infections has been reduced. This improvement has come from a very low base so that the performance of the NHS is still poor in international terms. For example, the UK ranks 20th out of 24 developed countries for cancer survival and 19th out of 23 for mortality amenable to healthcare. In league tables, the UK consistently ranks close to the post-communist countries of Central and Eastern Europe rather than to Western European countries. If the UK drew level with the 10th best-performing country in terms of mortality amenable to healthcare (Spain), at least 16 unnecessary deaths for every 100,000 inhabitants could be avoided each year – i.e. a total of about 10,000 deaths. The recent Commonwealth Fund study, which ranked the NHS well, has its merits, but it is structurally designed to favour an NHSstyle model of healthcare. The study’s limitations are perhaps best, albeit unintentionally, captured by The Guardian’s coverage of the report which stated: ‘The only serious black mark against the NHS was its poor record on keeping people alive.’ The UK comes 24th out of 30 high- and upper/middle-income countries for efficiency of the healthcare system. If the UK reached the efficiency level of the 5th best-performing country (Japan), life expectancy in the UK could be increased by more than two years without any additional healthcare spending and without people adopting healthier lifestyles. The reforms of the early 21st century gave well-performing hospitals more independence and introduced competition through a ‘payment by results’ formula. These reforms improved the service but they did not go far enough and have since stalled. The introduction of patient choice did lead patients to discriminate in favour of hospitals that had a better record. For example, postreform, a given increase in mortality after heart bypass operations led to a loss of market share for a hospital that was ten times greater than would have happened pre-reform. Scotland did not pursue the same healthcare reforms as England. The evidence shows that Scotland spends more per capita than England; it has larger numbers of hospital, dental, nursing, midwifery, health visiting, hospital management and support staff; and it has higher numbers of hospital beds and inpatient admissions. At the same time, Scotland has longer waiting times for inpatient and outpatient appointments, and longer ambulance response times. Scotland fares worse on outcome measures across the board. The intention of the reforms of the 2000s was that almost all healthcare spending would be channelled through the payment by results scheme and that the vast majority of hospitals would be Foundation Trusts. This has not materialised and the reforms need to be reinvigorated. Although non-NHS providers now
自21世纪初以来,NHS在大多数质量和绩效指标上都有所改善。重大疾病的存活率提高了,等候名单缩短了,医院感染率下降了。这种改善来自一个非常低的基础,因此国民保健服务的表现在国际上仍然很差。例如,在24个发达国家中,英国的癌症存活率排名第20,在23个发达国家中,英国的医疗死亡率排名第19。在排行榜上,英国的排名一直接近中欧和东欧的后共产主义国家,而不是西欧国家。如果联合王国在可获得医疗保健的死亡率方面与排名第十的国家(西班牙)持平,那么每年每10万居民中至少可避免16例不必要的死亡,即总共可避免约1万人死亡。联邦基金最近的一项研究对NHS进行了很好的排名,它有其优点,但它的结构设计倾向于采用NHS式的医疗模式。这项研究的局限性或许在《卫报》对该报告的报道中得到了最好的体现,尽管这是无意的,该报道称:“NHS唯一严重的污点是它在维持人们生命方面的糟糕记录。”“在30个高收入和中高收入国家中,英国的医疗体系效率排名第24位。如果英国达到排名第五的国家(日本)的效率水平,英国的预期寿命可以增加两年以上,而不需要任何额外的医疗保健支出,也不需要人们采取更健康的生活方式。21世纪初的改革给了表现良好的医院更多的独立性,并通过“按结果付费”的模式引入了竞争。这些改革改善了服务,但它们做得还不够,并从此停滞不前。病人选择的引入确实导致病人歧视那些有更好记录的医院。例如,改革后,心脏搭桥手术后死亡率的增加导致医院的市场份额损失是改革前的十倍。苏格兰没有推行与英格兰相同的医疗改革。有证据表明,苏格兰的人均支出高于英格兰;医院、牙科、护理、助产、保健探访、医院管理和支助人员较多;它的医院床位和住院人数也更多。与此同时,苏格兰住院和门诊预约的等待时间更长,救护车的反应时间也更长。苏格兰在整体结果指标上表现更差。本世纪头十年改革的意图是,几乎所有的医疗支出都将通过“按结果付费”计划进行,绝大多数医院将由基金会信托基金(Foundation Trusts)管理。这一目标尚未实现,改革需要重新焕发活力。尽管非nhs提供者现在占二级保健预算的9%左右,但这仍然远远达不到欧洲大陆系统中观察到的提供者多元化水平。例如,在德国,自愿非营利部门占所有医院床位的三分之一以上,私营营利性部门占近五分之一。私营部门也占法国所有医院床位的38%,奥地利的30%。除了重振21世纪初的改革计划外,为了提高护理效率和质量,还需要进行一些第二代改革:-患者应该能够在不同的初级保健提供者和专员之间进行选择。他们应该能够做到这一点,而不仅仅是基于他们居住的地方。相反,他们可能会选择在工作地点附近经营分支机构的连锁店,或者基于公民社会或宗教组织的“身份团体”。有证据表明,这种方法将改善护理。-保健专员和初级保健提供者应能够与医院等二级和三级保健提供者垂直整合。-必须允许医院和其他提供服务的组织破产。-最终,保健服务应允许完全的选择自由,以便人们可以在保健的各个阶段不受限制地选择私人提供者和私人专员。需要建立一个资金系统,根据适用于不同类型患者的成本和风险对提供者和专员进行补偿,以防止“挑三拣四”。这种机制早已在其他国家使用,可以很容易地转移到英国。
{"title":"Health Check: The NHS and Market Reforms","authors":"K. Niemietz","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3903899","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3903899","url":null,"abstract":"Since the early 2000s, the NHS has improved according to most measures of quality and performance. Survival rates for major diseases have increased, waiting lists have been shortened, and the prevalence of hospital infections has been reduced. This improvement has come from a very low base so that the performance of the NHS is still poor in international terms. For example, the UK ranks 20th out of 24 developed countries for cancer survival and 19th out of 23 for mortality amenable to healthcare. In league tables, the UK consistently ranks close to the post-communist countries of Central and Eastern Europe rather than to Western European countries. If the UK drew level with the 10th best-performing country in terms of mortality amenable to healthcare (Spain), at least 16 unnecessary deaths for every 100,000 inhabitants could be avoided each year – i.e. a total of about 10,000 deaths. The recent Commonwealth Fund study, which ranked the NHS well, has its merits, but it is structurally designed to favour an NHSstyle model of healthcare. The study’s limitations are perhaps best, albeit unintentionally, captured by The Guardian’s coverage of the report which stated: ‘The only serious black mark against the NHS was its poor record on keeping people alive.’ The UK comes 24th out of 30 high- and upper/middle-income countries for efficiency of the healthcare system. If the UK reached the efficiency level of the 5th best-performing country (Japan), life expectancy in the UK could be increased by more than two years without any additional healthcare spending and without people adopting healthier lifestyles. The reforms of the early 21st century gave well-performing hospitals more independence and introduced competition through a ‘payment by results’ formula. These reforms improved the service but they did not go far enough and have since stalled. The introduction of patient choice did lead patients to discriminate in favour of hospitals that had a better record. For example, postreform, a given increase in mortality after heart bypass operations led to a loss of market share for a hospital that was ten times greater than would have happened pre-reform. Scotland did not pursue the same healthcare reforms as England. The evidence shows that Scotland spends more per capita than England; it has larger numbers of hospital, dental, nursing, midwifery, health visiting, hospital management and support staff; and it has higher numbers of hospital beds and inpatient admissions. At the same time, Scotland has longer waiting times for inpatient and outpatient appointments, and longer ambulance response times. Scotland fares worse on outcome measures across the board. The intention of the reforms of the 2000s was that almost all healthcare spending would be channelled through the payment by results scheme and that the vast majority of hospitals would be Foundation Trusts. This has not materialised and the reforms need to be reinvigorated. Although non-NHS providers now","PeriodicalId":255520,"journal":{"name":"English & Commonwealth Law eJournal","volume":"242 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2014-10-30","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"132316624","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2
Becoming a Metagovernor: A Case Study of the Murray-Darling Basin Authority 成为一个超级州长:墨累-达令盆地管理局的个案研究
Pub Date : 2014-09-24 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.2500644
P. Fawcett, Matthew Wood
The Murray-Darling Basin is Australia’s most important river system. It is home to over two million people, covers 14% of the country’s landmass and is of national significance socially, culturally, economically and environmentally. The governance network surrounding the Basin is complex involving multiple levels of governments (Commonwealth, state and territory) as well as numerous non-state actors, including individuals and communities living in the Basin, industry groups and environmentalists. The past three to four decades have seen increased levels of intergovernmental cooperation and coordination as nearly all actors have recognised the need for concerted action in order to avoid potentially catastrophic, long-term and irreversible environmental damage within the Basin. The decision to create the Murray Darling Basin Authority (MDBA) in September 2008 represented another step towards increased cooperation as it was the first time in Australian history that a dedicated Agency had been created with an explicit mandate to develop an integrated water management plan at the Basin level. This paper tracks ebbs and flows in the extent to which the MDBA was able to secure the political legitimacy that it required in order to successfully oversee the development of this Plan from the MDBA’s establishment in September 2008 through to the Plan’s commencement in November 2012. We analyse the MDBA’s capacity to develop political legitimacy during this time, which we conceptualise in terms of the cognitive, moral, and pragmatic legitimacy that the Agency was able to achieve within the wider community. We also show how the MDBA learned to become an effective metagovernor by shaping, developing and mending its political legitimacy. Thus, we are able to track how the MDBA was able to learn from its past failures at metagovernance. This article hence provides the first systematic empirical analysis of how delegated agencies can become effective metagovernors through direct attempts to foster their political legitimacy. More broadly, we conclude that to become effective (and to effectively become) metagovernors, organisations require stakeholders within and beyond the immediate governance network to accept their decisions (on whatever grounds) as appropriate and justified – i.e. legitimate – whilst also recognising that achieving such a status is more likely to be provisional, transitory and ephemeral, rather than lengthy, enduring and permanent. This is increasingly relevant, we argue, in late-modern societies where trust in elected or non-elected authorities is increasingly challenged.
墨累-达令盆地是澳大利亚最重要的河流系统。它是200多万人口的家园,占全国陆地面积的14%,在社会、文化、经济和环境方面具有全国意义。盆地周围的治理网络非常复杂,涉及多个级别的政府(联邦、州和地区)以及许多非国家行为体,包括生活在盆地的个人和社区、工业团体和环保主义者。过去三、四十年来,政府间合作和协调的水平有所提高,因为几乎所有行动者都认识到需要采取协调一致的行动,以避免盆地内潜在的灾难性、长期和不可逆转的环境破坏。2008年9月成立墨累达令流域管理局(MDBA)的决定代表着加强合作的又一步,因为这是澳大利亚历史上第一次成立一个专门的机构,明确授权在流域一级制定综合水资源管理计划。从2008年9月多边开发银行成立到2012年11月该计划启动,本文追踪了多边开发银行在多大程度上能够确保其所需的政治合法性,从而成功监督该计划的发展。我们分析了MDBA在这段时间内发展政治合法性的能力,我们从机构能够在更广泛的社区中实现的认知、道德和实用合法性的角度对其进行了概念化。我们还展示了MDBA如何通过塑造、发展和修补其政治合法性,学会成为一个有效的元管理者。因此,我们能够跟踪MDBA是如何从过去的元治理失败中学习的。因此,本文提供了第一个系统的实证分析,即授权机构如何通过直接尝试促进其政治合法性而成为有效的元管理者。更广泛地说,我们得出结论,要成为有效的(并有效地成为)元管理者,组织需要直接治理网络内外的利益相关者接受他们的决定(无论基于何种理由),认为这是适当和合理的——即合法的——同时也要认识到,实现这样的地位更可能是临时的、暂时的和短暂的,而不是漫长的、持久的和永久的。我们认为,在对民选或非民选当局的信任日益受到挑战的近代社会,这一点越来越重要。
{"title":"Becoming a Metagovernor: A Case Study of the Murray-Darling Basin Authority","authors":"P. Fawcett, Matthew Wood","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.2500644","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2500644","url":null,"abstract":"The Murray-Darling Basin is Australia’s most important river system. It is home to over two million people, covers 14% of the country’s landmass and is of national significance socially, culturally, economically and environmentally. The governance network surrounding the Basin is complex involving multiple levels of governments (Commonwealth, state and territory) as well as numerous non-state actors, including individuals and communities living in the Basin, industry groups and environmentalists. The past three to four decades have seen increased levels of intergovernmental cooperation and coordination as nearly all actors have recognised the need for concerted action in order to avoid potentially catastrophic, long-term and irreversible environmental damage within the Basin. The decision to create the Murray Darling Basin Authority (MDBA) in September 2008 represented another step towards increased cooperation as it was the first time in Australian history that a dedicated Agency had been created with an explicit mandate to develop an integrated water management plan at the Basin level. This paper tracks ebbs and flows in the extent to which the MDBA was able to secure the political legitimacy that it required in order to successfully oversee the development of this Plan from the MDBA’s establishment in September 2008 through to the Plan’s commencement in November 2012. We analyse the MDBA’s capacity to develop political legitimacy during this time, which we conceptualise in terms of the cognitive, moral, and pragmatic legitimacy that the Agency was able to achieve within the wider community. We also show how the MDBA learned to become an effective metagovernor by shaping, developing and mending its political legitimacy. Thus, we are able to track how the MDBA was able to learn from its past failures at metagovernance. This article hence provides the first systematic empirical analysis of how delegated agencies can become effective metagovernors through direct attempts to foster their political legitimacy. More broadly, we conclude that to become effective (and to effectively become) metagovernors, organisations require stakeholders within and beyond the immediate governance network to accept their decisions (on whatever grounds) as appropriate and justified – i.e. legitimate – whilst also recognising that achieving such a status is more likely to be provisional, transitory and ephemeral, rather than lengthy, enduring and permanent. This is increasingly relevant, we argue, in late-modern societies where trust in elected or non-elected authorities is increasingly challenged.","PeriodicalId":255520,"journal":{"name":"English & Commonwealth Law eJournal","volume":"18 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2014-09-24","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"125467946","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 3
Informal Employment Contracts and the Battle over Retirement Benefits 非正式雇佣合同和退休福利之争
Pub Date : 2014-08-31 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.2399197
P. Spiro
Weak economic growth and the resultant financial pressures have made post-retirement benefits a tempting target for cutbacks, in both the private and public sectors. Unlike pensions themselves, ancillary retirement benefits such as supplementary medical coverage are often vaguely defined. If they are part of the contract of employment, an attempt by the employer to reduce them represents a breach of contract. The employment contract is often quite informal, and there is room for debate about which promises were contractual. In two recent decisions in BC and Ontario, retirees were able to convince the court that the benefits were contractual. Each case hinges on its own facts and the evidence on past communications, and how they fit with the contractual principles of offer, acceptance and consideration. Part of the problem is that the details of these benefits are often presented to the employees only after they have accepted the position. This allows the employer to argue that they are non-binding, gratuitous promises. Under the unilateral contract principle, the employee can accept by performance. However, there is a question of whether any consideration is provided by the employees to make the contract binding. In this case, it can be argued that the economic hypothesis of the efficiency wage is relevant. This hypothesis posits that better remuneration positively influences employee loyalty and productivity, providing consideration in exchange for the employer's offer of the enhanced benefit.
疲弱的经济增长和由此带来的财政压力,使得退休后福利成为私营和公共部门削减的诱人目标。与养老金本身不同,辅助退休福利,如补充医疗保险,往往定义模糊。如果他们是雇佣合同的一部分,雇主试图减少他们就代表违约。雇佣合同通常是非正式的,关于哪些承诺是合同,有争论的余地。在不列颠哥伦比亚省和安大略省最近的两项裁决中,退休人员能够说服法院,这些福利是合同规定的。每一案件都取决于其本身的事实和过去通信的证据,以及它们如何符合要约、接受和对价的合同原则。部分问题在于,这些福利的细节往往是在员工接受这个职位之后才向他们展示的。这使得雇主可以争辩说,这些承诺是没有约束力的、无偿的。在单方合同原则下,员工可以通过绩效接受。然而,有一个问题是,雇员是否提供了任何对价以使合同具有约束力。在这种情况下,可以认为效率工资的经济假设是相关的。这一假设认为,更好的薪酬对员工的忠诚度和生产力有积极的影响,为雇主提供更高的利益提供考虑。
{"title":"Informal Employment Contracts and the Battle over Retirement Benefits","authors":"P. Spiro","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.2399197","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.2399197","url":null,"abstract":"Weak economic growth and the resultant financial pressures have made post-retirement benefits a tempting target for cutbacks, in both the private and public sectors. Unlike pensions themselves, ancillary retirement benefits such as supplementary medical coverage are often vaguely defined. If they are part of the contract of employment, an attempt by the employer to reduce them represents a breach of contract. The employment contract is often quite informal, and there is room for debate about which promises were contractual. In two recent decisions in BC and Ontario, retirees were able to convince the court that the benefits were contractual. Each case hinges on its own facts and the evidence on past communications, and how they fit with the contractual principles of offer, acceptance and consideration. Part of the problem is that the details of these benefits are often presented to the employees only after they have accepted the position. This allows the employer to argue that they are non-binding, gratuitous promises. Under the unilateral contract principle, the employee can accept by performance. However, there is a question of whether any consideration is provided by the employees to make the contract binding. In this case, it can be argued that the economic hypothesis of the efficiency wage is relevant. This hypothesis posits that better remuneration positively influences employee loyalty and productivity, providing consideration in exchange for the employer's offer of the enhanced benefit.","PeriodicalId":255520,"journal":{"name":"English & Commonwealth Law eJournal","volume":"2012 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2014-08-31","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"128935740","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
European Banking Union and the EU Single Financial Market: More Differentiated Integration, or Disintegration? 欧洲银行联盟和欧盟单一金融市场:更加差异化的整合,还是解体?
Pub Date : 2014-08-01 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.2426580
Eilís Ferran
European Banking Union (EBU) provides an important new context in which to examine how differentiation affects integration. This chapter considers: (1) the short to medium term appeal of EBU participation for Member States that do not use the euro (centripetal effects); and (ii) the potential over the same time horizon for EBU to lead to disorderly break-up of the EU (centrifugal effects). On (1), EBU pushes the boundaries of legal technology with a view to maximising the functional equivalence between euro Member States, whose participation is compulsory, and the non-euro Member States that choose to participate in EBU via a close cooperation agreement. The early indications that some non-euro Member States do want to join EBU notwithstanding certain lingering differences between their position and that of euro area Member States provide an encouraging sign as to the value of those efforts. But whilst fair participation terms are necessary, they are not a sufficient precondition to the exercise of the option to participate in EBU. Each non-euro Member State will make its own wide-ranging political calculations on whether there are net welfare gains from EBU and in doing so will take due account of the policy preferences of private and public stakeholders, which may pull in different directions. The full extent of the centripetal effect of EBU is therefore hard to predict but it is certainly a new force to be reckoned with. On (2), the chapter reaches a cautiously optimistic prognosis. The legal safeguards in EBU to address disintegration risks are not a permanent solution to the problem of certain Member States being intent upon remaining outside deeper integration in the monetary and economic sphere but nor are they merely fleeting or stopgap measures. The chapter identifies compelling economic incentives for all Member States to make these safeguards work and to resist destructive behaviour.
欧洲银行业联盟(EBU)为研究差异化如何影响一体化提供了一个重要的新背景。本章考虑:(1)欧洲货币联盟参与对不使用欧元的成员国的中短期吸引力(向心效应);(ii)欧盟在同一时间范围内导致欧盟无序解体的可能性(离心效应)。在(1)上,EBU推动了法律技术的界限,以期最大限度地实现强制性参与的欧元区成员国与通过密切合作协议选择参与EBU的非欧元区成员国之间的功能对等。早期的迹象表明,一些非欧元成员国确实希望加入欧洲货币联盟,尽管它们的立场与欧元区成员国的立场之间存在着某些挥之不去的差异,这是一个令人鼓舞的迹象,表明这些努力的价值。但是,虽然公平参与条款是必要的,但它们并不是行使参与EBU期权的充分先决条件。每一个非欧元区成员国都将对EBU是否有净福利收益做出自己广泛的政治计算,并在此过程中适当考虑私人和公共利益相关者的政策偏好,这可能会导致不同的方向。因此,EBU的向心力效应的全面程度很难预测,但它肯定是一股不容忽视的新力量。在(2)上,本章做出了谨慎乐观的预测。欧洲货币联盟应对解体风险的法律保障措施并不能永久解决某些成员国有意留在货币和经济领域更深层次一体化之外的问题,但它们也不仅仅是短暂的或权宜之计。本章确定了所有会员国使这些保障措施发挥作用和抵制破坏性行为的强有力的经济激励。
{"title":"European Banking Union and the EU Single Financial Market: More Differentiated Integration, or Disintegration?","authors":"Eilís Ferran","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.2426580","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.2426580","url":null,"abstract":"European Banking Union (EBU) provides an important new context in which to examine how differentiation affects integration. This chapter considers: (1) the short to medium term appeal of EBU participation for Member States that do not use the euro (centripetal effects); and (ii) the potential over the same time horizon for EBU to lead to disorderly break-up of the EU (centrifugal effects). On (1), EBU pushes the boundaries of legal technology with a view to maximising the functional equivalence between euro Member States, whose participation is compulsory, and the non-euro Member States that choose to participate in EBU via a close cooperation agreement. The early indications that some non-euro Member States do want to join EBU notwithstanding certain lingering differences between their position and that of euro area Member States provide an encouraging sign as to the value of those efforts. But whilst fair participation terms are necessary, they are not a sufficient precondition to the exercise of the option to participate in EBU. Each non-euro Member State will make its own wide-ranging political calculations on whether there are net welfare gains from EBU and in doing so will take due account of the policy preferences of private and public stakeholders, which may pull in different directions. The full extent of the centripetal effect of EBU is therefore hard to predict but it is certainly a new force to be reckoned with. On (2), the chapter reaches a cautiously optimistic prognosis. The legal safeguards in EBU to address disintegration risks are not a permanent solution to the problem of certain Member States being intent upon remaining outside deeper integration in the monetary and economic sphere but nor are they merely fleeting or stopgap measures. The chapter identifies compelling economic incentives for all Member States to make these safeguards work and to resist destructive behaviour.","PeriodicalId":255520,"journal":{"name":"English & Commonwealth Law eJournal","volume":"15 3 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2014-08-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"126927809","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 20
Subject to Review? Consideration, Liquidated Damages and the Penalty Jurisdiction 有待检讨?对价、违约金与处罚管辖权
Pub Date : 2014-07-14 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.2512582
Dr Eliza Mik
The paper examines the relationship between what seem to be basic principles in contract law: "consideration need not be adequate" and "the rule against penalties applies only to sums payable on breach." The 'reluctant inspiration' lies in the recent Australian case of Andrews v. Australia and New Zealand Banking Group Ltd, which establishes that the absence of breach or an obligation to avoid the occurrence of an event upon which a sum becomes payable, does not render such sum incapable of being characterized as a penalty. This decision constitutes an unexpected divergence from the position in most other common law jurisdictions. What are its practical implications? Should we even engage in historical arguments given that the penalty jurisdiction evolved at the time where the law did not recognize enforceable promises to perform? The paper commences with broad observations regarding the enforceability of liquidated damages clauses, the increasingly commercial approach to evaluating whether a pre-estimate of loss is "genuine" and the necessity to treat sums payable on breach as part of the commercial bargain. The more liberal the attitude with regards to the amount (i.e. the higher the sum that can be stipulated), the more limited the effect of the rule against penalties. A liberal approach does not affect the contract breaker’s ability to invoke the rule but his ability to succeed. In combination with the description of the performance, the price and the limitation of liability (if any), sums payable on breach often point towards a transaction-specific risk allocation. In many instances such sums come dangerously close to primary obligations. And courts do not, as a matter of principle, review primary obligations. Once this is acknowledged, it becomes even more difficult to justify any attempts to expand the scope of the penalty jurisdiction beyond payments triggered by breach. After confronting some of the historical arguments made by the court in Andrews, the paper analyzes the recurring attempts to extend judicial review of contractual payments by creating "hybrid stipulations" – sums that are neither payable on breach nor in return for contractual performance. A difficult theoretical exercise awaits: should we create artificial divisions between contractual payments to establish whether they can be reviewed? Or should we finally acknowledge that all sums payable under a contract are part of the commercial bargain? On one hand, doctrinal integrity may point towards the need to vigorously defend the present form of the rule against penalties, including its (seemingly) strict limitation to sums payable on breach. On the other, some arguments made in Andrews and in other recent cases highlight the theoretical inconsistencies of its current formulation. After all, the "breach/no breach" dichotomy can also be regarded as a device for avoiding judicial scrutiny. At present, on the basis of Andrews alone it appears incorrect to use an institution th
本文考察了合同法中看似基本原则的关系:“对价不必足够”和“反对处罚的规则只适用于违约时应支付的款项”。“不情愿的启发”出现在最近的澳大利亚Andrews诉澳大利亚和新西兰银行集团有限公司案中,该案规定,没有违约或没有义务避免应支付款项的事件的发生,并不意味着该款项不能被定性为罚款。这一决定与大多数其他普通法司法管辖区的立场形成了意想不到的分歧。它的实际意义是什么?考虑到刑罚管辖权是在法律不承认可强制执行的承诺的情况下发展起来的,我们是否应该参与历史争论?本文首先对违约金条款的可执行性、评估预估损失是否“真实”的日益商业化的方法以及将违约应付款项视为商业交易一部分的必要性进行了广泛的观察。对金额的态度越宽松(即可以规定的金额越高),反对处罚规则的效果就越有限。自由的做法不会影响违约者援引规则的能力,但会影响他成功的能力。结合对履约的描述、价格和责任限制(如果有的话),违约应付金额通常指向特定于交易的风险分配。在许多情况下,这种数额危险地接近初级债务。作为一个原则问题,法院不审查主要义务。一旦承认这一点,就更难以证明任何企图将惩罚管辖权范围扩大到因违约而引发的付款以外的行为是正当的。在面对安德鲁斯法院提出的一些历史论点之后,本文分析了通过创建“混合规定”(既不能在违约时支付,也不能作为履行合同的回报)来扩大对合同付款的司法审查的反复尝试。等待我们的是一项困难的理论练习:我们是否应该人为地划分合同付款,以确定它们是否可以被审查?或者我们最终应该承认,合同下的所有应付款项都是商业交易的一部分?一方面,理论上的完整性可能表明需要大力捍卫现行形式的规则,反对处罚,包括(表面上)严格限制违反时应支付的款项。另一方面,安德鲁斯案和近期其他案例中的一些论点凸显了其当前表述在理论上的不一致性。毕竟,“违约/不违约”的二分法也可以被视为逃避司法审查的一种手段。目前,仅从安德鲁斯案来看,用一种禁止违约威慑的制度来审查合同的商业实质似乎是不正确的。反对处罚的规则反映了不强制执行压迫性或不合理交易的一般公平原则。它不会改革商业上轻率的交易。鉴于其特殊性质,刑罚管辖权的行使应谨慎- -即使涉及违约应付的款项。一旦违约应付款项被视为商业交易的一部分,就更难对其进行审查。然而,如果付款与违反合同承诺无关,那么它就危险地接近于合同承诺。任何评论似乎都不可接受。
{"title":"Subject to Review? Consideration, Liquidated Damages and the Penalty Jurisdiction","authors":"Dr Eliza Mik","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.2512582","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2512582","url":null,"abstract":"The paper examines the relationship between what seem to be basic principles in contract law: \"consideration need not be adequate\" and \"the rule against penalties applies only to sums payable on breach.\" The 'reluctant inspiration' lies in the recent Australian case of Andrews v. Australia and New Zealand Banking Group Ltd, which establishes that the absence of breach or an obligation to avoid the occurrence of an event upon which a sum becomes payable, does not render such sum incapable of being characterized as a penalty. This decision constitutes an unexpected divergence from the position in most other common law jurisdictions. What are its practical implications? Should we even engage in historical arguments given that the penalty jurisdiction evolved at the time where the law did not recognize enforceable promises to perform? The paper commences with broad observations regarding the enforceability of liquidated damages clauses, the increasingly commercial approach to evaluating whether a pre-estimate of loss is \"genuine\" and the necessity to treat sums payable on breach as part of the commercial bargain. The more liberal the attitude with regards to the amount (i.e. the higher the sum that can be stipulated), the more limited the effect of the rule against penalties. A liberal approach does not affect the contract breaker’s ability to invoke the rule but his ability to succeed. In combination with the description of the performance, the price and the limitation of liability (if any), sums payable on breach often point towards a transaction-specific risk allocation. In many instances such sums come dangerously close to primary obligations. And courts do not, as a matter of principle, review primary obligations. Once this is acknowledged, it becomes even more difficult to justify any attempts to expand the scope of the penalty jurisdiction beyond payments triggered by breach. After confronting some of the historical arguments made by the court in Andrews, the paper analyzes the recurring attempts to extend judicial review of contractual payments by creating \"hybrid stipulations\" – sums that are neither payable on breach nor in return for contractual performance. A difficult theoretical exercise awaits: should we create artificial divisions between contractual payments to establish whether they can be reviewed? Or should we finally acknowledge that all sums payable under a contract are part of the commercial bargain? On one hand, doctrinal integrity may point towards the need to vigorously defend the present form of the rule against penalties, including its (seemingly) strict limitation to sums payable on breach. On the other, some arguments made in Andrews and in other recent cases highlight the theoretical inconsistencies of its current formulation. After all, the \"breach/no breach\" dichotomy can also be regarded as a device for avoiding judicial scrutiny. At present, on the basis of Andrews alone it appears incorrect to use an institution th","PeriodicalId":255520,"journal":{"name":"English & Commonwealth Law eJournal","volume":"60 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2014-07-14","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"121946551","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Plays, Performances and Power Struggles – Examining Copyright's ‘Integrity’ in the Field of Theatre 戏剧、表演和权力斗争——审视戏剧领域版权的“完整性”
Pub Date : 2014-07-01 DOI: 10.1111/1468-2230.12078
Luke McDonagh
This article explores the notion of ‘integrity’ under copyright law by analysing examples of 'integrity-based objections' in the field of theatre. These objections typically involve playwrights objecting to changes being made to their copyright works by other parties, such as directors and actors. This analysis is deepened by the use of two concepts from the field of art theory – ‘aura’, as put forward by Walter Benjamin, and ‘trajectory’, as outlined by Bruno Latour and Adam Lowe. Finally, to shed further light on the issues raised, the work of Pierre Bourdieu is used to present new empirical research recently undertaken by the author in the field of UK theatre. This research demonstrates that ‘power struggles’ are a common feature of theatrical collaboration; that copyright is deeply implicated in the way such power struggles are conceived; and moreover, that resolving these power struggles successfully – including taking account of ‘integrity-based objections’ – is crucial to theatrical practice.
本文通过分析戏剧领域中“基于完整性的反对”的例子,探讨版权法下的“完整性”概念。这些反对通常涉及剧作家反对其他方(如导演和演员)对其版权作品所做的修改。通过使用艺术理论领域的两个概念——沃尔特·本雅明(Walter Benjamin)提出的“光环”(aura)和布鲁诺·拉图尔(Bruno Latour)和亚当·洛(Adam Lowe)概述的“轨迹”(trajectory)——加深了这种分析。最后,为了进一步阐明所提出的问题,皮埃尔·布迪厄的工作被用来介绍作者最近在英国戏剧领域进行的新的实证研究。本研究表明,“权力斗争”是戏剧合作的共同特征;版权与这种权力斗争的构思方式有着深刻的联系;此外,成功地解决这些权力斗争——包括考虑到“基于诚信的反对意见”——对戏剧实践至关重要。
{"title":"Plays, Performances and Power Struggles – Examining Copyright's ‘Integrity’ in the Field of Theatre","authors":"Luke McDonagh","doi":"10.1111/1468-2230.12078","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1111/1468-2230.12078","url":null,"abstract":"This article explores the notion of ‘integrity’ under copyright law by analysing examples of 'integrity-based objections' in the field of theatre. These objections typically involve playwrights objecting to changes being made to their copyright works by other parties, such as directors and actors. This analysis is deepened by the use of two concepts from the field of art theory – ‘aura’, as put forward by Walter Benjamin, and ‘trajectory’, as outlined by Bruno Latour and Adam Lowe. Finally, to shed further light on the issues raised, the work of Pierre Bourdieu is used to present new empirical research recently undertaken by the author in the field of UK theatre. This research demonstrates that ‘power struggles’ are a common feature of theatrical collaboration; that copyright is deeply implicated in the way such power struggles are conceived; and moreover, that resolving these power struggles successfully – including taking account of ‘integrity-based objections’ – is crucial to theatrical practice.","PeriodicalId":255520,"journal":{"name":"English & Commonwealth Law eJournal","volume":"1 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2014-07-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"128680243","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2
期刊
English & Commonwealth Law eJournal
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1