首页 > 最新文献

Economic Inequality & the Law eJournal最新文献

英文 中文
The Social Assistance System in Bulgaria 保加利亚的社会援助制度
Pub Date : 2019-10-21 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3477129
V. Terziev, M. Bogdanova, Dimitar Kanev, Marin Georgiev, Simeonov Simeon
Social policy as a set of principles, legal norms, activities and institutions, aimed at creating conditions that ensure the quality of life of the citizens of a country, is an expression of the social relations between the state and its citizens. Social policy determines safety (social, health, economic) and security of the individuals in society.Keywords: social assistance, social protection, social policy.
社会政策是一套原则、法律规范、活动和制度,旨在创造条件,确保一个国家的公民的生活质量,是国家和公民之间的社会关系的表现。社会政策决定了社会中个人的安全(社会、健康、经济)和保障。关键词:社会救助,社会保护,社会政策。
{"title":"The Social Assistance System in Bulgaria","authors":"V. Terziev, M. Bogdanova, Dimitar Kanev, Marin Georgiev, Simeonov Simeon","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3477129","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3477129","url":null,"abstract":"Social policy as a set of principles, legal norms, activities and institutions, aimed at creating conditions that ensure the quality of life of the citizens of a country, is an expression of the social relations between the state and its citizens. Social policy determines safety (social, health, economic) and security of the individuals in society.\u0000Keywords: social assistance, social protection, social policy.","PeriodicalId":306856,"journal":{"name":"Economic Inequality & the Law eJournal","volume":"139 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2019-10-21","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"124619228","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 4
Aligned: Sex Workers’ Lessons for the Gig Economy 对齐:性工作者对零工经济的教训
Pub Date : 2019-10-14 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3726920
Yvette Butler
Society’s perception of a type of work and the people who engage in money-generating activities has an impact on whether and how the law protects (or does not protect) the people who perform those activities. Work can be legitimized or delegitimized. Workers are protected or left out to dry depending upon their particular “hustle.” This Article argues that gig workers and sex workers face similar challenges within the legal system and that these groups can and should collaborate to their collective advantage when seeking reforms. Gig workers have been gaining legitimacy while sex workers still primarily operate in the shadow economy. This Article digs into the sometimes-conflicting desires of individuals working as sex workers and gig workers to inform how gig workers can achieve the power and economic independence necessary to prevent workplace exploitation.
社会对某种类型的工作和从事赚钱活动的人的看法会影响法律是否以及如何保护(或不保护)从事这些活动的人。工作可以合法化,也可以不合法化。工人们要么受到保护,要么被晾在一边,这取决于他们的“忙碌”程度。本文认为,零工和性工作者在法律体系中面临着类似的挑战,这些群体在寻求改革时可以也应该合作,以实现集体利益。零工正在获得合法性,而性工作者仍然主要在影子经济中运作。本文深入探讨了性工作者和零工工作者有时相互冲突的愿望,以告知零工工作者如何获得必要的权力和经济独立,以防止工作场所的剥削。
{"title":"Aligned: Sex Workers’ Lessons for the Gig Economy","authors":"Yvette Butler","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3726920","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3726920","url":null,"abstract":"Society’s perception of a type of work and the people who engage in money-generating activities has an impact on whether and how the law protects (or does not protect) the people who perform those activities. Work can be legitimized or delegitimized. Workers are protected or left out to dry depending upon their particular “hustle.” This Article argues that gig workers and sex workers face similar challenges within the legal system and that these groups can and should collaborate to their collective advantage when seeking reforms. Gig workers have been gaining legitimacy while sex workers still primarily operate in the shadow economy. This Article digs into the sometimes-conflicting desires of individuals working as sex workers and gig workers to inform how gig workers can achieve the power and economic independence necessary to prevent workplace exploitation.","PeriodicalId":306856,"journal":{"name":"Economic Inequality & the Law eJournal","volume":"13 5 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2019-10-14","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"133813412","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 4
People, Inc.? Law, Economic Enterprise, and the Development of Inequality in China 人,Inc .) ?法律、经济、企业与中国不平等的发展
Pub Date : 2019-07-31 DOI: 10.1093/AJCL/AVZ003
Teemu Ruskola
This Article tells the story of two Chinas and of different forms of public enterprise associated with each: state-owned enterprises (SOEs) in urban China and township-and-village enterprises (TVEs) in rural China. Historically SOEs have constituted the dominant form of socialist enterprise in China. However, China’s unprecedented economic growth began with the rise of rural industry in the 1980s, and the bulk of rural growth was generated by a new type of entity known as TVEs. While legal scholars have mostly ignored TVEs, economists have devoted a great deal of theoretical attention to them: How were TVEs able to succeed in the absence of legally protected property rights, in defiance of standard economic theory? Remarkably, they operated without a formal legal basis. This Article argues that long before the enactment of the PRC’s first Company Law in 1993, in TVEs local government law performed the core functions of corporation law—a phenomenon this Article characterizes as “Village, Inc.” It was this law of local governance, and the formal and informal institutions supporting it, that propelled China’s phenomenal growth for nearly two decades while helping close the historic welfare gap between city and country. The Article next compares TVEs’ record of success with that of SOEs. The Company Law promulgated in 1993 marked a reorientation from rural reforms to restructuring urban SOEs. Despite its apparent novelty, in many respects the Company Law simply codified institutional arrangements pioneered by TVEs. Even after SOEs were “corporatized” in order to attract outside capital, the state remained a controlling shareholder—a configuration this Article describes as “People, Inc.” However, despite the benefit of a formally promulgated corporate statute, as a group corporatized SOEs have not been able to replicate TVEs’ extraordinary success. Beyond the Company Law’s formal structures, there has been no informal “local law” of SOEs to regulate them, equivalent to the relatively egalitarian village institutions that governed the operation of TVEs. Significantly, however, the corporatization of SOEs has not only restructured the state’s relationship to capital. The final part of the Article considers how it has also fundamentally altered the relationship between capital and labor. The enactment of the Company Law was accompanied by the promulgation of a new Labor Law in 1994, mandating that all employees be provided with employment contracts. Since then, the revolutionary political subject of Maoism—“the people”—has been atomized into independent economic subjects responsible for their own welfare outside of work. This, in turn, has resulted in tectonic shifts in the boundaries among the state, the market, and the family. Moreover, with the contractualization of all labor, even urban workers no longer enjoy a guaranteed share of the benefits of economic development. Today, an earlier state-enforced inequality between city and country is increa
历史上,国有企业一直是中国社会主义企业的主导形式。然而,中国前所未有的经济增长始于20世纪80年代农村工业的兴起,农村增长的大部分是由一种被称为乡镇企业的新型实体产生的。虽然法律学者大多忽略了乡镇企业,但经济学家却对它们投入了大量的理论关注:乡镇企业是如何在没有法律保护的产权的情况下,无视标准的经济理论而取得成功的?值得注意的是,他们的行动没有正式的法律依据。本文认为,早在1993年中华人民共和国第一部公司法颁布之前,地方政府法就在乡镇企业中履行了公司法的核心职能——本文将这种现象定性为“乡镇公司”。正是这种地方治理的法律,以及支持它的正式和非正式机构,推动了中国近20年的显著增长,同时帮助缩小了城乡之间历史性的福利差距。接下来,文章比较了乡镇企业和国有企业的成功记录。1993年颁布的《公司法》标志着从农村改革到城市国有企业改制的重新定位。尽管《公司法》看起来很新颖,但在许多方面,它只是将乡镇企业开创的制度安排编纂成法律。即使在国有企业为了吸引外部资本而“公司化”之后,国家仍然是控股股东——本文将这种结构描述为“人民公司”。然而,尽管有正式颁布的公司法规的好处,作为一个集团,公司化的国有企业仍无法复制乡镇企业的非凡成功。在公司法的正式结构之外,没有非正式的国有企业“地方法律”来规范它们,相当于管理乡镇企业运营的相对平等的乡村机构。然而,值得注意的是,国有企业的公司化不仅重组了国家与资本的关系。文章的最后一部分考虑了它如何从根本上改变了资本和劳动之间的关系。伴随着《公司法》的颁布,1994年颁布了新的《劳动法》,规定所有员工都必须签订劳动合同。从那时起,毛主义的革命政治主体——“人民”——被原子化为独立的经济主体,在工作之外为自己的福利负责。这反过来又导致了国家、市场和家庭之间界限的结构性变化。此外,随着所有劳动力的契约化,即使是城市工人也不再享有经济发展利益的保障份额。今天,早前由国家造成的城乡不平等日益被社会范围内的贫富鸿沟所压倒,而这种鸿沟没有必要的地理关联。
{"title":"People, Inc.? Law, Economic Enterprise, and the Development of Inequality in China","authors":"Teemu Ruskola","doi":"10.1093/AJCL/AVZ003","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1093/AJCL/AVZ003","url":null,"abstract":"\u0000 This Article tells the story of two Chinas and of different forms of public enterprise associated with each: state-owned enterprises (SOEs) in urban China and township-and-village enterprises (TVEs) in rural China. Historically SOEs have constituted the dominant form of socialist enterprise in China. However, China’s unprecedented economic growth began with the rise of rural industry in the 1980s, and the bulk of rural growth was generated by a new type of entity known as TVEs. While legal scholars have mostly ignored TVEs, economists have devoted a great deal of theoretical attention to them: How were TVEs able to succeed in the absence of legally protected property rights, in defiance of standard economic theory? Remarkably, they operated without a formal legal basis. This Article argues that long before the enactment of the PRC’s first Company Law in 1993, in TVEs local government law performed the core functions of corporation law—a phenomenon this Article characterizes as “Village, Inc.” It was this law of local governance, and the formal and informal institutions supporting it, that propelled China’s phenomenal growth for nearly two decades while helping close the historic welfare gap between city and country.\u0000 The Article next compares TVEs’ record of success with that of SOEs. The Company Law promulgated in 1993 marked a reorientation from rural reforms to restructuring urban SOEs. Despite its apparent novelty, in many respects the Company Law simply codified institutional arrangements pioneered by TVEs. Even after SOEs were “corporatized” in order to attract outside capital, the state remained a controlling shareholder—a configuration this Article describes as “People, Inc.” However, despite the benefit of a formally promulgated corporate statute, as a group corporatized SOEs have not been able to replicate TVEs’ extraordinary success. Beyond the Company Law’s formal structures, there has been no informal “local law” of SOEs to regulate them, equivalent to the relatively egalitarian village institutions that governed the operation of TVEs.\u0000 Significantly, however, the corporatization of SOEs has not only restructured the state’s relationship to capital. The final part of the Article considers how it has also fundamentally altered the relationship between capital and labor. The enactment of the Company Law was accompanied by the promulgation of a new Labor Law in 1994, mandating that all employees be provided with employment contracts. Since then, the revolutionary political subject of Maoism—“the people”—has been atomized into independent economic subjects responsible for their own welfare outside of work. This, in turn, has resulted in tectonic shifts in the boundaries among the state, the market, and the family. Moreover, with the contractualization of all labor, even urban workers no longer enjoy a guaranteed share of the benefits of economic development. Today, an earlier state-enforced inequality between city and country is increa","PeriodicalId":306856,"journal":{"name":"Economic Inequality & the Law eJournal","volume":"16 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2019-07-31","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"125864577","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Should Governments Tax the Rich and Subsidize the Poor? A Comparative Study of Muslim and Christian Respondents 政府应该对富人征税而补贴穷人吗?穆斯林和基督徒受访者的比较研究
Pub Date : 2019-01-23 DOI: 10.3390/REL10020072
Robert W. McGee, Serkan Benk, B. Yüzbaşı
This study used the most recent World Values Survey (WVS) dataset to determine whether Christian and Muslim views on the acceptability of taxing the rich and subsidizing the poor was an essential feature of democracy. The sample size included more than 23,000 individuals from more than 50 countries. More than a dozen socioeconomic and attitudinal variables were also examined to determine whether significant differences existed. The study found that differences in viewpoint were often significant.
这项研究使用了最新的世界价值观调查(WVS)数据集,以确定基督教和穆斯林对对富人征税和补贴穷人的可接受性的看法是否是民主的基本特征。样本规模包括来自50多个国家的23,000多人。研究人员还检查了十多个社会经济和态度变量,以确定是否存在显著差异。研究发现,观点的差异往往是显著的。
{"title":"Should Governments Tax the Rich and Subsidize the Poor? A Comparative Study of Muslim and Christian Respondents","authors":"Robert W. McGee, Serkan Benk, B. Yüzbaşı","doi":"10.3390/REL10020072","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.3390/REL10020072","url":null,"abstract":"This study used the most recent World Values Survey (WVS) dataset to determine whether Christian and Muslim views on the acceptability of taxing the rich and subsidizing the poor was an essential feature of democracy. The sample size included more than 23,000 individuals from more than 50 countries. More than a dozen socioeconomic and attitudinal variables were also examined to determine whether significant differences existed. The study found that differences in viewpoint were often significant.","PeriodicalId":306856,"journal":{"name":"Economic Inequality & the Law eJournal","volume":"55 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2019-01-23","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"122731737","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 3
Cities as Drivers of Social Mobility 城市作为社会流动的驱动力
Pub Date : 2019-01-04 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3310480
A. Michelangeli, Umut Türk
Intergenerational mobility refers to children moving up from the social class position held by their parents. Previous studies indicate family background as one of the major determinants of socioeconomic mobility and, in general, of individual life chances. This paper extends the standard approach to measure intergenerational social mobility by examining the role of cities where offspring grew up. The idea is that cities can provide resources and opportunities able to increase the chance of employment and status attainment. We assess intergenerational mobility in Italy, the most immobile country in Europe together with Greece and Portugal. We use a data survey provided by the Italian National Institute of Statistics (ISTAT), which provides information on the individual-level track of Italian students’ life path from high school to occupation. We merge these data with city-level data on economic conditions, human capital, and social capital. We distinguish between students who attended university in the same province where they presumably grew up and those who migrated to another province for higher education. This allows us to test whether migration affects the shift in occupation type and, if so, which characteristics of cities enhance upward mobility.
代际流动指的是孩子从父母所处的社会阶层地位上升。先前的研究表明,家庭背景是社会经济流动性的主要决定因素之一,总的来说,也是个人生活机会的主要决定因素之一。本文通过考察后代成长城市的作用,扩展了衡量代际社会流动性的标准方法。其理念是,城市可以提供资源和机会,以增加就业机会和地位的实现。我们评估了意大利的代际流动性,意大利与希腊和葡萄牙一起是欧洲最不流动的国家。我们使用了意大利国家统计局(ISTAT)提供的数据调查,该调查提供了意大利学生从高中到职业的个人生活轨迹的信息。我们将这些数据与城市层面的经济状况、人力资本和社会资本数据合并。我们区分了那些在他们可能成长的省份上大学的学生和那些迁移到另一个省份接受高等教育的学生。这使我们能够测试移民是否会影响职业类型的转变,如果是的话,城市的哪些特征会增强向上流动。
{"title":"Cities as Drivers of Social Mobility","authors":"A. Michelangeli, Umut Türk","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3310480","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3310480","url":null,"abstract":"Intergenerational mobility refers to children moving up from the social class position held by their parents. Previous studies indicate family background as one of the major determinants of socioeconomic mobility and, in general, of individual life chances. This paper extends the standard approach to measure intergenerational social mobility by examining the role of cities where offspring grew up. The idea is that cities can provide resources and opportunities able to increase the chance of employment and status attainment. We assess intergenerational mobility in Italy, the most immobile country in Europe together with Greece and Portugal. We use a data survey provided by the Italian National Institute of Statistics (ISTAT), which provides information on the individual-level track of Italian students’ life path from high school to occupation. We merge these data with city-level data on economic conditions, human capital, and social capital. We distinguish between students who attended university in the same province where they presumably grew up and those who migrated to another province for higher education. This allows us to test whether migration affects the shift in occupation type and, if so, which characteristics of cities enhance upward mobility.","PeriodicalId":306856,"journal":{"name":"Economic Inequality & the Law eJournal","volume":"393 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2019-01-04","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"122783781","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 5
Captive Audience Meetings: The Right Not to Attend 强制性的听众会议:不参加的权利
Pub Date : 2018-10-08 DOI: 10.1017/9781108610070.026
Paul M. Secunda
For nearly seventy years, the National Labor Relations Board (NLRB or "Board") and various courts have interpreted the National Labor Relations Act (NLRA or "Act") as permitting employers to give captive audience meetings during labor organizational campaigns in the private-sector. Employees, in the midst of deciding whether to join a union, must attend such meetings where "labor relations consultants" usually dictate management's views about the evils of unionism. These meeting occur during working hours, when management is best situated to shackle employees through the exertion of its economic authority and to play on fears of job loss if employees vote in favor of unionization. During these meetings, employees are not permitted to question the employer representative and employers are not obligated to provide the union access to the workplace to present opposing views. While in a formal sense employees are free to leave these meetings, they do so in reality at the peril of losing their jobs. Put simply, rightfully motivated by the necessity of continued employment for basic economic survival, employees will not miss the threatening subtexts of carefully crafted message. Such messages, while free from overt statutorily prohibited threats of reprisal or promise of benefits, will nonetheless convey the detrimental effects of failing to agree with the employer's anti-union stance. Even though eventual voting on unionization will be completed by secret ballot, most employees by that point seem to lose all interest in supporting a cause that will surely draw their employer's ire. Thus, the central argument of this Chapter is that captive audience meetings are not about employer speech rights at all, but rather amount to coercive conduct against employees in derogation of employees' right to self-organization under the NLRA. Of course, employers are free to express or discuss anti-union views with their employees. However, doing so through the mechanism of forced listening, implied coercion, and fear is conduct that should be regulated under the NLRA. Utilizing the conduct/speech distinction in labor picketing law and sexual harassment law, this Chapter will establish the similar conduct-like nature of captive audience meetings and contend that the Board should make employer captive audience meetings a per se violation of Section 8(a)(1) of the NLRA, as it is conduct that directly interferes with, restrains and/or intimidates employees in Section 7 organizational rights to decide whether they wish to join a union.
近70年来,国家劳工关系委员会(NLRB或“委员会”)和各种法院都将《国家劳工关系法》(NLRA或“法案”)解释为允许雇主在私营部门的劳工组织运动期间举行强制听众会议。在决定是否加入工会的过程中,员工必须参加这样的会议,在那里,“劳资关系顾问”通常会口述管理层对工会主义弊端的看法。这些会议在工作时间举行,这是管理层通过行使其经济权力来束缚员工的最佳时机,也是利用员工投票支持工会组织而担心失业的最佳时机。在这些会议中,雇员不得向雇主代表提问,雇主也没有义务让工会进入工作场所提出反对意见。虽然在正式意义上,员工可以自由离开这些会议,但实际上,他们这样做可能会丢掉工作。简单地说,出于基本经济生存需要继续就业的正当动机,员工不会错过精心制作的信息的威胁潜台词。这些信息,虽然没有公开的法律禁止的报复威胁或福利承诺,但仍然会传达不同意雇主反工会立场的有害影响。尽管最终的工会投票将通过无记名投票完成,但到那时,大多数员工似乎对支持一项肯定会引起雇主愤怒的事业失去了所有兴趣。因此,本章的中心论点是,强制听众会议根本不是关于雇主的言论权利,而是一种针对雇员的强制性行为,损害了雇员在NLRA下的自我组织权利。当然,雇主可以自由地与员工表达或讨论反工会的观点。然而,通过强迫倾听、隐含胁迫和恐惧的机制来做到这一点,是应该受到NLRA监管的行为。本章将利用劳工纠集法和性骚扰法中行为/言论的区别,确立俘虏听众会议类似行为的性质,并主张董事会应将雇主俘虏听众会议本身定为违反NLRA第8(a)(1)条的行为,因为这种行为直接干扰、限制和/或恐吓雇员在第7条的组织权利中决定他们是否希望加入工会。
{"title":"Captive Audience Meetings: The Right Not to Attend","authors":"Paul M. Secunda","doi":"10.1017/9781108610070.026","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108610070.026","url":null,"abstract":"For nearly seventy years, the National Labor Relations Board (NLRB or \"Board\") and various courts have interpreted the National Labor Relations Act (NLRA or \"Act\") as permitting employers to give captive audience meetings during labor organizational campaigns in the private-sector. Employees, in the midst of deciding whether to join a union, must attend such meetings where \"labor relations consultants\" usually dictate management's views about the evils of unionism. These meeting occur during working hours, when management is best situated to shackle employees through the exertion of its economic authority and to play on fears of job loss if employees vote in favor of unionization. During these meetings, employees are not permitted to question the employer representative and employers are not obligated to provide the union access to the workplace to present opposing views. While in a formal sense employees are free to leave these meetings, they do so in reality at the peril of losing their jobs. \u0000Put simply, rightfully motivated by the necessity of continued employment for basic economic survival, employees will not miss the threatening subtexts of carefully crafted message. Such messages, while free from overt statutorily prohibited threats of reprisal or promise of benefits, will nonetheless convey the detrimental effects of failing to agree with the employer's anti-union stance. Even though eventual voting on unionization will be completed by secret ballot, most employees by that point seem to lose all interest in supporting a cause that will surely draw their employer's ire. Thus, the central argument of this Chapter is that captive audience meetings are not about employer speech rights at all, but rather amount to coercive conduct against employees in derogation of employees' right to self-organization under the NLRA. Of course, employers are free to express or discuss anti-union views with their employees. However, doing so through the mechanism of forced listening, implied coercion, and fear is conduct that should be regulated under the NLRA. Utilizing the conduct/speech distinction in labor picketing law and sexual harassment law, this Chapter will establish the similar conduct-like nature of captive audience meetings and contend that the Board should make employer captive audience meetings a per se violation of Section 8(a)(1) of the NLRA, as it is conduct that directly interferes with, restrains and/or intimidates employees in Section 7 organizational rights to decide whether they wish to join a union.","PeriodicalId":306856,"journal":{"name":"Economic Inequality & the Law eJournal","volume":"43 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2018-10-08","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"125607646","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Impacts of Financial Literacy and Confidence on the Severity of Financial Hardship in Australia 金融知识和信心对澳大利亚金融困难严重程度的影响
Pub Date : 2018-08-06 DOI: 10.14453/AABFJ.V12I4.2
E. Bourova, M. Anderson, I. Ramsay, P. Ali
Consumers in Australia and other developed countries are increasingly required to interact with providers of complex financial products and services, and to estimate, mitigate or absorb the risks that flow from their financial decisions. A range of debt-related problems in Australia have been attributed to low levels of financial literacy in the population. However, there has been limited research exploring the relationship between low financial literacy and the problem of financial hardship, where a consumer takes on payment obligations under a contract, but then becomes unable to meet them when they fall due. Drawing on a survey of Australians who recently experienced debt problems, this article examines the impact of financial literacy levels and levels of confidence in managing day-to-day spending on the severity of financial hardship. The article also examines the impacts of financial literacy and confidence levels on the strategies employed to get by financially while in debt. The article shows that while there is no straightforward relationship between low financial literacy and severity of financial hardship, lower levels of financial literacy may reduce consumers’ ability to avoid some of the more serious consequences of default, particularly if coupled with overconfidence about their ability to manage spending.
澳大利亚和其他发达国家的消费者越来越多地被要求与复杂金融产品和服务的提供者互动,并估计、减轻或吸收其金融决策所产生的风险。澳大利亚一系列与债务有关的问题归因于人口中金融知识水平低。然而,关于低金融知识水平与财务困难问题之间关系的研究有限,财务困难是指消费者根据合同承担支付义务,但在到期时却无法履行。根据对最近经历过债务问题的澳大利亚人的调查,本文研究了财务知识水平和管理日常支出的信心水平对财务困难严重程度的影响。本文还研究了金融知识和信心水平对负债时财务策略的影响。这篇文章表明,虽然低金融知识水平和经济困难的严重程度之间没有直接的关系,但较低的金融知识水平可能会降低消费者避免违约的一些更严重后果的能力,特别是如果加上对自己管理支出能力的过度自信。
{"title":"Impacts of Financial Literacy and Confidence on the Severity of Financial Hardship in Australia","authors":"E. Bourova, M. Anderson, I. Ramsay, P. Ali","doi":"10.14453/AABFJ.V12I4.2","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.14453/AABFJ.V12I4.2","url":null,"abstract":"Consumers in Australia and other developed countries are increasingly required to interact with providers of complex financial products and services, and to estimate, mitigate or absorb the risks that flow from their financial decisions. A range of debt-related problems in Australia have been attributed to low levels of financial literacy in the population. However, there has been limited research exploring the relationship between low financial literacy and the problem of financial hardship, where a consumer takes on payment obligations under a contract, but then becomes unable to meet them when they fall due. Drawing on a survey of Australians who recently experienced debt problems, this article examines the impact of financial literacy levels and levels of confidence in managing day-to-day spending on the severity of financial hardship. The article also examines the impacts of financial literacy and confidence levels on the strategies employed to get by financially while in debt. The article shows that while there is no straightforward relationship between low financial literacy and severity of financial hardship, lower levels of financial literacy may reduce consumers’ ability to avoid some of the more serious consequences of default, particularly if coupled with overconfidence about their ability to manage spending.","PeriodicalId":306856,"journal":{"name":"Economic Inequality & the Law eJournal","volume":"17 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2018-08-06","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"133821801","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 11
Intellectual Property and the End of Work 知识产权和工作的终结
Pub Date : 2018-07-14 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3011735
C. Hrdy
The conventional wisdom is that intellectual property (IP) is good for jobs. Indeed, according to legislators and the U.S. patent office, IP “creates jobs.” But this is not quite right. The purpose of IP is to increase the amount of innovation in the economy. Yet a significant subset of the innovations protected by IP, from self-service kiosks to self-driving cars, are in fact labor-saving. They reduce the amount of human labor required to complete a task. Therefore, to the extent IP is successful at incentivizing innovation, IP actually contributes to job loss. More precisely, IP contributes to what this article terms technological un/employment: job loss, and job creation, resulting from technological change. Commentators concerned about the “end of work” have suggested using taxation to slow down the pace of automation and provide aid to displaced workers. But this article yields another surprising insight: IP law itself could be designed to effectuate similar goals, either alone or in coordination with the tax system. For example, rather than taxing businesses that employ robots, legislators could deny patents on robots, or tax IP owners and use the proceeds to fund social programs like a universal basic income. IP’s relationship to technological un/employment, and the implications for public policy, seem obvious in hindsight. Yet the connection has been overlooked. Lawyers and academics who study IP must pay more attention.
传统观点认为,知识产权(IP)有利于就业。事实上,根据立法者和美国专利局的说法,知识产权“创造了就业机会”。但这并不完全正确。知识产权的目的是增加经济中创新的数量。然而,从自助服务亭到自动驾驶汽车,受知识产权保护的创新中有很大一部分实际上是节省劳动力的。它们减少了完成一项任务所需的人力劳动量。因此,在某种程度上,知识产权成功地激励了创新,知识产权实际上导致了失业。更准确地说,知识产权促成了本文所称的技术失业:技术变革导致的失业和就业创造。担心“工作终结”的评论人士建议利用税收来减缓自动化的步伐,并为失业工人提供援助。但这篇文章产生了另一个令人惊讶的见解:知识产权法本身也可以被设计成实现类似的目标,要么单独实施,要么与税收系统协同实施。例如,立法者可以不向使用机器人的企业征税,而是拒绝授予机器人专利,或者向知识产权所有者征税,并将所得用于资助全民基本收入等社会项目。事后看来,知识产权与技术失业的关系及其对公共政策的影响似乎是显而易见的。然而,这种联系被忽视了。研究知识产权的律师和学者必须多加关注。
{"title":"Intellectual Property and the End of Work","authors":"C. Hrdy","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3011735","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3011735","url":null,"abstract":"The conventional wisdom is that intellectual property (IP) is good for jobs. Indeed, according to legislators and the U.S. patent office, IP “creates jobs.” But this is not quite right. The purpose of IP is to increase the amount of innovation in the economy. Yet a significant subset of the innovations protected by IP, from self-service kiosks to self-driving cars, are in fact labor-saving. They reduce the amount of human labor required to complete a task. Therefore, to the extent IP is successful at incentivizing innovation, IP actually contributes to job loss. More precisely, IP contributes to what this article terms technological un/employment: job loss, and job creation, resulting from technological change. Commentators concerned about the “end of work” have suggested using taxation to slow down the pace of automation and provide aid to displaced workers. But this article yields another surprising insight: IP law itself could be designed to effectuate similar goals, either alone or in coordination with the tax system. For example, rather than taxing businesses that employ robots, legislators could deny patents on robots, or tax IP owners and use the proceeds to fund social programs like a universal basic income. IP’s relationship to technological un/employment, and the implications for public policy, seem obvious in hindsight. Yet the connection has been overlooked. Lawyers and academics who study IP must pay more attention.","PeriodicalId":306856,"journal":{"name":"Economic Inequality & the Law eJournal","volume":"18 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2018-07-14","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"115888761","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Residential Segregation: The Role of Inequality and Housing Subsidies 居住隔离:不平等与住房补贴的作用
Pub Date : 2018-06-01 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3191791
P. Harting, D. Radi
Abstract Residential segregation is a key public policy issue that is driven by economic factors on the one side, and individual attitudes towards ethnic diversity on the other side. We assume a modeling framework that consists of a population of two ethnic groups, a rental market for each neighborhood, and household’s utility which depends on consumption and housing. Accounting for income disparities and heterogeneous preferences for living in ethnically diverse neighborhoods, we examine the residential segregation patterns that occur when households make their neighborhood choice by taking economic and diversity related aspects into account. The investigation reveals that ethnic income disparities and heterogeneous preferences are antagonistic forces such that a certain level of income stratification is the price for residential integration. In light of these findings, we discuss to which extent and under which conditions housing subsidy policies can favor residential integration.
居住隔离是一个关键的公共政策问题,它一方面受到经济因素的驱动,另一方面受到个人对种族多样性的态度的驱动。我们假设一个建模框架由两个民族的人口、每个社区的租赁市场以及依赖于消费和住房的家庭效用组成。考虑到收入差距和居住在种族多样化社区的异质性偏好,我们研究了家庭在考虑经济和多样性相关因素的情况下做出社区选择时发生的居住隔离模式。研究表明,种族收入差距和异质性偏好是对立的力量,一定程度的收入分层是居民一体化的代价。根据这些发现,我们讨论了住房补贴政策在何种程度上和在何种条件下有利于居住一体化。
{"title":"Residential Segregation: The Role of Inequality and Housing Subsidies","authors":"P. Harting, D. Radi","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3191791","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3191791","url":null,"abstract":"Abstract Residential segregation is a key public policy issue that is driven by economic factors on the one side, and individual attitudes towards ethnic diversity on the other side. We assume a modeling framework that consists of a population of two ethnic groups, a rental market for each neighborhood, and household’s utility which depends on consumption and housing. Accounting for income disparities and heterogeneous preferences for living in ethnically diverse neighborhoods, we examine the residential segregation patterns that occur when households make their neighborhood choice by taking economic and diversity related aspects into account. The investigation reveals that ethnic income disparities and heterogeneous preferences are antagonistic forces such that a certain level of income stratification is the price for residential integration. In light of these findings, we discuss to which extent and under which conditions housing subsidy policies can favor residential integration.","PeriodicalId":306856,"journal":{"name":"Economic Inequality & the Law eJournal","volume":"8 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2018-06-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"125761770","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 8
Income, Consumption and Wealth Inequality in Spain (La desigualdad de la renta, el consumo y la riqueza en España) 西班牙的收入、消费和财富不平等(La desigualdad de La renta, el consumo y La riqueza en España)
Pub Date : 2018-05-31 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3188029
Brindusa Anghel, Henrique S. Basso, O. Bover, J. Casado, Laura Hospido, Mario Izquierdo, Iván Kataryniuk, Aitor Lacuesta, José Manuel Montero, Elena Vozmediano
espanolEl documento analiza el nivel y la evolucion de la desigualdad en Espana durante la ultima crisis y la fase inicial de la actual recuperacion. Para tal fin, el trabajo introduce, inicialmente, distintas dimensiones de la desigualdad en terminos de salarios, renta, consumo y riqueza, y analiza su evolucion. Este analisis muestra una reducida dispersion salarial en Espana en relacion con otras economias de nuestro entorno incluso tras los anos de crisis, mientras que el fuerte aumento del desempleo durante ese periodo provoco una elevada desigualdad de la renta per capita. El nivel de desigualdad en Espana se modera cuando se analiza la renta bruta total del hogar. Ademas, este nivel se redujo durante la crisis como consecuencia de la evolucion positiva de las pensiones en relacion con otras fuentes de renta y al retraso en la edad de emancipacion de los jovenes. Durante la crisis, se incremento la desigualdad en el consumo per capita, sobre todo, por la caida en el gasto de bienes duraderos en los hogares con bajos ingresos. La desigualdad de la riqueza es mayor que la de la renta y se incremento durante el periodo recesivo debido al mejor comportamiento de los rendimientos de los activos financieros que al de los reales, si bien Espana presenta un grado de desigualdad de la riqueza moderado en comparacion al de otros paises ya que la tenencia de activos reales es relativamente mas generalizada que en otros paises. La evolucion de la desigualdad durante las fases iniciales de la actual recuperacion economica revela que la caida del paro ha permitido una reduccion de la desigualdad de las rentas salariales y, aunque de forma mas limitada, tambien de la renta per capita. EnglishThis document analyses the level of inequality in Spain and how it evolved over the course of the past crisis and the early stages of the current recovery. To this end, it first introduces the various dimensions of wage, income, consumption and wealth inequality, and analyses how they have developed. The analysis shows less wage dispersion in Spain than in other comparable economies, even after the crisis years, while the surge in unemployment during the period resulted in a high level of inequality in per capita income. The level of inequality in Spain is more moderate when total gross household income is analysed, decreasing during the crisis as a result of pensions developing more favourably than other sources of income, in conjunction with young people delaying setting up home. Inequality in per capita consumption rose during the crisis, particularly as a result of a decrease in expenditure on consumer durables by low-income households. Wealth inequality exceeds income inequality and increased during the downturn as a result of financial assets outperforming real assets. Nevertheless, Spain’s wealth inequality is moderate by international standards, as ownership of real assets is more widespread than in other countries. The way inequality has evolved during the ear
espanolEl文件分析水平和evolucion不平等在西班牙过去危机的初期阶段,目前recuperacion。为此,引入工作,最初的几个方面不平等的术语。工资、收入、消费和财富,并分析其evolucion。这一分析表明,即使在经济危机多年之后,西班牙与其他邻国相比,工资差距也很小,而在此期间失业率的急剧上升导致了人均收入的高度不平等。在西班牙不平等水平时一点分析家庭总净租金。此外,这种程度降低了危机期间由于养恤金evolucion积极与其他收入来源的关系和在年轻人emancipacion年龄延迟。在危机期间,人均消费的不平等加剧,特别是低收入家庭耐用品支出的下降。不平等是比财富和收入增长出现隐性期间,由于金融资产回报率的行为比实际,虽然西班牙介绍了一位温和的财富不平等程度在其他国家因为comparacion实际持有资产是相对比其他国家更普遍。evolucion的最初阶段里,不平等现象目前recuperacion economica表明失业下降,落差了工资收入不平等问题,但更多地,人均收入也有限。EnglishThis document非洲the level of inequality in Spain and how it如火如荼over the 52,000 of the过去危机and the early stages of the current recovery。为此,它首先介绍了工资、收入、消费和财富不平等的各个方面,并分析了这些方面是如何发展的。The analysis节目较paulien注入in Spain than in其他经济体相比,even after The crisis》,而出现in unemployment during The period民兵in a high level of inequality in人均收入。在分析家庭总收入时,西班牙的不平等程度较为温和,在危机期间下降,原因是养恤金的发展比其他收入来源更有利,年轻人推迟安家。Inequality in人均消耗量rose during the危机,特别是由于a decrease in开支on消费者耐久by低收入农户。财富不平等exceeds income inequality and增加during the downturn因此of financial assets outperforming皇家资产。然而,按照国际标准,西班牙的财富不平等程度有所缓和,因为西班牙对不动产的所有权比其他国家更为广泛。The way inequality如火如荼during The early stages of The current economic recovery节目减少你that falling unemployment enabled paulien人均收入不平等,as well as in income inequality,尽管to a lesser涵盖面。
{"title":"Income, Consumption and Wealth Inequality in Spain (La desigualdad de la renta, el consumo y la riqueza en España)","authors":"Brindusa Anghel, Henrique S. Basso, O. Bover, J. Casado, Laura Hospido, Mario Izquierdo, Iván Kataryniuk, Aitor Lacuesta, José Manuel Montero, Elena Vozmediano","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3188029","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3188029","url":null,"abstract":"espanolEl documento analiza el nivel y la evolucion de la desigualdad en Espana durante la ultima crisis y la fase inicial de la actual recuperacion. Para tal fin, el trabajo introduce, inicialmente, distintas dimensiones de la desigualdad en terminos de salarios, renta, consumo y riqueza, y analiza su evolucion. Este analisis muestra una reducida dispersion salarial en Espana en relacion con otras economias de nuestro entorno incluso tras los anos de crisis, mientras que el fuerte aumento del desempleo durante ese periodo provoco una elevada desigualdad de la renta per capita. El nivel de desigualdad en Espana se modera cuando se analiza la renta bruta total del hogar. Ademas, este nivel se redujo durante la crisis como consecuencia de la evolucion positiva de las pensiones en relacion con otras fuentes de renta y al retraso en la edad de emancipacion de los jovenes. Durante la crisis, se incremento la desigualdad en el consumo per capita, sobre todo, por la caida en el gasto de bienes duraderos en los hogares con bajos ingresos. La desigualdad de la riqueza es mayor que la de la renta y se incremento durante el periodo recesivo debido al mejor comportamiento de los rendimientos de los activos financieros que al de los reales, si bien Espana presenta un grado de desigualdad de la riqueza moderado en comparacion al de otros paises ya que la tenencia de activos reales es relativamente mas generalizada que en otros paises. La evolucion de la desigualdad durante las fases iniciales de la actual recuperacion economica revela que la caida del paro ha permitido una reduccion de la desigualdad de las rentas salariales y, aunque de forma mas limitada, tambien de la renta per capita. EnglishThis document analyses the level of inequality in Spain and how it evolved over the course of the past crisis and the early stages of the current recovery. To this end, it first introduces the various dimensions of wage, income, consumption and wealth inequality, and analyses how they have developed. The analysis shows less wage dispersion in Spain than in other comparable economies, even after the crisis years, while the surge in unemployment during the period resulted in a high level of inequality in per capita income. The level of inequality in Spain is more moderate when total gross household income is analysed, decreasing during the crisis as a result of pensions developing more favourably than other sources of income, in conjunction with young people delaying setting up home. Inequality in per capita consumption rose during the crisis, particularly as a result of a decrease in expenditure on consumer durables by low-income households. Wealth inequality exceeds income inequality and increased during the downturn as a result of financial assets outperforming real assets. Nevertheless, Spain’s wealth inequality is moderate by international standards, as ownership of real assets is more widespread than in other countries. The way inequality has evolved during the ear","PeriodicalId":306856,"journal":{"name":"Economic Inequality & the Law eJournal","volume":"12 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2018-05-31","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"125361345","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 6
期刊
Economic Inequality & the Law eJournal
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1