首页 > 最新文献

Corporate Law: Securities Law最新文献

英文 中文
Regulating Hedge Funds 监管对冲基金
Pub Date : 2006-06-01 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.913045
D. Oesterle
This short piece is on the merits of government regulation of hedge funds. The article begins with background information on hedge funds and the current state of their regulation. After sifting through the various reasons advanced for regulating hedge funds, and focusing on three in particular - short selling, leverage and funds of funds, I argue that extensive direct regulation of hedge funds is unnecessary and may harm the country's trading markets. Indeed, the dramatic growth of hedge funds is in part attributable to the current overregulation of registered investment companies. We should, therefore, not tighten the regulation of hedge funds but lighten the regulation of registered investment companies. I also argue, however, that strengthening of some forms of indirect regulation of hedge fund leverage, principally limits on banks that lend to and are counterparties of hedge funds, may make sense.
这篇短文是关于政府监管对冲基金的优点。本文首先介绍了对冲基金的背景信息及其监管现状。在对监管对冲基金的各种理由进行了筛选之后,我认为,对对冲基金进行广泛的直接监管是不必要的,可能会损害国家的交易市场。事实上,对冲基金的急剧增长在一定程度上要归因于目前对注册投资公司的过度监管。因此,我们不应该收紧对对冲基金的监管,而应该放松对注册投资公司的监管。然而,我还认为,加强对对冲基金杠杆的某些形式的间接监管(主要是限制向对冲基金提供贷款并作为对冲基金交易对手的银行)可能是有意义的。
{"title":"Regulating Hedge Funds","authors":"D. Oesterle","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.913045","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.913045","url":null,"abstract":"This short piece is on the merits of government regulation of hedge funds. The article begins with background information on hedge funds and the current state of their regulation. After sifting through the various reasons advanced for regulating hedge funds, and focusing on three in particular - short selling, leverage and funds of funds, I argue that extensive direct regulation of hedge funds is unnecessary and may harm the country's trading markets. Indeed, the dramatic growth of hedge funds is in part attributable to the current overregulation of registered investment companies. We should, therefore, not tighten the regulation of hedge funds but lighten the regulation of registered investment companies. I also argue, however, that strengthening of some forms of indirect regulation of hedge fund leverage, principally limits on banks that lend to and are counterparties of hedge funds, may make sense.","PeriodicalId":336554,"journal":{"name":"Corporate Law: Securities Law","volume":"14 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2006-06-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"125979674","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 10
The Chameleon Effect: Beyond the Bonding Hypothesis for Cross-Listed Securities 变色龙效应:超越交叉上市证券的结合假说
Pub Date : 2006-05-10 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.901768
Cally Jordan
This paper is based on a presentation made at the New York Stock Exchange Conference on the Future of Global Equity Trading, March 12, 2004, Sarasota, FL. Looking back, was it a momentary enthusiasm? The dramatic increase in cross-listed securities, particularly in the United States, was one of the remarkable phenomena of the 1990s capital markets. The bonding, or corporate governance, hypothesis was one of the more intriguing theories to surface to explain the phenomenon. Cross-listing, the hypothesis suggested, might be a bonding mechanism by which firms, incorporated in a jurisdiction with weak protection of minority shareholder rights or poor enforcement mechanisms, could voluntarily subject themselves to higher disclosure standards and stricter enforcement of the US markets in order to attract investors. By focusing on shareholder protection as key to cross-listing, the bonding hypothesis became inextricably linked to an important and influential body of academic work, the law and finance literature. As intriguing as the bonding hypothesis is, this article argues that it offers only a partial explanation for the cross-listing phenomenon in the United States in the 1990s. Largely overlooked has been the main motor driving the exponential growth of cross-listings on the NYSE and NASDAQ in the 1990s: Canadian-based interlisted corporations (CBIs). CBIs form the largest single group of interlisted foreign corporations in the United States, by a huge margin, representing over 25% all interlistings on the NYSE, NMS-NASDAQ and AMEX in 2004. In fact, Canadian issuers form the largest single group of foreign private issuers (FPIs) in the United States, period. In 2004, there were nearly five times as many Canadian FPIs as the next largest national group, United Kingdom issuers. The bonding hypothesis does not explain CBIs easily. CBIs do not come from a weak investor protection jurisdiction and, for a variety of reasons and in a number of ways, tend not to signal their entry into the US market. Rather than bonding, CBIs have been adroitly exploiting what financial economists have described as the home bias of US portfolio investors. CBIs have been, at least until very recently, chameleons, deliberately blending into the woodwork of the US markets. This article will look at what makes CBIs different from most other interlisted companies and why the bonding hypothesis may not be explanatory of their behavior. In doing so, the article questions some of the underlying assumptions of the law and finance literature which supports the bonding hypothesis. Finally, the article considers implications of the CBI experience which may merit further consideration going forward.
这篇论文是基于2004年3月12日在佛罗里达州萨拉索塔举行的纽约证券交易所全球股票交易未来会议上的演讲。回顾过去,这是一时的热情吗?交叉上市证券的急剧增加,尤其是在美国,是20世纪90年代资本市场的显著现象之一。联结假说或公司治理假说是解释这一现象的较为有趣的理论之一。该假说认为,交叉上市可能是一种联系机制,通过这种机制,在少数股东权利保护薄弱或执法机制薄弱的司法管辖区注册的公司,可以自愿接受美国市场更高的披露标准和更严格的执法,以吸引投资者。通过将股东保护作为交叉上市的关键,债券假说与一个重要而有影响力的学术著作——法律和金融文献——密不可分地联系在一起。尽管“结合假说”很有趣,但本文认为,它只能部分解释20世纪90年代美国的交叉上市现象。上世纪90年代,推动纽交所和纳斯达克交叉上市呈指数级增长的主要动力,却在很大程度上被忽视:总部位于加拿大的交叉上市公司(cbi)。cbi是在美国上市的外国公司中最大的一个群体,占比很大,2004年在纽约证券交易所、纳斯达克和美国证券交易所上市的所有公司的25%以上。事实上,加拿大发行人是美国最大的外国私人发行人(fpi)群体。2004年,加拿大fpi的数量几乎是第二大国家集团英国的5倍。结合假说不能轻易解释CBIs。cbi并非来自投资者保护薄弱的司法管辖区,出于各种原因和多种方式,它们往往不会发出进入美国市场的信号。中央投资银行并没有将债券联系起来,而是巧妙地利用了金融经济学家所称的美国投资组合投资者的本土偏好。至少直到最近,中央银行一直是变色龙,刻意融入美国市场的框架。本文将探讨CBIs与大多数其他上市公司的不同之处,以及为什么纽带假说可能无法解释其行为。在此过程中,文章质疑了一些支持债券假设的法律和金融文献的基本假设。最后,本文考虑了CBI经验的影响,这可能值得进一步考虑。
{"title":"The Chameleon Effect: Beyond the Bonding Hypothesis for Cross-Listed Securities","authors":"Cally Jordan","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.901768","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.901768","url":null,"abstract":"This paper is based on a presentation made at the New York Stock Exchange Conference on the Future of Global Equity Trading, March 12, 2004, Sarasota, FL. Looking back, was it a momentary enthusiasm? The dramatic increase in cross-listed securities, particularly in the United States, was one of the remarkable phenomena of the 1990s capital markets. The bonding, or corporate governance, hypothesis was one of the more intriguing theories to surface to explain the phenomenon. Cross-listing, the hypothesis suggested, might be a bonding mechanism by which firms, incorporated in a jurisdiction with weak protection of minority shareholder rights or poor enforcement mechanisms, could voluntarily subject themselves to higher disclosure standards and stricter enforcement of the US markets in order to attract investors. By focusing on shareholder protection as key to cross-listing, the bonding hypothesis became inextricably linked to an important and influential body of academic work, the law and finance literature. As intriguing as the bonding hypothesis is, this article argues that it offers only a partial explanation for the cross-listing phenomenon in the United States in the 1990s. Largely overlooked has been the main motor driving the exponential growth of cross-listings on the NYSE and NASDAQ in the 1990s: Canadian-based interlisted corporations (CBIs). CBIs form the largest single group of interlisted foreign corporations in the United States, by a huge margin, representing over 25% all interlistings on the NYSE, NMS-NASDAQ and AMEX in 2004. In fact, Canadian issuers form the largest single group of foreign private issuers (FPIs) in the United States, period. In 2004, there were nearly five times as many Canadian FPIs as the next largest national group, United Kingdom issuers. The bonding hypothesis does not explain CBIs easily. CBIs do not come from a weak investor protection jurisdiction and, for a variety of reasons and in a number of ways, tend not to signal their entry into the US market. Rather than bonding, CBIs have been adroitly exploiting what financial economists have described as the home bias of US portfolio investors. CBIs have been, at least until very recently, chameleons, deliberately blending into the woodwork of the US markets. This article will look at what makes CBIs different from most other interlisted companies and why the bonding hypothesis may not be explanatory of their behavior. In doing so, the article questions some of the underlying assumptions of the law and finance literature which supports the bonding hypothesis. Finally, the article considers implications of the CBI experience which may merit further consideration going forward.","PeriodicalId":336554,"journal":{"name":"Corporate Law: Securities Law","volume":"42 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2006-05-10","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"126887005","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 14
Insider Trading, Chinese Walls, and Brokerage Commissions: The Origins of Modern Regulation of Information Flows in Securities Markets 内幕交易、中国壁垒和经纪佣金:现代证券市场信息流监管的起源
Pub Date : 2006-04-17 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.897180
S. Dolgopolov
This Article examines the emergence of modern regulation of information flows in securities markets in the form of restrictions on insider trading and Chinese Walls within financial intermediaries during the 1960s and early 1970s. It is argued that these regulatory developments can be traced to the demise of the fixed brokerage commissions regime on the New York Stock Exchange and other national securities exchanges and the corresponding use of inside information by brokers as a means of competing for brokerage revenues. In fact, the overall enforcement program of the SEC, which led to insider trading regulation and the creation of Chinese Walls, was strongly influenced by the existence of the fixed brokerage commissions regime and the related concern about the representation of financial institutions on corporate boards. This Article also examines the evolution of the fixed brokerage commissions regimes in the United Kingdom and Japan and argues that such price controls strongly influenced insider trading practices and the emergence of the regulation of information flows in these countries.
本文考察了20世纪60年代和70年代初以限制内幕交易和金融中介机构内部中国墙的形式出现的现代证券市场信息流监管。有人认为,这些监管的发展可以追溯到纽约证券交易所和其他国家证券交易所的固定经纪佣金制度的消亡,以及经纪人相应地使用内幕信息作为竞争经纪收入的手段。事实上,导致内幕交易监管和“中国墙”创建的SEC的整体执行计划,受到固定经纪佣金制度的存在以及对金融机构在公司董事会中代表性的相关担忧的强烈影响。本文还考察了英国和日本固定经纪佣金制度的演变,并认为这种价格控制强烈影响了这些国家的内幕交易行为和信息流监管的出现。
{"title":"Insider Trading, Chinese Walls, and Brokerage Commissions: The Origins of Modern Regulation of Information Flows in Securities Markets","authors":"S. Dolgopolov","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.897180","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.897180","url":null,"abstract":"This Article examines the emergence of modern regulation of information flows in securities markets in the form of restrictions on insider trading and Chinese Walls within financial intermediaries during the 1960s and early 1970s. It is argued that these regulatory developments can be traced to the demise of the fixed brokerage commissions regime on the New York Stock Exchange and other national securities exchanges and the corresponding use of inside information by brokers as a means of competing for brokerage revenues. In fact, the overall enforcement program of the SEC, which led to insider trading regulation and the creation of Chinese Walls, was strongly influenced by the existence of the fixed brokerage commissions regime and the related concern about the representation of financial institutions on corporate boards. This Article also examines the evolution of the fixed brokerage commissions regimes in the United Kingdom and Japan and argues that such price controls strongly influenced insider trading practices and the emergence of the regulation of information flows in these countries.","PeriodicalId":336554,"journal":{"name":"Corporate Law: Securities Law","volume":"1 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2006-04-17","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"131213390","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 3
Why is the U.S. Treasury Contemplating Becoming a Lender of Last Resort for Treasury Securities? 为什么美国财政部正在考虑成为美国国债的最后贷款人?
Pub Date : 2006-04-01 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.829004
K. Garbade, J. Kambhu
The U.S. Treasury announced in August 2005 that it is exploring whether to provide a backstop securities lending facility for U.S. Treasury securities. This paper examines the conceptual basis for such a facility by analogizing the market for borrowing and lending Treasury securities with the market for borrowing and lending money prior to the founding of the Federal Reserve System in 1914. An inelastic supply of currency in the nineteenth century led to periodic suspensions of convertibility of bank deposits; Congress authorized a system of Federal Reserve Banks to address the problem. A similarly inelastic supply of Treasury securities has led to several recent episodes of chronic settlement fails. A backstop lending facility would mitigate the fails problem by allowing the Treasury to act as a lender of last resort of Treasury securities during periods of unusual market stress.
美国财政部于2005年8月宣布,正在研究是否为美国国债提供担保证券借贷便利。本文通过将国债的借贷市场与1914年联邦储备系统建立之前的借贷市场进行类比,考察了这种工具的概念基础。19世纪缺乏弹性的货币供应导致银行存款的可兑换性定期暂停;国会授权联邦储备银行系统来解决这个问题。同样缺乏弹性的国债供应导致了最近几次长期结算失败。担保贷款安排将允许财政部在市场异常紧张时期充当国债的最后贷款人,从而缓解破产问题。
{"title":"Why is the U.S. Treasury Contemplating Becoming a Lender of Last Resort for Treasury Securities?","authors":"K. Garbade, J. Kambhu","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.829004","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.829004","url":null,"abstract":"The U.S. Treasury announced in August 2005 that it is exploring whether to provide a backstop securities lending facility for U.S. Treasury securities. This paper examines the conceptual basis for such a facility by analogizing the market for borrowing and lending Treasury securities with the market for borrowing and lending money prior to the founding of the Federal Reserve System in 1914. An inelastic supply of currency in the nineteenth century led to periodic suspensions of convertibility of bank deposits; Congress authorized a system of Federal Reserve Banks to address the problem. A similarly inelastic supply of Treasury securities has led to several recent episodes of chronic settlement fails. A backstop lending facility would mitigate the fails problem by allowing the Treasury to act as a lender of last resort of Treasury securities during periods of unusual market stress.","PeriodicalId":336554,"journal":{"name":"Corporate Law: Securities Law","volume":"9 4 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2006-04-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"116777033","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Mandatory vs. Contractual Disclosure in Securities Markets: Evidence from the 1930s 证券市场的强制性披露与契约性披露:来自20世纪30年代的证据
Pub Date : 2006-02-01 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.883706
P. Mahoney, J. Mei
This paper studies mandatory disclosure documents filed during the period 1933-35 in response to the Securities Act of 1933 and the Securities Exchange Act of 1934. Our sample companies are all listed on the New York Stock Exchange (NYSE) and therefore subject to the NYSE’s disclosure requirements at the time of the regulatory filings. We ask whether the additional disclosures contained in the filed documents constitute information. Using newly-available daily price, volume, and bid and ask quotation data, we test whether the filings are associated with changes in bid-ask spreads, return autocovariance, turnover, volatility, or no-trade days. We find almost no evidence that the new disclosures required by the securities laws—principally having to do with management compensation and large shareholdings—reduced informational asymmetry. We also find no evidence that earnings reports were more informative after enactment of the securities laws.
本文研究1933-35年间根据1933年《证券法》和1934年《证券交易法》提交的强制性披露文件。我们的样本公司都在纽约证券交易所(NYSE)上市,因此在提交监管文件时要遵守纽约证券交易所的披露要求。我们询问提交的文件中包含的额外披露是否构成信息。使用最新的每日价格、成交量和买卖报价数据,我们测试这些文件是否与买卖价差、回报自协方差、周转率、波动性或无交易日的变化有关。我们发现几乎没有证据表明证券法要求的新披露——主要是与管理层薪酬和大股东有关——减少了信息不对称。我们也没有发现证据表明,在证券法颁布后,收益报告的信息更丰富。
{"title":"Mandatory vs. Contractual Disclosure in Securities Markets: Evidence from the 1930s","authors":"P. Mahoney, J. Mei","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.883706","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.883706","url":null,"abstract":"This paper studies mandatory disclosure documents filed during the period 1933-35 in response to the Securities Act of 1933 and the Securities Exchange Act of 1934. Our sample companies are all listed on the New York Stock Exchange (NYSE) and therefore subject to the NYSE’s disclosure requirements at the time of the regulatory filings. We ask whether the additional disclosures contained in the filed documents constitute information. Using newly-available daily price, volume, and bid and ask quotation data, we test whether the filings are associated with changes in bid-ask spreads, return autocovariance, turnover, volatility, or no-trade days. We find almost no evidence that the new disclosures required by the securities laws—principally having to do with management compensation and large shareholdings—reduced informational asymmetry. We also find no evidence that earnings reports were more informative after enactment of the securities laws.","PeriodicalId":336554,"journal":{"name":"Corporate Law: Securities Law","volume":"42 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2006-02-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"127657037","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 31
Doctrinal Path Dependence and Functional Convergence: The Case of Investment Securities 理论路径依赖与功能收敛:以投资证券为例
Pub Date : 2006-01-31 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.880110
Eva Micheler
Globalisation has significant effect on the way business is done in most countries. The need to compete on an international level causes companies to adjust their business practice to whatever they believe to be the most promising strategy for succeeding in a global world economy. Globalisation has not only affected the markets for goods and services, but also financial markets. Companies seek to satisfy their need for capital by marketing their securities in more than one jurisdiction. At the same time, investors seek to diversify their portfolios by buying securities in foreign companies. Financial markets have become global markets. This development is subject of an academic debate in the field of comparative law which will be analysed in this paper. One of the current discussion topics in the field is whether, with globalising economies, legal systems converge. The focus of this discussion is corporate governance. The central focus of the debate is whether the economic forces driving globalisation or other forces such as politics or culture are more influential in shaping the future of corporate law. Notwithstanding the differences in view on the influence of these respective factors, the scholarship examined in this paper views the law is as a variable that is a function of respective other non-legal driving forces and that can be changed to any desirable degree. This paper challenges this underlying assumption. It argues that legal development is not simply a function of external forces. Legal development and law reform are to a significant degree determined by the doctrinal framework that is in place in a particular legal system. To be sure, the paper does not put forward the view that the law is independent of external forces. It nevertheless argues that legal doctrine shapes the content of future legal development. The paper also argues that legal doctrine determines what type of market infrastructure emerges in a particular legal system. The thesis of this paper will be illustrated by a case study relating to the law of investment securities. The law of investment securities has been chosen for such a case study because it has, in recent years, been subject to pressure for convergence perhaps an even larger extent than the corporate governance rules. Notwithstanding this, the convergence/path dependence debate has so far neglected this branch of corporate law. This paper attempts to fill this gap. The thesis put forward in this paper will be illustrated by a case study analysing the law relating to investment securities. The findings in the case study point to a general obstacle to the convergence of laws that affects not only the law of investment securities but corporate law in general. The paper concludes that convergence is nevertheless possible but only consistently with incumbent legal doctrine. Because legal systems are restricted by legal doctrine, they can only converge on a functional level.
全球化对大多数国家的商业运作方式产生了重大影响。在国际层面上竞争的需要导致公司调整他们的商业实践,以适应他们认为最有希望在全球经济中取得成功的战略。全球化不仅影响了商品和服务市场,也影响了金融市场。公司寻求通过在多个司法管辖区销售其证券来满足其对资金的需求。与此同时,投资者寻求通过购买外国公司的证券来分散投资组合。金融市场已经成为全球市场。这一发展是比较法领域一场学术辩论的主题,本文将对此进行分析。该领域当前讨论的话题之一是,随着经济全球化,法律体系是否会趋同。本次讨论的重点是公司治理。这场辩论的中心焦点是,推动全球化的经济力量,还是政治或文化等其他力量,在塑造公司法的未来方面更有影响力。尽管对这些各自因素的影响有不同的看法,但本文所考察的学术观点认为,法律是一个变量,是各自其他非法律驱动力的函数,可以在任何理想程度上进行改变。本文对这一基本假设提出了挑战。它认为,法律的发展不仅仅是外部力量的作用。法律发展和法律改革在很大程度上取决于某一特定法律制度的理论框架。可以肯定的是,本文并没有提出法律不受外力影响的观点。然而,它认为,法律学说塑造了未来法律发展的内容。本文还认为,法律原则决定了在特定的法律制度中出现何种类型的市场基础设施。本文将通过一个与投资证券法有关的案例来说明本文的主题。之所以选择投资证券法作为这样一个案例研究,是因为近年来,该法律受到趋同的压力,其程度可能比公司治理规则更大。尽管如此,到目前为止,关于趋同/路径依赖的争论忽视了公司法的这一分支。本文试图填补这一空白。本文将通过对投资证券相关法律的案例分析来阐述本文的观点。案例研究的结果指出了法律趋同的普遍障碍,这种障碍不仅影响投资证券法,而且影响一般公司法。本文的结论是,趋同仍然是可能的,但只有与现任法律原则一致。由于法律制度受到法律学说的限制,它们只能在功能层面上趋同。
{"title":"Doctrinal Path Dependence and Functional Convergence: The Case of Investment Securities","authors":"Eva Micheler","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.880110","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.880110","url":null,"abstract":"Globalisation has significant effect on the way business is done in most countries. The need to compete on an international level causes companies to adjust their business practice to whatever they believe to be the most promising strategy for succeeding in a global world economy. Globalisation has not only affected the markets for goods and services, but also financial markets. Companies seek to satisfy their need for capital by marketing their securities in more than one jurisdiction. At the same time, investors seek to diversify their portfolios by buying securities in foreign companies. Financial markets have become global markets. This development is subject of an academic debate in the field of comparative law which will be analysed in this paper. One of the current discussion topics in the field is whether, with globalising economies, legal systems converge. The focus of this discussion is corporate governance. The central focus of the debate is whether the economic forces driving globalisation or other forces such as politics or culture are more influential in shaping the future of corporate law. Notwithstanding the differences in view on the influence of these respective factors, the scholarship examined in this paper views the law is as a variable that is a function of respective other non-legal driving forces and that can be changed to any desirable degree. This paper challenges this underlying assumption. It argues that legal development is not simply a function of external forces. Legal development and law reform are to a significant degree determined by the doctrinal framework that is in place in a particular legal system. To be sure, the paper does not put forward the view that the law is independent of external forces. It nevertheless argues that legal doctrine shapes the content of future legal development. The paper also argues that legal doctrine determines what type of market infrastructure emerges in a particular legal system. The thesis of this paper will be illustrated by a case study relating to the law of investment securities. The law of investment securities has been chosen for such a case study because it has, in recent years, been subject to pressure for convergence perhaps an even larger extent than the corporate governance rules. Notwithstanding this, the convergence/path dependence debate has so far neglected this branch of corporate law. This paper attempts to fill this gap. The thesis put forward in this paper will be illustrated by a case study analysing the law relating to investment securities. The findings in the case study point to a general obstacle to the convergence of laws that affects not only the law of investment securities but corporate law in general. The paper concludes that convergence is nevertheless possible but only consistently with incumbent legal doctrine. Because legal systems are restricted by legal doctrine, they can only converge on a functional level.","PeriodicalId":336554,"journal":{"name":"Corporate Law: Securities Law","volume":"65 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2006-01-31","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"121362744","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2
A Note on Economic Theories of the Firm 企业经济理论述评
Pub Date : 2006-01-01 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.880435
Amitai Aviram
This note is designed to explain basic concepts of the economic theory of the firm to students who have no background in economics. It does not purport to cover all or even most of the scholarship in the field, nor does it aim to provide new insights into the theory of the firm. I find this note to be a useful teaching tool in introductory organizational law courses. The note is copied from: Amitai Aviram, Unincorporated Business Entities: Course Material.
本笔记旨在向没有经济学背景的学生解释企业经济理论的基本概念。它并不打算涵盖该领域的全部甚至大部分学术研究,也不打算为企业理论提供新的见解。我发现这篇笔记在组织法入门课程中是一个有用的教学工具。该说明摘自:Amitai Aviram,非法人商业实体:课程材料。
{"title":"A Note on Economic Theories of the Firm","authors":"Amitai Aviram","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.880435","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.880435","url":null,"abstract":"This note is designed to explain basic concepts of the economic theory of the firm to students who have no background in economics. It does not purport to cover all or even most of the scholarship in the field, nor does it aim to provide new insights into the theory of the firm. I find this note to be a useful teaching tool in introductory organizational law courses. The note is copied from: Amitai Aviram, Unincorporated Business Entities: Course Material.","PeriodicalId":336554,"journal":{"name":"Corporate Law: Securities Law","volume":"272 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2006-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"131610307","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2
New IFRS, Half-Way Up to 'The' Profit Formula(R) 新国际财务报告准则:利润公式(R)的一半
Pub Date : 2005-11-16 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.721630
Jan F. Jacobs
The new IFRS (International Financial Reporting Standards) acknowledge value differences in some instances but not in all cases. Moreover, for instance under regulation IAS 16, fundamental mistakes are still allowed or even prescribed, contradictory to logic. It is never correct to enter direct mutations onto the balance sheet regardless of the profit and loss account.A new equation is available within which the balance sheet, the profit and loss account, and the statement of source and use of funds remain inter-related. The apparent antithesis between nominalism and substantialism has been bridged over. The Profit Formula(R), this basic equation of profit measurement, includes each and every capital maintenance concept and does not exclude a single concept of value. According to all reasonable profit definitions, anybody can measure profit over a randomly chosen period, of any length - quickly and easily. The Profit Formula(R) is exceptionally user-friendly. Working with this profit meter is straightforward and relatively simple. Counting and calculating are reduced to an absolute minimum via a direct way to the outcome. A tremendous amount of money can be saved with regard to administration and fringe costs, including for cases of pure nominalism (measuring fiscal profit).
新的国际财务报告准则承认在某些情况下存在价值差异,但并非在所有情况下都存在价值差异。此外,例如,根据国际会计准则第16号,基本错误仍然是允许的,甚至是规定的,与逻辑相矛盾。无论损益帐如何,在资产负债表上输入直接变化都是不正确的。一个新的等式是可用的,在这个等式中,资产负债表、损益表和资金来源和使用表保持相互关联。唯名论和实体论之间明显的对立已被消除。利润公式(R)是衡量利润的基本方程,它包括每一个资本维持概念,并不排除任何一个价值概念。根据所有合理的利润定义,任何人都可以在随机选择的任意长度的时间段内快速、轻松地衡量利润。利润公式(R)是非常友好的。使用这个利润表是直接和相对简单的。计数和计算通过直接的方式减少到绝对的最低限度。在行政管理和附带成本方面,包括纯粹唯名论(衡量财政利润)的情况下,可以节省大量资金。
{"title":"New IFRS, Half-Way Up to 'The' Profit Formula(R)","authors":"Jan F. Jacobs","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.721630","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.721630","url":null,"abstract":"The new IFRS (International Financial Reporting Standards) acknowledge value differences in some instances but not in all cases. Moreover, for instance under regulation IAS 16, fundamental mistakes are still allowed or even prescribed, contradictory to logic. It is never correct to enter direct mutations onto the balance sheet regardless of the profit and loss account.A new equation is available within which the balance sheet, the profit and loss account, and the statement of source and use of funds remain inter-related. The apparent antithesis between nominalism and substantialism has been bridged over. The Profit Formula(R), this basic equation of profit measurement, includes each and every capital maintenance concept and does not exclude a single concept of value. According to all reasonable profit definitions, anybody can measure profit over a randomly chosen period, of any length - quickly and easily. The Profit Formula(R) is exceptionally user-friendly. Working with this profit meter is straightforward and relatively simple. Counting and calculating are reduced to an absolute minimum via a direct way to the outcome. A tremendous amount of money can be saved with regard to administration and fringe costs, including for cases of pure nominalism (measuring fiscal profit).","PeriodicalId":336554,"journal":{"name":"Corporate Law: Securities Law","volume":"58 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2005-11-16","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"128425959","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Behavioral Economics and the Regulation of Public Offerings 行为经济学与上市监管
Pub Date : 2005-11-01 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.849585
Stephen Choi
The SEC adopted new rules in 2005 governing registered public offerings in the United States. Few, if any, of the rules make sense if we start from a presumption that investors are rational and are able to discount properly for any information they receive during the public offering process. In this Article, I examine the new rules and assess the implicit behavioral assumptions about investors contained in the rules. I also provide an assessment of the behavioral biases that may affect regulators at the SEC. Regulator biases may lead the SEC to take an ad hoc evaluative process often ending with a reference to investor confidence in justifying new regulations. As a minimal solution, I propose that the SEC bear the burden of specifying its assumptions behind investor behavior explicitly together with how regulations will benefit investors suffering from such biases (as well as how other investors are affected by the regulations). Taking such an approach will lead to a more consistent approach in how the SEC deals with investor biases and reduce unnecessary regulation (as opposed to the SEC's present ad hoc approach as typified in the public offering rules). To the extent other more public choice factors motivate regulation and references to investor confidence are merely a pretext, my proposal would help bring transparency to these other factors by focusing attention on whether the investor confidence rationale in fact is justified.
美国证券交易委员会于2005年通过了管理美国注册公开募股的新规定。如果我们假设投资者是理性的,能够对他们在公开发行过程中收到的任何信息进行适当的贴现,那么这些规则几乎没有意义。在本文中,我研究了新规则,并评估了规则中包含的关于投资者的隐性行为假设。我还对可能影响美国证券交易委员会监管者的行为偏见进行了评估。监管者的偏见可能导致美国证券交易委员会采取一种特别的评估过程,通常以投资者信心为依据来证明新法规的合理性。作为一个最小的解决方案,我建议SEC承担责任,明确说明其投资者行为背后的假设,以及监管将如何使遭受此类偏见的投资者受益(以及其他投资者如何受到监管的影响)。采取这种方法将导致SEC在如何处理投资者偏见和减少不必要的监管方面采取更一致的方法(而不是SEC目前在公开发行规则中典型的临时方法)。在某种程度上,其他更多的公共选择因素激发了监管,而投资者信心的提及仅仅是一个借口,我的提议将通过将注意力集中在投资者信心的理由实际上是否合理上,有助于提高这些其他因素的透明度。
{"title":"Behavioral Economics and the Regulation of Public Offerings","authors":"Stephen Choi","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.849585","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.849585","url":null,"abstract":"The SEC adopted new rules in 2005 governing registered public offerings in the United States. Few, if any, of the rules make sense if we start from a presumption that investors are rational and are able to discount properly for any information they receive during the public offering process. In this Article, I examine the new rules and assess the implicit behavioral assumptions about investors contained in the rules. I also provide an assessment of the behavioral biases that may affect regulators at the SEC. Regulator biases may lead the SEC to take an ad hoc evaluative process often ending with a reference to investor confidence in justifying new regulations. As a minimal solution, I propose that the SEC bear the burden of specifying its assumptions behind investor behavior explicitly together with how regulations will benefit investors suffering from such biases (as well as how other investors are affected by the regulations). Taking such an approach will lead to a more consistent approach in how the SEC deals with investor biases and reduce unnecessary regulation (as opposed to the SEC's present ad hoc approach as typified in the public offering rules). To the extent other more public choice factors motivate regulation and references to investor confidence are merely a pretext, my proposal would help bring transparency to these other factors by focusing attention on whether the investor confidence rationale in fact is justified.","PeriodicalId":336554,"journal":{"name":"Corporate Law: Securities Law","volume":"56 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2005-11-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"121856572","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 9
Deficits and Debt in the Short and Long Run 短期和长期的赤字和债务
Pub Date : 2005-10-01 DOI: 10.3386/W11630
B. Friedman
This paper begins by examining the persistence of movements in the U.S. Government%u2019s budget posture. Deficits display considerable persistence, and debt levels (relative to GDP) even more so. Further, the degree of persistence depends on what gives rise to budget deficits in the first place. Deficits resulting from shocks to defense spending exhibit the greatest persistence and those from shocks to nondefense spending the least; deficits resulting from shocks to revenues fall in the middle. The paper next reviews recent evidence on the impact of changes in government debt levels (again, relative to GDP) on interest rates. The recent literature, focusing on expected future debt levels and expected real interest rates, indicates impacts that are large in the context of actual movements in debt levels: for example, an increase of 94 basis points due to the rise in the debt-to-GDP ratio during 1981-93, and a decline of 65 basis point due to the decline in the debt-to-GDP ratio during 1993-2001. The paper next asks why deficits would exhibit the observed negative correlation with key elements of investment. One answer, following the analysis presented earlier, is that deficits are persistent and therefore lead to changes in expected future debt levels, which in turn affect real interest rates. A different reason, however, revolves around the need for markets to absorb the increased issuance of Government securities in a setting of costly portfolio adjustment. The paper concludes with some reflections on %u201Cthe Perverse Corollary of Stein%u2019s Law%u201D: that is, the view that in the presence of large government deficits nothing need be done because something will be done.
本文首先考察了美国政府2019年预算态势的持续变化。赤字显示出相当大的持久性,债务水平(相对于GDP)更是如此。此外,持续的程度首先取决于导致预算赤字的原因。国防开支冲击导致的赤字表现出最大的持久性,而非国防开支冲击造成的赤字表现出最少的持久性;由收入冲击造成的赤字落在中间。接下来,论文回顾了最近关于政府债务水平(同样是相对于GDP)变化对利率影响的证据。最近的文献着重于预期的未来债务水平和预期的实际利率,表明在债务水平实际变动的背景下影响很大:例如,1981- 1993年期间,由于债务与国内生产总值比率的上升,增加了94个基点,1993-2001年期间由于债务与国内生产总值比率的下降,下降了65个基点。接下来,论文提出了为什么赤字会与投资的关键要素呈现出观察到的负相关。根据前面的分析,一个答案是赤字是持续存在的,因此会导致预期未来债务水平的变化,进而影响实际利率。然而,另一个不同的理由是,市场需要在代价高昂的投资组合调整的情况下吸收政府证券发行的增加。本文最后对斯坦因定律的反常推论(reverse Corollary of Stein’s Law)进行了一些反思:即认为在存在巨额政府赤字的情况下,不需要做任何事情,因为会做一些事情。
{"title":"Deficits and Debt in the Short and Long Run","authors":"B. Friedman","doi":"10.3386/W11630","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.3386/W11630","url":null,"abstract":"This paper begins by examining the persistence of movements in the U.S. Government%u2019s budget posture. Deficits display considerable persistence, and debt levels (relative to GDP) even more so. Further, the degree of persistence depends on what gives rise to budget deficits in the first place. Deficits resulting from shocks to defense spending exhibit the greatest persistence and those from shocks to nondefense spending the least; deficits resulting from shocks to revenues fall in the middle. The paper next reviews recent evidence on the impact of changes in government debt levels (again, relative to GDP) on interest rates. The recent literature, focusing on expected future debt levels and expected real interest rates, indicates impacts that are large in the context of actual movements in debt levels: for example, an increase of 94 basis points due to the rise in the debt-to-GDP ratio during 1981-93, and a decline of 65 basis point due to the decline in the debt-to-GDP ratio during 1993-2001. The paper next asks why deficits would exhibit the observed negative correlation with key elements of investment. One answer, following the analysis presented earlier, is that deficits are persistent and therefore lead to changes in expected future debt levels, which in turn affect real interest rates. A different reason, however, revolves around the need for markets to absorb the increased issuance of Government securities in a setting of costly portfolio adjustment. The paper concludes with some reflections on %u201Cthe Perverse Corollary of Stein%u2019s Law%u201D: that is, the view that in the presence of large government deficits nothing need be done because something will be done.","PeriodicalId":336554,"journal":{"name":"Corporate Law: Securities Law","volume":"15 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2005-10-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"126790239","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 42
期刊
Corporate Law: Securities Law
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1