首页 > 最新文献

FEN: Differences in Taxation & Corporate Finance (Topic)最新文献

英文 中文
How Does the U.S. Taxation of Foreign Earnings Affect Internal Capital Markets: Evidence from TIPRA 2005 美国对外收入征税如何影响国内资本市场:来自TIPRA 2005的证据
Pub Date : 2017-11-08 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3084075
Frank Murphy
I use the passage of the Tax Increase Prevention and Reconciliation Act of 2005 (TIPRA), which alters the after-tax considerations of foreign internal capital markets, as a quasi-natural experimental setting to test whether a reduction in the tax costs associated with moving foreign capital increased firms’ use of holding companies. In separate tests using Compustat and IRS data, I document that firms increase holding company use after TIPRA. Furthermore, I find that firms with the greatest increases in holding companies also increase their post-TIPRA foreign sales and generate more persistent foreign earnings. I interpret these findings to suggest that TIPRA is associated with increased global competitiveness for firms that actively modify their organizational structures. In additional analysis, I attribute this increased global competitiveness to maintained liquidity and capital investments during a financial crisis, relative to firms that do not respond as strongly to tax incentives to utilize holding companies.
我使用2005年税收增加预防和协调法案(TIPRA)的通过,该法案改变了外国内部资本市场的税后考虑,作为准自然实验设置,以测试与转移外国资本相关的税收成本降低是否增加了公司对控股公司的使用。在使用Compustat和IRS数据的单独测试中,我记录了公司在TIPRA之后增加了控股公司的使用。此外,我发现控股公司增加最多的公司也增加了tipra后的国外销售,并产生了更持久的国外收益。我对这些发现的解释是,对于积极调整组织结构的公司来说,TIPRA与全球竞争力的提高有关。在进一步的分析中,我将这种全球竞争力的提高归因于金融危机期间保持的流动性和资本投资,相对于那些对利用控股公司的税收优惠反应不那么强烈的公司而言。
{"title":"How Does the U.S. Taxation of Foreign Earnings Affect Internal Capital Markets: Evidence from TIPRA 2005","authors":"Frank Murphy","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3084075","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3084075","url":null,"abstract":"I use the passage of the Tax Increase Prevention and Reconciliation Act of 2005 (TIPRA), which alters the after-tax considerations of foreign internal capital markets, as a quasi-natural experimental setting to test whether a reduction in the tax costs associated with moving foreign capital increased firms’ use of holding companies. In separate tests using Compustat and IRS data, I document that firms increase holding company use after TIPRA. Furthermore, I find that firms with the greatest increases in holding companies also increase their post-TIPRA foreign sales and generate more persistent foreign earnings. I interpret these findings to suggest that TIPRA is associated with increased global competitiveness for firms that actively modify their organizational structures. In additional analysis, I attribute this increased global competitiveness to maintained liquidity and capital investments during a financial crisis, relative to firms that do not respond as strongly to tax incentives to utilize holding companies.","PeriodicalId":385233,"journal":{"name":"FEN: Differences in Taxation & Corporate Finance (Topic)","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2017-11-08","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"116207354","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2
Heterogeneity in Tax Rate Elasticities of Capital: Evidence from Local Business Tax Reforms 资本税率弹性的异质性:来自地方营业税改革的证据
Pub Date : 2017-03-24 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.2940271
I. Bethmann
This study examines heterogeneity in tax rate elasticities of corporate capital using staggered variation in local business tax rates of German municipalities. The results suggest an average long-run capital decline of 0.97% after a 1% increase in the tax rate. In line with prior literature that suggests higher investment-cash flow sensitivities of firms with financing constraints tax rate elasticities are up to half times larger for financially constrained firms than for unconstrained firms. Moreover, capital responses are about half times larger for firms with fewer tax avoidance possibilities. Finally, this study contributes to the literature on tax incidence. I find a weaker relation between taxes and capital for firms that are less likely to bear the economic burden of the tax because they shift the tax incidence to their stakeholders.
本研究利用德国市政当局地方营业税税率的交错变化来检验企业资本税率弹性的异质性。结果表明,税率每提高1%,长期资本平均下降0.97%。与先前的文献一致,这些文献表明,有融资约束的公司的投资现金流敏感性更高,有融资约束的公司的税率弹性比没有融资约束的公司大一半。此外,对于避税可能性较小的公司,资本反应大约是前者的一半。最后,本研究对税收发生率的文献有所贡献。我发现,对于那些不太可能承担税收经济负担的公司来说,税收和资本之间的关系较弱,因为它们将税收发生率转移给了利益相关者。
{"title":"Heterogeneity in Tax Rate Elasticities of Capital: Evidence from Local Business Tax Reforms","authors":"I. Bethmann","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.2940271","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2940271","url":null,"abstract":"This study examines heterogeneity in tax rate elasticities of corporate capital using staggered variation in local business tax rates of German municipalities. The results suggest an average long-run capital decline of 0.97% after a 1% increase in the tax rate. In line with prior literature that suggests higher investment-cash flow sensitivities of firms with financing constraints tax rate elasticities are up to half times larger for financially constrained firms than for unconstrained firms. Moreover, capital responses are about half times larger for firms with fewer tax avoidance possibilities. Finally, this study contributes to the literature on tax incidence. I find a weaker relation between taxes and capital for firms that are less likely to bear the economic burden of the tax because they shift the tax incidence to their stakeholders.","PeriodicalId":385233,"journal":{"name":"FEN: Differences in Taxation & Corporate Finance (Topic)","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2017-03-24","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"134225322","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Do Multinational Enterprises Exploit a Window of Opportunity? An Empirical Analysis of Profit Shifting in the Absence of Restrictions 跨国企业是否利用了机会之窗?无约束条件下利润转移的实证分析
Pub Date : 2017-02-01 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3165968
Carolin Holzmann, Christoph Wunder
This paper investigates multinational enterprises’ (MNEs) response to a unique window of opportunity for temporarily unrestricted profit shifting. The window unexpectedly opened because of a ruling by the European Court of Justice in 2006 that suspended the application of controlled foreign corporation (CFC) rules within the European Economic Area. It closed with a subsequent piece of anti-shifting legislation on thin capitalization in 2007. We identify causal effects of the suspension of the CFC rules on profit shifting by exploiting random variation in the size of MNEs’ windows that results from variation in the business year starting dates across MNEs. Using detailed balance sheet information on internal debt shifting between foreign low tax subsidiaries and their parents, we find that MNEs’ response to the window of opportunity is remarkably moderate in terms of both the probability and the volume of internal lending. On the one hand, this results from substantial short-term rigidities: internal lending increases with window size. On the other hand, MNEs in general responded with a fair amount of reserve which is indicated by low total levels of internal lending throughout the window. Presumably, this is caused by legal uncertainty about the scope of internal debt shifting that would be accepted by tax offices.
本文研究了跨国企业对暂时不受限制的利润转移的独特机会之窗的反应。2006年,欧洲法院(European Court of Justice)暂停了在欧洲经济区(European Economic Area)实施受控外国公司(CFC)规则的裁决,出人意料地打开了这扇窗口。2007年,它又通过了一项针对资本不足的反转移立法。我们通过利用跨国公司营业年度开始日期变化导致的跨国公司窗口大小的随机变化,确定暂停CFC规则对利润转移的因果影响。利用关于外国低税子公司与其母公司之间内部债务转移的详细资产负债表信息,我们发现跨国公司对机会之窗的反应在内部贷款的概率和数量方面都非常温和。一方面,这是由于大量的短期刚性:内部贷款随着窗口规模的扩大而增加。另一方面,跨国公司一般都有相当数量的储备,这从整个窗口期内的内部贷款总额较低可以看出。据推测,这是由于税务部门可以接受的内部债务转移范围的法律不确定性造成的。
{"title":"Do Multinational Enterprises Exploit a Window of Opportunity? An Empirical Analysis of Profit Shifting in the Absence of Restrictions","authors":"Carolin Holzmann, Christoph Wunder","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3165968","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3165968","url":null,"abstract":"This paper investigates multinational enterprises’ (MNEs) response to a unique window of opportunity for temporarily unrestricted profit shifting. The window unexpectedly opened because of a ruling by the European Court of Justice in 2006 that suspended the application of controlled foreign corporation (CFC) rules within the European Economic Area. It closed with a subsequent piece of anti-shifting legislation on thin capitalization in 2007. We identify causal effects of the suspension of the CFC rules on profit shifting by exploiting random variation in the size of MNEs’ windows that results from variation in the business year starting dates across MNEs. Using detailed balance sheet information on internal debt shifting between foreign low tax subsidiaries and their parents, we find that MNEs’ response to the window of opportunity is remarkably moderate in terms of both the probability and the volume of internal lending. On the one hand, this results from substantial short-term rigidities: internal lending increases with window size. On the other hand, MNEs in general responded with a fair amount of reserve which is indicated by low total levels of internal lending throughout the window. Presumably, this is caused by legal uncertainty about the scope of internal debt shifting that would be accepted by tax offices.","PeriodicalId":385233,"journal":{"name":"FEN: Differences in Taxation & Corporate Finance (Topic)","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2017-02-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"129131737","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
The Corporate Income Tax in Canada: Does Its Past Foretell Its Future? 加拿大的企业所得税:过去预示未来吗?
Pub Date : 2016-12-13 DOI: 10.11575/SPPP.V9I0.42611
R. Bird, T. Wilson
Corporate tax reform has long been a contentious issue in Canada. Official commissions, academics and others have often proposed changes in the way we tax corporations. During the last 30 years, perhaps largely owing to concerns about international competitiveness, the corporate tax rate has been substantially reduced. Since revenues did not decline as a result, those concerned by increased inequality who believe that corporate taxes are paid mainly by the rich have suggested that corporate rates should be increased. Others, more persuaded by the increasing evidence that much of the burden of the corporate tax ultimately falls on workers and wages and that even to the extent it falls on capital the economic price paid in terms of reduced output and productivity for each corporate tax dollar collected is high have taken the opposite tack and argued that, if anything, corporate tax reform should be aimed at reducing even further the effective tax rate on corporate capital. Both the technical and the political aspects of corporate taxation are thus at play in the current discussion of possible corporate tax reform. After a brief review of the history, we consider what is now known about the relation between corporate rates and revenue, the surprisingly complex question of who ultimately pays the tax, and the largely undesirable economic effects of corporate income taxes. If all voters were economists and familiar with the evidence, it is unlikely any would favour big increases in corporate taxes. However, even economists who have read all the studies mentioned here (and more) do not agree about the best way to reform the corporate income tax. We sketch three recent major reform proposals Canadian experts have recently put forward (1) replace the existing corporate tax by a tax on ‘rents’ (above-normal returns on capital), (2) replace both it and the current personal income tax by a ‘dual income tax’ with a flat rate on all capital income (corporate and personal), or (3) adopt a more gradual approach to reform that would broadly keep the present system but make it more uniform in its treatment of investment. On the whole, we suggest that, although the ‘rent’ proposal is clearly the favourite in the academic horse race, and we think a much closer look should be taken at the second (dual income tax), the more incremental third proposal – improve what we now have – is perhaps not only the way we should go now but is also likely to be the politically most acceptable of these schemes. Finally, since one reason corporate tax reform is so difficult is because it is closely related to a number of other issues that are often both technically complex and politically sensitive, we consider several such issues. Some, such as small business taxation, could be reformed independently of the sorts of more general reforms just mentioned. We sketch several reforms that would simplify the system, maintain some incentive for small businesses and reduce the extent to whi
公司税改革在加拿大一直是一个有争议的问题。官方委员会、学者和其他人经常提议改变我们对企业征税的方式。在过去30年里,也许主要是出于对国际竞争力的担忧,公司税率大幅降低。由于收入并没有因此下降,那些担心不平等加剧的人认为公司税主要是由富人支付的,他们建议应该提高公司税。越来越多的证据表明,公司税的大部分负担最终落在了工人和工资身上,而且即使它落在资本身上,每征收一美元公司税所付出的产出和生产率下降的经济代价也很高,而另一些人则更相信这一点,他们采取了相反的策略,认为公司税改革的目标应该是进一步降低公司资本的有效税率。因此,在目前关于可能的公司税改革的讨论中,公司税的技术方面和政治方面都在发挥作用。在简要回顾历史之后,我们将考虑目前已知的企业税率与收入之间的关系、最终由谁纳税这一令人惊讶的复杂问题,以及企业所得税在很大程度上不受欢迎的经济影响。如果所有的选民都是经济学家并且熟悉相关证据,就不太可能有人支持大幅提高公司税。然而,即使是读过这里提到的所有研究(以及更多)的经济学家,也不能就改革企业所得税的最佳方式达成一致。我们概述了加拿大专家最近提出的三个主要改革建议:(1)用“租金”税(高于正常的资本回报率)取代现有的公司税,(2)用“双重所得税”取代现有的公司税和现行的个人所得税,对所有资本收入(企业和个人)征收统一税率,或(3)采取更渐进的改革方法,大致保留现行制度,但使其在对待投资方面更加统一。总的来说,我们认为,尽管“租金”提案显然是学术竞赛中最受欢迎的,而且我们认为应该更仔细地研究第二个(双重所得税),但更多增量的第三个提案-改善我们现在拥有的-可能不仅是我们现在应该走的路,而且可能是这些方案中政治上最可接受的。最后,由于公司税改革如此困难的一个原因是它与许多其他问题密切相关,这些问题往往既在技术上复杂又在政治上敏感,因此我们考虑了几个这样的问题。有些改革,如小企业税收,可以独立于刚才提到的各种更广泛的改革进行改革。我们概述了几项改革,这些改革将简化该体系,保留对小企业的一些激励,并减少当前体系为富人提供庇护的程度。但其他问题不能单独处理。企业所得税和个人所得税之间“整合”的适当水平和性质是什么?联邦和省政府在企业所得税方面的适当作用是什么?而且,假设我们继续使用税收来为特定部门和活动提供优惠(激励),那么最好的方式是什么?在进入税收系统内部运作的“阴暗沼泽”太远的情况下,我们建议在这些领域进行一些可能的改革方向,例如税收优惠的“日落”条款,以减少它们无限期保留的可能性,无论它们是否对社会有用。
{"title":"The Corporate Income Tax in Canada: Does Its Past Foretell Its Future?","authors":"R. Bird, T. Wilson","doi":"10.11575/SPPP.V9I0.42611","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.11575/SPPP.V9I0.42611","url":null,"abstract":"Corporate tax reform has long been a contentious issue in Canada. Official commissions, academics and others have often proposed changes in the way we tax corporations. During the last 30 years, perhaps largely owing to concerns about international competitiveness, the corporate tax rate has been substantially reduced. Since revenues did not decline as a result, those concerned by increased inequality who believe that corporate taxes are paid mainly by the rich have suggested that corporate rates should be increased. Others, more persuaded by the increasing evidence that much of the burden of the corporate tax ultimately falls on workers and wages and that even to the extent it falls on capital the economic price paid in terms of reduced output and productivity for each corporate tax dollar collected is high have taken the opposite tack and argued that, if anything, corporate tax reform should be aimed at reducing even further the effective tax rate on corporate capital. Both the technical and the political aspects of corporate taxation are thus at play in the current discussion of possible corporate tax reform. After a brief review of the history, we consider what is now known about the relation between corporate rates and revenue, the surprisingly complex question of who ultimately pays the tax, and the largely undesirable economic effects of corporate income taxes. If all voters were economists and familiar with the evidence, it is unlikely any would favour big increases in corporate taxes. However, even economists who have read all the studies mentioned here (and more) do not agree about the best way to reform the corporate income tax. We sketch three recent major reform proposals Canadian experts have recently put forward (1) replace the existing corporate tax by a tax on ‘rents’ (above-normal returns on capital), (2) replace both it and the current personal income tax by a ‘dual income tax’ with a flat rate on all capital income (corporate and personal), or (3) adopt a more gradual approach to reform that would broadly keep the present system but make it more uniform in its treatment of investment. On the whole, we suggest that, although the ‘rent’ proposal is clearly the favourite in the academic horse race, and we think a much closer look should be taken at the second (dual income tax), the more incremental third proposal – improve what we now have – is perhaps not only the way we should go now but is also likely to be the politically most acceptable of these schemes. Finally, since one reason corporate tax reform is so difficult is because it is closely related to a number of other issues that are often both technically complex and politically sensitive, we consider several such issues. Some, such as small business taxation, could be reformed independently of the sorts of more general reforms just mentioned. We sketch several reforms that would simplify the system, maintain some incentive for small businesses and reduce the extent to whi","PeriodicalId":385233,"journal":{"name":"FEN: Differences in Taxation & Corporate Finance (Topic)","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2016-12-13","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"123583145","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2
Factual Indeterminacy in International Tax Law 国际税法中的事实不确定性
Pub Date : 2016-11-03 DOI: 10.21684/2412-2343-2016-3-3-73-102
B. Bogenschneider
Legal indeterminacy comes in a variety of forms identified here as: (i) general legal indeterminacy; (ii) factual indeterminacy; and (iii) Mach/Feyerabend factual indeterminacy. The concept of general “legal indeterminacy” refers to problems in legal interpretation and has been extensively studied. “Factual indeterminacy” refers to the indeterminacy of facts as a matter of tax law when derived from separately indeterminate fields of law. “Mach/ Feyerabend factual indeterminacy” refers to fact words as derived from legal theory which provide the content for legal interpretation. The “facts” in tax law are not transcendent to law; in addition, the “fact” words of tax law cannot be simply imported from the field of economics. The incremental question of the origins of theory (as discussed by Karl Popper and Albert Einstein) is also analyzed here. The theory of tax law originates with “sympathy with experience” or “intellectual love” (tr. Einfuhlung) of tax law by lawyers as reflected in the special heuristics and practices of the profession. Legal theory accordingly functions in similar fashion to scientific theory where a particular legal theory can be falsified (qua Popper) or understood in pluralistic terms by incorporating auxiliary ideas.
法律上的不确定性有多种形式,本文将其归纳为:(i)一般法律上的不确定性;(二)事实不确定性;(iii)马赫/费耶阿本德事实不确定性。一般意义上的“法律不确定性”概念涉及法律解释中的问题,已被广泛研究。“事实不确定性”是指当从不确定的法律领域衍生出来时,作为税法问题的事实的不确定性。“马赫/费耶阿本德事实不确定性”是指法理衍生出来的事实词,为法律解释提供内容。税法中的“事实”不超越法律;此外,税法中的“事实”一词不能简单地从经济学领域引进。理论起源的增量问题(如卡尔·波普尔和阿尔伯特·爱因斯坦所讨论的)也在这里进行了分析。税法理论起源于律师对税法的“经验共鸣”或“知性之爱”,反映在该专业的特殊启发和实践中。因此,法律理论以类似于科学理论的方式发挥作用,在科学理论中,特定的法律理论可以通过纳入辅助思想而被证伪(根据波普尔的说法)或以多元化的方式被理解。
{"title":"Factual Indeterminacy in International Tax Law","authors":"B. Bogenschneider","doi":"10.21684/2412-2343-2016-3-3-73-102","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.21684/2412-2343-2016-3-3-73-102","url":null,"abstract":"Legal indeterminacy comes in a variety of forms identified here as: (i) general legal indeterminacy; (ii) factual indeterminacy; and (iii) Mach/Feyerabend factual indeterminacy. The concept of general “legal indeterminacy” refers to problems in legal interpretation and has been extensively studied. “Factual indeterminacy” refers to the indeterminacy of facts as a matter of tax law when derived from separately indeterminate fields of law. “Mach/ Feyerabend factual indeterminacy” refers to fact words as derived from legal theory which provide the content for legal interpretation. The “facts” in tax law are not transcendent to law; in addition, the “fact” words of tax law cannot be simply imported from the field of economics. The incremental question of the origins of theory (as discussed by Karl Popper and Albert Einstein) is also analyzed here. The theory of tax law originates with “sympathy with experience” or “intellectual love” (tr. Einfuhlung) of tax law by lawyers as reflected in the special heuristics and practices of the profession. Legal theory accordingly functions in similar fashion to scientific theory where a particular legal theory can be falsified (qua Popper) or understood in pluralistic terms by incorporating auxiliary ideas.","PeriodicalId":385233,"journal":{"name":"FEN: Differences in Taxation & Corporate Finance (Topic)","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2016-11-03","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"125310735","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Does Capital Tax Uncertainty Delay Irreversible Risky Investment? 资本税的不确定性是否会延迟不可逆转的风险投资?
Pub Date : 2016-08-17 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.2826022
Rainer Niemann, Caren Sureth-Sloane
Tax uncertainty is often claimed to be harmful for investments. Capital taxes, such as property and wealth taxes, are particularly exposed to tax uncertainty. Capital tax uncertainty emerges from expected tax reforms, the unclear outcome of future tax audits, and simplified estimates of capital tax bases in investment models. Uncertain returns on investment as well as stochastic taxation contribute to overall uncertainty and may significantly affect investment decisions. Hitherto, it is unknown how capital tax uncertainty affects investment timing. However, it is well known that both uncertainty and capital tax may be harmful for investment and decelerate investment activities. We are the first to study the investment timing effects of stochastic capital taxes in a real options setting with risky investment opportunities. Our results indicate that even risk neutral investors are sensitive with respect to capital tax risk and may react in a surprising manner to a newly introduced stochastic capital tax. As an apparently paradoxical investment effect, we find that increased capital tax uncertainty can accelerate risky investment if such uncertainty is sufficiently low compared to cash flow uncertainty. In contrast, high capital tax risk delays high-risk innovative investment projects. To reduce unintended consequences of uncertain tax policy, tax legislators and tax authorities should avoid high levels of capital tax uncertainty. Broadening the capital tax base or increasing the capital tax rate induces ambiguous timing effects. Furthermore, high-growth investments are likely to be postponed if they experience a capital tax cut. Since investment reactions upon tax reforms are well-known to affect income and wealth distribution, reliable estimations of the impact of taxes on economic decisions are necessary.
税收的不确定性通常被认为对投资有害。资本税,如财产税和财富税,尤其容易受到税收不确定性的影响。资本税的不确定性来自预期的税收改革、未来税务审计的不明确结果以及投资模型中对资本税基的简化估计。不确定的投资回报以及随机税收导致整体不确定性,并可能显著影响投资决策。迄今为止,尚不清楚资本税的不确定性如何影响投资时机。然而,众所周知,不确定性和资本税都可能对投资有害,并减缓投资活动。我们首次研究了在具有风险投资机会的实物期权环境下随机资本税的投资时机效应。我们的研究结果表明,即使是风险中性的投资者对资本税风险也很敏感,并且可能对新引入的随机资本税做出令人惊讶的反应。作为一种明显矛盾的投资效应,我们发现,如果资本税不确定性与现金流不确定性相比足够低,则增加的资本税不确定性可以加速风险投资。相反,高资本税风险会延迟高风险的创新投资项目。为了减少不确定的税收政策带来的意外后果,税收立法者和税务当局应避免资本税的高度不确定性。扩大资本税基或提高资本税率会产生模糊的时间效应。此外,如果资本税被削减,高增长投资可能会被推迟。由于投资对税收改革的反应众所周知会影响收入和财富分配,因此有必要对税收对经济决策的影响进行可靠的估计。
{"title":"Does Capital Tax Uncertainty Delay Irreversible Risky Investment?","authors":"Rainer Niemann, Caren Sureth-Sloane","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.2826022","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2826022","url":null,"abstract":"Tax uncertainty is often claimed to be harmful for investments. Capital taxes, such as property and wealth taxes, are particularly exposed to tax uncertainty. Capital tax uncertainty emerges from expected tax reforms, the unclear outcome of future tax audits, and simplified estimates of capital tax bases in investment models. Uncertain returns on investment as well as stochastic taxation contribute to overall uncertainty and may significantly affect investment decisions. Hitherto, it is unknown how capital tax uncertainty affects investment timing. However, it is well known that both uncertainty and capital tax may be harmful for investment and decelerate investment activities. We are the first to study the investment timing effects of stochastic capital taxes in a real options setting with risky investment opportunities. Our results indicate that even risk neutral investors are sensitive with respect to capital tax risk and may react in a surprising manner to a newly introduced stochastic capital tax. As an apparently paradoxical investment effect, we find that increased capital tax uncertainty can accelerate risky investment if such uncertainty is sufficiently low compared to cash flow uncertainty. In contrast, high capital tax risk delays high-risk innovative investment projects. To reduce unintended consequences of uncertain tax policy, tax legislators and tax authorities should avoid high levels of capital tax uncertainty. Broadening the capital tax base or increasing the capital tax rate induces ambiguous timing effects. Furthermore, high-growth investments are likely to be postponed if they experience a capital tax cut. Since investment reactions upon tax reforms are well-known to affect income and wealth distribution, reliable estimations of the impact of taxes on economic decisions are necessary.","PeriodicalId":385233,"journal":{"name":"FEN: Differences in Taxation & Corporate Finance (Topic)","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2016-08-17","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"130843846","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 5
International Differences in Accounting Practices under IFRS and the Influence of the USA 国际财务报告准则下会计实务的国际差异及美国的影响
Pub Date : 2016-07-23 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.2813585
I. Lourenço, R. Sarquis, M. C. Branco, Nuno Magro
This paper expands prior IFRS accounting systems’ classifications to a broader set of 27 countries where the IFRS adoption is a widespread practice, plus the United States of America (USA). The results suggest a classification distinguishing between three groups of countries, based on the similarity of their accounting practices: 1) Australia and New Zealand, 2) USA-influenced countries, and 3) South Africa, Oman and European countries. This study contributes to the literature not only by providing evidence of differences in accounting practices to a broader set of countries, but mainly by suggesting an economic explanation to the existence of accounting choices. In particular, the economic proximity to the USA may be an important factor influencing accounting practices in some countries even after the IFRS adoption.
本文将先前的国际财务报告准则会计系统的分类扩展到更广泛的27个国家,其中国际财务报告准则的采用是一种广泛的做法,加上美利坚合众国(美国)。结果表明,根据会计实践的相似性,可以对三组国家进行分类区分:1)澳大利亚和新西兰,2)受美国影响的国家,以及3)南非、阿曼和欧洲国家。本研究不仅通过为更广泛的国家提供会计实践差异的证据,而且主要通过提出对会计选择存在的经济解释,为文献做出了贡献。特别是,即使在采用国际财务报告准则之后,与美国的经济接近可能是影响某些国家会计实践的重要因素。
{"title":"International Differences in Accounting Practices under IFRS and the Influence of the USA","authors":"I. Lourenço, R. Sarquis, M. C. Branco, Nuno Magro","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.2813585","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2813585","url":null,"abstract":"This paper expands prior IFRS accounting systems’ classifications to a broader set of 27 countries where the IFRS adoption is a widespread practice, plus the United States of America (USA). The results suggest a classification distinguishing between three groups of countries, based on the similarity of their accounting practices: 1) Australia and New Zealand, 2) USA-influenced countries, and 3) South Africa, Oman and European countries. This study contributes to the literature not only by providing evidence of differences in accounting practices to a broader set of countries, but mainly by suggesting an economic explanation to the existence of accounting choices. In particular, the economic proximity to the USA may be an important factor influencing accounting practices in some countries even after the IFRS adoption.","PeriodicalId":385233,"journal":{"name":"FEN: Differences in Taxation & Corporate Finance (Topic)","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2016-07-23","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"132803258","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Tax Sparing, FDI, and Foreign Aid: Evidence from Territorial Tax Reforms 税收节约、外国直接投资与对外援助:来自地方税收改革的证据
Pub Date : 2016-04-18 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.2767184
Céline Azémar, Dhammika Dharmapala
The governments of many developing countries seek to attract inbound foreign direct investment (FDI) through the use of tax incentives for multinational corporations (MNCs). The effectiveness of these tax incentives depends crucially on MNCs’ residence country tax regime, especially where the residence country imposes worldwide taxation on foreign income. Tax sparing provisions are included in many bilateral tax treaties to prevent host country tax incentives being nullified by residence country taxation. We analyse the impact of tax sparing provisions using panel data on bilateral FDI stocks from 23 OECD countries in 113 developing and transition economies over the period 2002-2012, coding tax sparing provisions in all bilateral tax treaties among these countries. We find that tax sparing agreements are associated with 30 percent to 123 percent higher FDI. The estimated effect is concentrated in the year that tax sparing comes into force and the subsequent years, with no effects in prior years, and is thus consistent with a causal interpretation. Four countries - Norway in 2004, and the U.K., Japan, and New Zealand in 2009 - enacted tax reforms that moved them from worldwide to territorial taxation, potentially changing the value of their preexisting tax sparing agreements. However, there is no detectable effect of these reforms on bilateral FDI in tax sparing countries, relative to nonsparing countries. These results are consistent with tax sparing being an important determinant of FDI in developing countries for MNCs from both worldwide and territorial home countries. We also find that these territorial reforms are associated with increases in certain forms of bilateral foreign aid from residence countries to sparing countries, relative to nonsparing countries. This suggests that tax sparing and foreign aid may function as substitutes.
许多发展中国家的政府寻求通过对跨国公司(MNCs)使用税收优惠来吸引入境外国直接投资(FDI)。这些税收激励措施的有效性在很大程度上取决于跨国公司居住国的税收制度,特别是居住国对外国收入征收全球税收的情况下。许多双边税收协定中都包括税收节约条款,以防止东道国的税收优惠被居住国的税收取消。我们利用2002年至2012年期间来自113个发展中经济体和转型经济体的23个经合组织国家的双边外国直接投资存量面板数据分析了税收减免条款的影响,并对这些国家之间所有双边税收协定中的税收减免条款进行了编码。我们发现,税收优惠协议与30%至123%的外国直接投资增长有关。估计的影响集中在节税生效的年份和随后的年份,对以前的年份没有影响,因此与因果解释一致。四个国家——2004年的挪威,2009年的英国、日本和新西兰——实施了税收改革,将它们从全球税收转向地域性税收,这可能会改变它们之前存在的税收减免协议的价值。然而,相对于不节约税收的国家,这些改革对税收节约国家的双边外国直接投资没有明显的影响。这些结果与税收节约是发展中国家对来自世界各地和属地母国的跨国公司的外国直接投资的重要决定因素相一致。我们还发现,相对于非保留国家,这些领土改革与居住国向保留国家提供某些形式的双边外援的增加有关。这表明税收减免和外国援助可以作为替代品。
{"title":"Tax Sparing, FDI, and Foreign Aid: Evidence from Territorial Tax Reforms","authors":"Céline Azémar, Dhammika Dharmapala","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.2767184","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2767184","url":null,"abstract":"The governments of many developing countries seek to attract inbound foreign direct investment (FDI) through the use of tax incentives for multinational corporations (MNCs). The effectiveness of these tax incentives depends crucially on MNCs’ residence country tax regime, especially where the residence country imposes worldwide taxation on foreign income. Tax sparing provisions are included in many bilateral tax treaties to prevent host country tax incentives being nullified by residence country taxation. We analyse the impact of tax sparing provisions using panel data on bilateral FDI stocks from 23 OECD countries in 113 developing and transition economies over the period 2002-2012, coding tax sparing provisions in all bilateral tax treaties among these countries. We find that tax sparing agreements are associated with 30 percent to 123 percent higher FDI. The estimated effect is concentrated in the year that tax sparing comes into force and the subsequent years, with no effects in prior years, and is thus consistent with a causal interpretation. Four countries - Norway in 2004, and the U.K., Japan, and New Zealand in 2009 - enacted tax reforms that moved them from worldwide to territorial taxation, potentially changing the value of their preexisting tax sparing agreements. However, there is no detectable effect of these reforms on bilateral FDI in tax sparing countries, relative to nonsparing countries. These results are consistent with tax sparing being an important determinant of FDI in developing countries for MNCs from both worldwide and territorial home countries. We also find that these territorial reforms are associated with increases in certain forms of bilateral foreign aid from residence countries to sparing countries, relative to nonsparing countries. This suggests that tax sparing and foreign aid may function as substitutes.","PeriodicalId":385233,"journal":{"name":"FEN: Differences in Taxation & Corporate Finance (Topic)","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2016-04-18","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"115655948","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Taxing Royalty Payments 对特许权使用费征税
Pub Date : 2016-03-21 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.2839756
Steffen Juranek, Dirk Schindler, Guttorm Schjelderup
The digital economy is characterized by the use of intellectual property such as software, patents and trademarks. The pricing of such intangibles is widely used to shift profits to low-tax countries. We analyze the role of a source tax on royalty payments for abusive transfer pricing, and optimal tax policy. First, we show that mispricing of royalty payments does not affect investment behavior by multinationals. Second, it is in the vast majority of cases not optimal for a government to set the source tax equal to the corporate tax rate. The reason is that shutting down abusive transfer pricing activities needs to be traded off against mitigating the corporate tax distortion in capital investment. The latter can be achieved by some tax deductibility of royalty payments. If the true arm's length transfer price equals zero or for special corporate tax systems that treat debt and equity alike (i.e., for ACE and CBIT), it will be optimal to equate both tax rates.
数字经济的特点是使用知识产权,如软件、专利和商标。这种无形资产的定价被广泛用于将利润转移到低税收国家。我们分析了源税对滥用转让定价的特许权使用费支付的作用,以及最优税收政策。首先,我们发现特许权使用费的错误定价并不影响跨国公司的投资行为。其次,在绝大多数情况下,政府将源税设定为与企业税率相等的税率并不是最优的。原因是,关闭滥用转让定价活动需要与减轻资本投资中的企业税收扭曲相权衡。后者可以通过特许权使用费的某些税收减免来实现。如果真正的公平转让价格等于零,或者对于同样对待债务和股权的特殊公司税制度(例如,对于ACE和CBIT),将两种税率相等是最理想的。
{"title":"Taxing Royalty Payments","authors":"Steffen Juranek, Dirk Schindler, Guttorm Schjelderup","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.2839756","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2839756","url":null,"abstract":"The digital economy is characterized by the use of intellectual property such as software, patents and trademarks. The pricing of such intangibles is widely used to shift profits to low-tax countries. We analyze the role of a source tax on royalty payments for abusive transfer pricing, and optimal tax policy. First, we show that mispricing of royalty payments does not affect investment behavior by multinationals. Second, it is in the vast majority of cases not optimal for a government to set the source tax equal to the corporate tax rate. The reason is that shutting down abusive transfer pricing activities needs to be traded off against mitigating the corporate tax distortion in capital investment. The latter can be achieved by some tax deductibility of royalty payments. If the true arm's length transfer price equals zero or for special corporate tax systems that treat debt and equity alike (i.e., for ACE and CBIT), it will be optimal to equate both tax rates.","PeriodicalId":385233,"journal":{"name":"FEN: Differences in Taxation & Corporate Finance (Topic)","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2016-03-21","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"115900793","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2
Tackling Spillovers by Taxing Corporate Income in the European Union at Source 从源头上对欧盟企业收入征税以解决溢出效应
Pub Date : 2016-03-03 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.2760236
S. Cnossen
This paper surveys and evaluates the corporation tax (CT) systems of the Member States of the European Union on the basis of a comprehensive taxonomy of actual and potential regimes, which have as their base either profits, profits and interest, or economic rents. The current regimes give rise to various instate and interstate spillovers, which violate the basic tenets – neutrality and subsidiarity – of the single market. The trade-offs between the implications of these tenets – harmonization and diversity, respectively – can be reconciled by a bottom-up, reversible strategy of strengthening source-based taxation and approximating tax rates. The strategy starts with dual income taxation, proceeds with final source withholding taxes and rate approximation, and is made complete by comprehensive business income taxation. Common base taxation, if desired, should probably be left to the Member States themselves.
本文在对欧盟成员国现行和潜在的公司税制度进行全面分类的基础上,对公司税制度进行了调查和评价,这些制度的基础要么是利润、利润和利息,要么是经济租金。当前的制度导致了各种国内和州际溢出效应,违反了单一市场的基本原则——中立和辅助。这些原则的影响- -分别是协调和多样化- -之间的权衡可以通过自下而上的可逆战略来调和,即加强以来源为基础的征税和近似税率。该策略从双重所得税开始,以最终来源预扣税和税率近似进行,并以综合企业所得税完成。如果愿意,共同基础税也许应该留给会员国自己。
{"title":"Tackling Spillovers by Taxing Corporate Income in the European Union at Source","authors":"S. Cnossen","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.2760236","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2760236","url":null,"abstract":"This paper surveys and evaluates the corporation tax (CT) systems of the Member States of the European Union on the basis of a comprehensive taxonomy of actual and potential regimes, which have as their base either profits, profits and interest, or economic rents. The current regimes give rise to various instate and interstate spillovers, which violate the basic tenets – neutrality and subsidiarity – of the single market. The trade-offs between the implications of these tenets – harmonization and diversity, respectively – can be reconciled by a bottom-up, reversible strategy of strengthening source-based taxation and approximating tax rates. The strategy starts with dual income taxation, proceeds with final source withholding taxes and rate approximation, and is made complete by comprehensive business income taxation. Common base taxation, if desired, should probably be left to the Member States themselves.","PeriodicalId":385233,"journal":{"name":"FEN: Differences in Taxation & Corporate Finance (Topic)","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2016-03-03","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"127767949","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
期刊
FEN: Differences in Taxation & Corporate Finance (Topic)
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1