首页 > 最新文献

Michigan Law & Economics: Law Faculty Papers (Topic)最新文献

英文 中文
Exclusion from Income of Compensation for Services and Pooling of Labor Occurring in a Noncommercial Setting 在非商业环境中,排除在服务补偿收入和集中劳动力之外
Pub Date : 2022-04-07 DOI: 10.5744/ftr.2011.1082
Douglas A. Kahn
When cash is received for services, it typically will constitute gross income to the recipient. But what if the payments are made in a noncommercial setting such as the payment by a parent to a child for mowing the lawn or performing household chores? As discussed later in this Essay, there are reasons to conclude that such payments do not constitute income. The problem of how to treat receipts from a noncommercial activity frequently arises in the context of an exchange of services. A similar problem arises when services are provided by several persons pursuant to a pooling of labor to accomplish a common noncommercial goal.The regulations state that if a taxpayer receives services from another as payment for services rendered by the taxpayer, each party will realize gross income equal to the value of the services received from the other. If services were received as full or partial payment for property, the value of the services received would be included in the amount realized on the sale of the property. The tax problems that arise in connection with the receipt of services mostly occur when services are exchanged, and this Essay addresses that situation and will deal only incidentally with a payment of cash or other property for services.
当收到服务的现金时,它通常构成接受者的总收入。但是,如果付款是在非商业环境中进行的,比如父母给孩子修剪草坪或做家务的报酬,那该怎么办?正如本文后面所讨论的,有理由得出这样的结论:此类支付不构成收入。如何处理来自非商业活动的收据的问题经常出现在服务交换的背景下。当服务是由几个人根据集中劳动力来完成共同的非商业目标而提供时,也会出现类似的问题。《条例》规定,纳税人接受对方劳务作为其劳务报酬的,双方按接受对方劳务的价值实现总收入。如果收到的服务是作为财产的全部或部分付款,收到的服务的价值将包括在出售财产时实现的金额中。与接受服务有关的税收问题主要发生在交换服务时,本文将讨论这种情况,并仅附带处理支付现金或其他财产的服务。
{"title":"Exclusion from Income of Compensation for Services and Pooling of Labor Occurring in a Noncommercial Setting","authors":"Douglas A. Kahn","doi":"10.5744/ftr.2011.1082","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.5744/ftr.2011.1082","url":null,"abstract":"When cash is received for services, it typically will constitute gross income to the recipient. But what if the payments are made in a noncommercial setting such as the payment by a parent to a child for mowing the lawn or performing household chores? As discussed later in this Essay, there are reasons to conclude that such payments do not constitute income. The problem of how to treat receipts from a noncommercial activity frequently arises in the context of an exchange of services. A similar problem arises when services are provided by several persons pursuant to a pooling of labor to accomplish a common noncommercial goal.The regulations state that if a taxpayer receives services from another as payment for services rendered by the taxpayer, each party will realize gross income equal to the value of the services received from the other. If services were received as full or partial payment for property, the value of the services received would be included in the amount realized on the sale of the property. The tax problems that arise in connection with the receipt of services mostly occur when services are exchanged, and this Essay addresses that situation and will deal only incidentally with a payment of cash or other property for services.","PeriodicalId":415088,"journal":{"name":"Michigan Law & Economics: Law Faculty Papers (Topic)","volume":"33 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2022-04-07","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"122901873","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
A Comprehensive Approach to the Capital Requirements Based on EVA 基于EVA的资本要求综合分析
Pub Date : 2021-03-12 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3803317
A. Golbabaei, M. Botshekan
We propose a holistic approach to balance sheet management to show how banks can meet both regulatory capital (proposed under Basel III) and shareholders’ wealth simultaneously. Using the consolidated balance sheet, this work outlines a methodology for mapping between targeted credit risks based capital ratio and economic value added by which banks can predict their optimal balance sheet. The results of this study are as follows. First, using an ex-ante approach, we predict the optimized balance sheet in each year from the previous year's data. By imposing the restriction of a maximum of 5% possible changes in the balance sheet items compared to the real changes, we could make an optimized balance sheet in which we predict more EVA with the same capital ratio compared to the real performance in each year. Second, in the ex-post approach, we use the optimized balance sheet items predicted by the ex-ante approach and assume that if this optimized balance sheet is used by the bank in practice, how much more EVA will be gained. The results show that in this approach (the ex-post approach), we could generate more EVA. It means that if the bank had used this optimized balance sheet in practice, it could have made more EVA. Robustness tests also support our main results when we impose more restrictions on the analysis.
我们提出了一种全面的资产负债表管理方法,以展示银行如何同时满足监管资本(根据巴塞尔协议III提出)和股东财富。使用合并资产负债表,本工作概述了一种基于目标信贷风险的资本比率和经济增加值之间映射的方法,银行可以通过该方法预测其最佳资产负债表。本研究的结果如下:首先,使用事前法,我们根据前一年的数据预测每年的优化资产负债表。通过限制资产负债表项目与实际变化相比最多可能发生5%的变化,我们可以制作一个优化的资产负债表,其中我们以相同的资本比率预测更多的EVA与每年的实际表现相比。其次,在事后方法中,我们使用事前方法预测的优化资产负债表项目,并假设如果银行在实践中使用这种优化的资产负债表,将获得多少EVA。结果表明,在这种方法(事后法)中,我们可以产生更多的EVA。这意味着,如果银行在实践中使用这种优化的资产负债表,它可以获得更多的EVA。当我们对分析施加更多限制时,稳健性测试也支持我们的主要结果。
{"title":"A Comprehensive Approach to the Capital Requirements Based on EVA","authors":"A. Golbabaei, M. Botshekan","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3803317","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3803317","url":null,"abstract":"We propose a holistic approach to balance sheet management to show how banks can meet both regulatory capital (proposed under Basel III) and shareholders’ wealth simultaneously. Using the consolidated balance sheet, this work outlines a methodology for mapping between targeted credit risks based capital ratio and economic value added by which banks can predict their optimal balance sheet. The results of this study are as follows. First, using an ex-ante approach, we predict the optimized balance sheet in each year from the previous year's data. By imposing the restriction of a maximum of 5% possible changes in the balance sheet items compared to the real changes, we could make an optimized balance sheet in which we predict more EVA with the same capital ratio compared to the real performance in each year. Second, in the ex-post approach, we use the optimized balance sheet items predicted by the ex-ante approach and assume that if this optimized balance sheet is used by the bank in practice, how much more EVA will be gained. The results show that in this approach (the ex-post approach), we could generate more EVA. It means that if the bank had used this optimized balance sheet in practice, it could have made more EVA. Robustness tests also support our main results when we impose more restrictions on the analysis.","PeriodicalId":415088,"journal":{"name":"Michigan Law & Economics: Law Faculty Papers (Topic)","volume":"30 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2021-03-12","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"124951192","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Taxes in the Time of Coronavirus: Is It Time to Revive the Excess Profits Tax? 冠状病毒时期的税收:是时候恢复超额利得税了吗?
Pub Date : 2020-05-19 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3560806
R. Avi-Yonah
A recent NY Times headline summarizes one of the biggest economic impacts of the current pandemic: “Big Tech Could Emerge From Coronavirus Crisis Stronger Than Ever.” At a time when most American citizens and businesses suffer catastrophic economic damage from the Coronavirus Recession, some corporations such as Amazon, 3M, Gilead, and Zoom see their profits rise dramatically because of the pandemic. Given that most corporations are losing money but some are now earning excess profits due to the crisis, it is time to revive the wartime excess profits taxes that the US deployed in WW1 and WW2 to prevent the winners from achieving this form of opportunistic unjust enrichment. In what follows, I will first briefly summarize the WW2 historical experience (part 2) and then propose how it could be implemented today (part 3). Part 4 concludes.
《纽约时报》最近的一篇标题总结了当前疫情对经济的最大影响之一:“大型科技公司可能会比以往任何时候都更强大地走出冠状病毒危机。”在大多数美国公民和企业因冠状病毒经济衰退而遭受灾难性经济损失的时候,亚马逊、3M、吉利德和Zoom等一些公司的利润因疫情而大幅增长。鉴于大多数企业都在亏损,但有些企业正因这场危机而获得超额利润,现在是时候恢复战时超额利得税了。美国在一战和二战期间实施了这种税,以防止赢家获得这种形式的机会主义的不正当获利。接下来,我将首先简要总结二战的历史经验(第二部分),然后提出如何在今天实施(第三部分)。第四部分总结。
{"title":"Taxes in the Time of Coronavirus: Is It Time to Revive the Excess Profits Tax?","authors":"R. Avi-Yonah","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3560806","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3560806","url":null,"abstract":"A recent NY Times headline summarizes one of the biggest economic impacts of the current pandemic: “Big Tech Could Emerge From Coronavirus Crisis Stronger Than Ever.” At a time when most American citizens and businesses suffer catastrophic economic damage from the Coronavirus Recession, some corporations such as Amazon, 3M, Gilead, and Zoom see their profits rise dramatically because of the pandemic. \u0000 \u0000Given that most corporations are losing money but some are now earning excess profits due to the crisis, it is time to revive the wartime excess profits taxes that the US deployed in WW1 and WW2 to prevent the winners from achieving this form of opportunistic unjust enrichment. In what follows, I will first briefly summarize the WW2 historical experience (part 2) and then propose how it could be implemented today (part 3). Part 4 concludes.","PeriodicalId":415088,"journal":{"name":"Michigan Law & Economics: Law Faculty Papers (Topic)","volume":"36 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2020-05-19","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"125601797","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 5
If Not Now, When? US Tax Treaties with Latin America after TCJA 如果不是现在,会是什么时候?在TCJA之后,美国与拉丁美洲的税收协定
Pub Date : 2019-05-12 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.3382208
R. Avi-Yonah
Since the 1990s, the US tax treaty network has expanded to include most large developing countries. However, there remains a glaring exception: The US only has two tax treaties in Latin America (Mexico and Venezuela), and one pending tax treaty (Chile). The traditional explanation for why the US has no treaty with, for example, Argentina or Brazil is the US refusal since 1957 to grant tax sparing credits to developing countries. Before the Tax Cuts and Jobs Act of 2017 (TCJA), this explanation was wrong, because the combination of deferral and cross-crediting meant that tax holidays in a source country would not lead to a shift in revenues to a residence country even without tax sparing. This traditional view needs however to be updated given TCJA. On the one hand, there is now an exemption for direct dividends, so that the traditional rationale for not entering into treaties is gone. On the other hand, GILTI means that deferral is abolished and to the extent the income of a CFC exceeds the GILTI threshold there can in fact be a transfer of revenue to the US. Nevertheless, I believe that Latin American countries should enter into treaties with the US, for three reasons. First, cross-crediting still means that even with GILTI there may not be a revenue shift. Second, there are good reasons to enter into treaties even with a revenue shift, such as attracting FDI and limiting tax evasion. Third, Latin American countries are increasingly capital exporters, and the absence of a treaty hurts their multinationals. Finally, now is an opportunity, because the entire US treaty network needs to be updated to take account of TCJA.
自上世纪90年代以来,美国税收协定网络已扩大到包括大多数大型发展中国家。然而,仍有一个明显的例外:美国在拉丁美洲只有两个税收协定(墨西哥和委内瑞拉),还有一个悬而未决的税收协定(智利)。对于美国为何没有与阿根廷或巴西等国签订协定,传统的解释是,自1957年以来,美国拒绝向发展中国家提供税收减免。在2017年减税和就业法案(TCJA)之前,这种解释是错误的,因为递延和交叉抵扣的结合意味着,即使没有税收减免,来源国的免税期也不会导致收入转移到居住国。然而,在TCJA的情况下,这种传统观点需要更新。一方面,现在对直接股息有了豁免,因此不加入条约的传统理由就不存在了。另一方面,GILTI意味着延期被废除,在某种程度上,CFC的收入超过了GILTI的门槛,实际上可以将收入转移到美国。尽管如此,我认为拉美国家应该与美国签订条约,理由有三。首先,交叉信用仍然意味着,即使有GILTI,也可能不会有收入转移。其次,即使是在收入发生变化的情况下,也有很好的理由签署一些条约,比如吸引外国直接投资和限制逃税。第三,拉美国家越来越多地成为资本出口国,而缺乏协议损害了它们的跨国公司。最后,现在是一个机会,因为整个美国条约网络需要更新,以考虑到TCJA。
{"title":"If Not Now, When? US Tax Treaties with Latin America after TCJA","authors":"R. Avi-Yonah","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.3382208","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.3382208","url":null,"abstract":"Since the 1990s, the US tax treaty network has expanded to include most large developing countries. However, there remains a glaring exception: The US only has two tax treaties in Latin America (Mexico and Venezuela), and one pending tax treaty (Chile). The traditional explanation for why the US has no treaty with, for example, Argentina or Brazil is the US refusal since 1957 to grant tax sparing credits to developing countries. Before the Tax Cuts and Jobs Act of 2017 (TCJA), this explanation was wrong, because the combination of deferral and cross-crediting meant that tax holidays in a source country would not lead to a shift in revenues to a residence country even without tax sparing. This traditional view needs however to be updated given TCJA. On the one hand, there is now an exemption for direct dividends, so that the traditional rationale for not entering into treaties is gone. On the other hand, GILTI means that deferral is abolished and to the extent the income of a CFC exceeds the GILTI threshold there can in fact be a transfer of revenue to the US. Nevertheless, I believe that Latin American countries should enter into treaties with the US, for three reasons. First, cross-crediting still means that even with GILTI there may not be a revenue shift. Second, there are good reasons to enter into treaties even with a revenue shift, such as attracting FDI and limiting tax evasion. Third, Latin American countries are increasingly capital exporters, and the absence of a treaty hurts their multinationals. Finally, now is an opportunity, because the entire US treaty network needs to be updated to take account of TCJA.","PeriodicalId":415088,"journal":{"name":"Michigan Law & Economics: Law Faculty Papers (Topic)","volume":"32 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2019-05-12","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"116874806","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
The Promotion of Financial Inclusion in Madagascar Through Mobile Money and Microfinance 通过移动货币和小额信贷促进马达加斯加的普惠金融
Pub Date : 2018-05-04 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3173606
Andriamirado Rakoto
Madagascar is a country in Sub-Saharan Africa. With an area of 592,800 square kilometres, it is the world’s 46th largest country and the fourth largest island. The country has many natural resources which are unique. Despite on the fact that Madagascar has abundant natural resources which are a fundamental point for its development, it is among of the poorest countries in Africa and the world: more than 60% of the population live on less than $2 a day. Many factors could be advanced to explain the origins of the poverty of this country, but one of them is the low access of the population to Financial Services. As Dr Muhammad Yunus said, “the system causes poverty; if we can change the system, we can change people’s life.” In Madagascar, the Mobile Money and the Microcredit plays a grand role in the promotion of Financial Inclusion. The success of Mobile Money in Madagascar will depend on the partnerships between the Mobile Network Operators and the Financial Institutions like Bank and Micro Finance Institutions.
马达加斯加是撒哈拉以南非洲的一个国家。面积59.28万平方公里,是世界第46大国和第四大岛。这个国家有许多独特的自然资源。尽管马达加斯加拥有丰富的自然资源,这是其发展的基础,但它是非洲和世界上最贫穷的国家之一:超过60%的人口每天的生活费不足2美元。可以提出许多因素来解释这个国家贫困的根源,但其中之一是人口获得金融服务的机会较少。正如穆罕默德·尤努斯博士所说,“体制导致贫困;如果我们能改变体制,我们就能改变人们的生活。”在马达加斯加,移动货币和小额信贷在促进普惠金融方面发挥了重要作用。移动货币在马达加斯加的成功将取决于移动网络运营商与银行和微型金融机构等金融机构之间的合作关系。
{"title":"The Promotion of Financial Inclusion in Madagascar Through Mobile Money and Microfinance","authors":"Andriamirado Rakoto","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3173606","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3173606","url":null,"abstract":"Madagascar is a country in Sub-Saharan Africa. With an area of 592,800 square kilometres, it is the world’s 46th largest country and the fourth largest island. The country has many natural resources which are unique. Despite on the fact that Madagascar has abundant natural resources which are a fundamental point for its development, it is among of the poorest countries in Africa and the world: more than 60% of the population live on less than $2 a day. Many factors could be advanced to explain the origins of the poverty of this country, but one of them is the low access of the population to Financial Services. As Dr Muhammad Yunus said, “the system causes poverty; if we can change the system, we can change people’s life.” In Madagascar, the Mobile Money and the Microcredit plays a grand role in the promotion of Financial Inclusion. The success of Mobile Money in Madagascar will depend on the partnerships between the Mobile Network Operators and the Financial Institutions like Bank and Micro Finance Institutions.","PeriodicalId":415088,"journal":{"name":"Michigan Law & Economics: Law Faculty Papers (Topic)","volume":"3 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2018-05-04","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"130070617","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
From Here to Eternity: The Folly of Perpetual Trusts 从现在到永恒:永久信托的愚蠢
Pub Date : 2016-07-01 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.1975117
Lawrence W. Waggoner
In a country that is only 240 years old, trusts that can last for as many as 1000 years or even forever, typically for the benefit of the settlor’s descendants living from time to time, now and in the future, are all the rage in banking and estate-planning circles. Before 1986, when Congress passed the federal generation-skipping transfer tax (GST tax), settlors had little incentive and probably little desire to establish perpetual trusts, even though they were permitted to do so under the law of Wisconsin, South Dakota, or Idaho. The GST tax created an artificial incentive for the wealthy to establish such trusts. The origin of the perpetual-trust movement is the GST exemption, which is part of the GST tax. When Congress granted the GST exemption, it did not impose a durational limit on trusts that qualify for the exemption, but instead relied on state perpetuity laws to supply that limit. The reliance on state perpetuity laws was badly misplaced. At the instigation of state banking groups and estate-planning attorneys, states began to pass legislation allowing trust settlors to create perpetual trusts — trusts that can last for several centuries or even forever. With state perpetuity laws out of the way, the wealthy began creating perpetual trusts in significant numbers. This essay questions whether the state legislators who vote to authorize perpetual trusts and the wealthy who create them are thinking through what they are allowing or putting in place. The essay shows the folly of such trusts, primarily by producing a table projecting how, with each step down the generational ladder, the number of beneficiaries will proliferate and the settlor’s genetic connection with the beneficiaries will decline. The essay then points out that the primary responsibility for the perpetual-trust movement rests not with the state legislators or the wealthy, but with Congress. The primary responsibility for curtailing it also rests with Congress, but so far Congress has been decidedly uninterested in fixing what it instigated.
在一个只有240年历史的国家,可以持续1000年甚至永远的信托,通常是为了现在和将来不时生活的定居者的后代的利益,在银行业和遗产规划界风靡一时。1986年,国会通过了联邦跨代转让税(GST税),在此之前,尽管威斯康辛州、南达科他州和爱达荷州的法律允许定居者建立永久信托,但定居者几乎没有动力,也可能没有意愿建立永久信托。商品及服务税人为地激励富人建立这样的信托。永久信托运动的起源是商品及服务税的豁免,这是商品及服务税的一部分。当国会批准GST豁免时,它并没有对有资格获得豁免的信托施加期限限制,而是依靠州永续法来提供这一限制。对州永续法的依赖严重错位。在州银行集团和遗产规划律师的鼓动下,各州开始通过立法,允许信托受托人创建永久信托——可以持续几个世纪甚至永远的信托。随着州永续财产法的废除,富人开始大量创建永续财产信托。本文质疑投票授权永久信托的州议员和创建永久信托的富人是否仔细考虑过他们允许或实施的事情。这篇文章展示了这种信托的愚蠢之处,主要是通过制作一个表格来预测,随着代际阶梯的每一步,受益人的数量将如何激增,而遗产继承人与受益人的遗传联系将如何下降。文章接着指出,永久信托运动的主要责任不在于州议员或富人,而在于国会。削减赤字的主要责任也在国会,但到目前为止,国会显然对解决它所煽动的问题不感兴趣。
{"title":"From Here to Eternity: The Folly of Perpetual Trusts","authors":"Lawrence W. Waggoner","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.1975117","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.1975117","url":null,"abstract":"In a country that is only 240 years old, trusts that can last for as many as 1000 years or even forever, typically for the benefit of the settlor’s descendants living from time to time, now and in the future, are all the rage in banking and estate-planning circles. Before 1986, when Congress passed the federal generation-skipping transfer tax (GST tax), settlors had little incentive and probably little desire to establish perpetual trusts, even though they were permitted to do so under the law of Wisconsin, South Dakota, or Idaho. The GST tax created an artificial incentive for the wealthy to establish such trusts. The origin of the perpetual-trust movement is the GST exemption, which is part of the GST tax. When Congress granted the GST exemption, it did not impose a durational limit on trusts that qualify for the exemption, but instead relied on state perpetuity laws to supply that limit. The reliance on state perpetuity laws was badly misplaced. At the instigation of state banking groups and estate-planning attorneys, states began to pass legislation allowing trust settlors to create perpetual trusts — trusts that can last for several centuries or even forever. With state perpetuity laws out of the way, the wealthy began creating perpetual trusts in significant numbers. This essay questions whether the state legislators who vote to authorize perpetual trusts and the wealthy who create them are thinking through what they are allowing or putting in place. The essay shows the folly of such trusts, primarily by producing a table projecting how, with each step down the generational ladder, the number of beneficiaries will proliferate and the settlor’s genetic connection with the beneficiaries will decline. The essay then points out that the primary responsibility for the perpetual-trust movement rests not with the state legislators or the wealthy, but with Congress. The primary responsibility for curtailing it also rests with Congress, but so far Congress has been decidedly uninterested in fixing what it instigated.","PeriodicalId":415088,"journal":{"name":"Michigan Law & Economics: Law Faculty Papers (Topic)","volume":"31 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2016-07-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"115929841","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
In Praise of (Some) Ex Post Regulation: A Response to Professor Galle 赞扬(某些)事后管制:对加勒教授的回应
Pub Date : 2016-03-24 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.2754174
Kyle D. Logue
Professor Brian Galle recently argued that the growing consensus that ex post regulation is superior to ex ante regulation on efficiency grounds has been overstated by scholars, including me, and that ex ante regulation has advantages that have been ignored or underemphasized. In this Response, I explain that ex post regulation does have advantages in certain settings and that the optimal regulatory response to many market failures will entail the use of both ex post and ex ante policy instruments. I also explain how an ex post incentive-based regulation, such as tort law or workers' compensation law, gets converted into a form of ex ante regulation through liability insurance and how liability insurance premiums produce a sort of "clustered" externality pricing that Galle suggests might be superior to both unitary Pigovian taxes or individualized tort sanctions.
Brian Galle教授最近认为,从效率的角度来看,事后监管优于事前监管这一日益增长的共识被包括我在内的学者夸大了,而事前监管具有被忽视或低估的优势。在本回应中,我解释了事后监管在某些情况下确实有优势,对许多市场失灵的最佳监管反应将需要同时使用事后和事前政策工具。我还解释了基于事后激励的监管,如侵权法或工人赔偿法,如何通过责任保险转化为一种事前监管形式,以及责任保险保费如何产生一种“集群”外部性定价,加勒认为这种定价可能优于单一的庇古税或个体化的侵权制裁。
{"title":"In Praise of (Some) Ex Post Regulation: A Response to Professor Galle","authors":"Kyle D. Logue","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.2754174","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.2754174","url":null,"abstract":"Professor Brian Galle recently argued that the growing consensus that ex post regulation is superior to ex ante regulation on efficiency grounds has been overstated by scholars, including me, and that ex ante regulation has advantages that have been ignored or underemphasized. In this Response, I explain that ex post regulation does have advantages in certain settings and that the optimal regulatory response to many market failures will entail the use of both ex post and ex ante policy instruments. I also explain how an ex post incentive-based regulation, such as tort law or workers' compensation law, gets converted into a form of ex ante regulation through liability insurance and how liability insurance premiums produce a sort of \"clustered\" externality pricing that Galle suggests might be superior to both unitary Pigovian taxes or individualized tort sanctions.","PeriodicalId":415088,"journal":{"name":"Michigan Law & Economics: Law Faculty Papers (Topic)","volume":"81 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2016-03-24","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"116214671","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
The Perverse Effects of Subsidized Weather Insurance 补贴天气保险的反常影响
Pub Date : 2015-05-07 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.2549320
O. Ben‐Shahar, Kyle D. Logue
This Article explores the role of insurance as substitute for direct regulation of risks posed by severe weather. In pricing the risk of human activity along the predicted path of storms, insurance can provide incentives for efficient location decisions as well as for cost-justified mitigation effort in building construction and infrastructure. Currently, however, much insurance for severe weather risks is provided and heavily subsidized by the government. The Article demonstrates two primary distortions arising from the government’s dominance in these insurance markets. First, the subsidies are allocated differentially across households, resulting in a significant regressive redistribution, favoring affluent homeowners in coastal communities. The Article provides some empirical measures of this effect. Second, the subsidies induce excessive development (and redevelopment) of storm-stricken and erosion-prone areas. While political efforts to scale down the insurance subsidies have so far failed, by exposing the unintended costs of government-subsidized insurance this Article contributes to reevaluation of the social regulation of weather risk.
本文探讨了保险作为对恶劣天气带来的风险的直接监管的替代品的作用。在为预测的风暴路径上的人类活动风险定价时,保险可以激励人们作出有效的地点决定,并在建筑施工和基础设施方面为成本合理的减灾努力提供激励。然而,目前,许多恶劣天气风险的保险都是由政府提供并大量补贴的。这篇文章展示了政府在这些保险市场中的主导地位所造成的两种主要扭曲。首先,补贴在不同家庭之间的分配是不同的,导致了显著的递减再分配,有利于沿海社区的富裕房主。本文提供了对这种效应的一些实证度量。其次,补贴导致了对遭受风暴袭击和易受侵蚀地区的过度开发(和再开发)。虽然缩减保险补贴的政治努力迄今为止失败了,但通过暴露政府补贴保险的意外成本,本文有助于重新评估天气风险的社会监管。
{"title":"The Perverse Effects of Subsidized Weather Insurance","authors":"O. Ben‐Shahar, Kyle D. Logue","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.2549320","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.2549320","url":null,"abstract":"This Article explores the role of insurance as substitute for direct regulation of risks posed by severe weather. In pricing the risk of human activity along the predicted path of storms, insurance can provide incentives for efficient location decisions as well as for cost-justified mitigation effort in building construction and infrastructure. Currently, however, much insurance for severe weather risks is provided and heavily subsidized by the government. The Article demonstrates two primary distortions arising from the government’s dominance in these insurance markets. First, the subsidies are allocated differentially across households, resulting in a significant regressive redistribution, favoring affluent homeowners in coastal communities. The Article provides some empirical measures of this effect. Second, the subsidies induce excessive development (and redevelopment) of storm-stricken and erosion-prone areas. While political efforts to scale down the insurance subsidies have so far failed, by exposing the unintended costs of government-subsidized insurance this Article contributes to reevaluation of the social regulation of weather risk.","PeriodicalId":415088,"journal":{"name":"Michigan Law & Economics: Law Faculty Papers (Topic)","volume":"9 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2015-05-07","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"117063653","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 71
The Agency Exception to the Anticipatory Assignment Doctrine 预见性转让原则的代理例外
Pub Date : 2015-05-04 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.2575915
Douglas A. Kahn, J. Kahn
One consequence of having graduated income tax rates is that it becomes advantageous to shift income from a high bracket taxpayer to a person in a lower tax bracket. A number of different vehicles have been tried to shift the incidence of the income tax to another person, and the courts and Congress have adopted a number of rules to prevent that from occurring. As early as 1930, the Supreme Court adopted the anticipatory assignment of income doctrine to prevent a person who anticipates earning income from his services from shifting that income to another person in a lower tax bracket. Income is taxed to the person whose services produced it rather than to the person who has the beneficial right to possess the income once it is earned. This article discusses the tax treatment of an employee whose services create income for his employer. The anticipatory assignment of income doctrine does not apply in these circumstances under the so-called agency exception. This article explains the policy justification of the agency exception and uses examples to help illustrate when and when not the agency exception should apply.
累进所得税率的一个后果是,将收入从高税率的纳税人转移到低税率的人身上变得有利。人们已经尝试了许多不同的方式来将所得税的负担转移到另一个人身上,法院和国会也采用了许多规则来防止这种情况的发生。早在1930年,最高法院就采纳了预期收入分配原则,以防止预期从其服务中获得收入的人将该收入转移给另一个税率较低的人。收入是向提供服务的人征税,而不是向获得收入后拥有实益权利的人征税。这篇文章讨论了为雇主创造收入的雇员的税收待遇。在所谓的代理例外情况下,预期分配收入原则不适用于这些情况。本文解释了代理例外的政策正当性,并使用示例来帮助说明何时应适用代理例外,何时不应适用代理例外。
{"title":"The Agency Exception to the Anticipatory Assignment Doctrine","authors":"Douglas A. Kahn, J. Kahn","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.2575915","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.2575915","url":null,"abstract":"One consequence of having graduated income tax rates is that it becomes advantageous to shift income from a high bracket taxpayer to a person in a lower tax bracket. A number of different vehicles have been tried to shift the incidence of the income tax to another person, and the courts and Congress have adopted a number of rules to prevent that from occurring. As early as 1930, the Supreme Court adopted the anticipatory assignment of income doctrine to prevent a person who anticipates earning income from his services from shifting that income to another person in a lower tax bracket. Income is taxed to the person whose services produced it rather than to the person who has the beneficial right to possess the income once it is earned. This article discusses the tax treatment of an employee whose services create income for his employer. The anticipatory assignment of income doctrine does not apply in these circumstances under the so-called agency exception. This article explains the policy justification of the agency exception and uses examples to help illustrate when and when not the agency exception should apply.","PeriodicalId":415088,"journal":{"name":"Michigan Law & Economics: Law Faculty Papers (Topic)","volume":"1 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2015-05-04","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"116014954","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
What Boilerplate Said: A Response to Omri Ben-Shahar (and a Diagnosis) 样板说了什么:对欧姆里·本·沙哈尔的回应(和诊断)
Pub Date : 2014-02-26 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.2401720
M. Radin
This essay responds to Omri Ben-Shahar’s review of my book, Boilerplate: The Fine Print, Vanishing Rights, and the Rule of Law (Princeton 2013). Ben-Shahar’s review (available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2255161) unfortunately does not convey the nature of this book to possible readers. His preconceptions – reflecting primarily what I call “old-school Chicago”--apparently caused him to believe that some strong version of “autonomy” was the focus of my book. Instead, the book’s purpose is to gather together a broad range of ideas relevant to boilerplate, in order to encourage readers to consider opportunities for improving our theory and practice. It makes detailed suggestions for improving our treatment of boilerplate, including chapters on how judges could improve on unconscionability and public policy decisions, how market initiatives might be harnessed to cabin boilerplate excesses, and how bad boilerplate might be regulated by tort law rather than contract law. Boilerplate does investigate the disjuncture between contract theories’ various commitments to voluntariness and the realities of contemporary practice with respect to mass-market boilerplate; but it does so as backdrop to its main purpose.
本文回应了Omri Ben-Shahar对我的书《样板:精细印刷、消失的权利和法治》(普林斯顿大学2013年出版)的评论。不幸的是,Ben-Shahar的评论(可在http://ssrn.com/abstract=2255161找到)并没有向可能的读者传达这本书的本质。他的先入之见——主要反映了我所说的“老派芝加哥”——显然使他相信,我的书的重点是某种强烈的“自治”。相反,本书的目的是收集与模板相关的广泛观点,以鼓励读者考虑改进我们的理论和实践的机会。它为改善我们对样板文件的处理提出了详细的建议,包括法官如何改进不合理行为和公共政策决策,如何利用市场主动性来遏制样板文件的过度行为,以及如何通过侵权法而不是合同法来规范不良样板文件。Boilerplate确实研究了契约理论对自愿性的各种承诺与大众市场样板的当代实践现实之间的脱节;但这只是其主要目的的背景。
{"title":"What Boilerplate Said: A Response to Omri Ben-Shahar (and a Diagnosis)","authors":"M. Radin","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.2401720","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.2401720","url":null,"abstract":"This essay responds to Omri Ben-Shahar’s review of my book, Boilerplate: The Fine Print, Vanishing Rights, and the Rule of Law (Princeton 2013). Ben-Shahar’s review (available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2255161) unfortunately does not convey the nature of this book to possible readers. His preconceptions – reflecting primarily what I call “old-school Chicago”--apparently caused him to believe that some strong version of “autonomy” was the focus of my book. Instead, the book’s purpose is to gather together a broad range of ideas relevant to boilerplate, in order to encourage readers to consider opportunities for improving our theory and practice. It makes detailed suggestions for improving our treatment of boilerplate, including chapters on how judges could improve on unconscionability and public policy decisions, how market initiatives might be harnessed to cabin boilerplate excesses, and how bad boilerplate might be regulated by tort law rather than contract law. Boilerplate does investigate the disjuncture between contract theories’ various commitments to voluntariness and the realities of contemporary practice with respect to mass-market boilerplate; but it does so as backdrop to its main purpose.","PeriodicalId":415088,"journal":{"name":"Michigan Law & Economics: Law Faculty Papers (Topic)","volume":"19 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2014-02-26","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"131537111","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2
期刊
Michigan Law & Economics: Law Faculty Papers (Topic)
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1