首页 > 最新文献

Indian Growth and Development Review最新文献

英文 中文
China, India and the contest for the Indo-Pacific 中国、印度和印太地区的竞争
IF 1.4 Q4 DEVELOPMENT STUDIES Pub Date : 2019-11-01 DOI: 10.1108/igdr-06-2019-0055
P. Robertson, Jingdong Yuan, Harsha Konara Mudiyanselage
PurposeThe purpose of this paper is to describe how China’s rapid growth and increasing resource dependence have changed its relationship with India and their respective defense strategies. In particular, we consider China's Belt and Road Initiative, India's “Act East” policy and the strategic and economic value of the Indian Ocean and South China Sea regions.Design/methodology/approachThe authors find no econometric evidence of interactions between China and India’s military spending using a Richardson-Baumol arms race model. Likewise, in a cross-county panel data study of military spending, they find that China’s military spending has no independent effect on military spending in other countries. The authors also show that once wage costs and other sources of military inflation are accounted for, the pattern of real defense spending growth is much less intense than is suggested by nominal data. Nevertheless, they show that China has been undertaking intense military modernization with rapidly rising capital-labor ratios in its defense spending.FindingsThe authors find little evidence of a traditional arms race, but also show that China, and to a lesser extent India, have been realigning their military capabilities to these new security risks while maintaining overall military burden on the economy.Research limitations/implicationsEconometric analysis is limited by data availability and is necessarily historical, whereas the security situation is very fluid and may change in the short term.Practical implicationsThe paper identifies factors that are likely to influence China and India's attitudes to defense spending in the coming years.Social implicationsThe paper finds that there is not an arms race in the traditional sense but may be an arms race in terms of new technologies and military modernization.Originality/valueThis is a very much underexplored topic in economics. The authors take an interdisciplinary approach showing how economics tools can be used to help understand this important issue in international relations.
目的本文旨在描述中国的快速增长和日益增长的资源依赖如何改变其与印度的关系以及各自的国防战略。我们特别考虑中国的“一带一路”倡议倡议、印度的“向东行动”政策以及印度洋和南海地区的战略和经济价值。设计/方法论/方法作者使用Richardson-Baumol军备竞赛模型没有发现中国和印度军费开支之间相互作用的计量经济学证据。同样,在一项关于军费开支的跨县小组数据研究中,他们发现中国的军费开支对其他国家的军费开支没有独立影响。作者还表明,一旦考虑到工资成本和其他军事通胀来源,实际国防开支增长的模式就远没有名义数据所显示的那么激烈。尽管如此,它们表明,中国一直在进行激烈的军事现代化,国防开支中的资本-劳动力比例迅速上升。研究结果作者几乎没有发现传统军备竞赛的证据,但也表明,中国和印度在较小程度上一直在调整其军事能力,以应对这些新的安全风险,同时保持经济的整体军事负担。研究局限性/含义经济计量分析受到数据可用性的限制,并且必然是历史性的,而安全状况非常不稳定,可能在短期内发生变化。实际含义本文确定了可能影响中国和印度未来几年对国防开支态度的因素。社会含义本文发现,不存在传统意义上的军备竞赛,而可能存在新技术和军事现代化方面的军备竞赛。原创性/价值这是经济学中一个未被充分挖掘的话题。作者采用了跨学科的方法,展示了如何使用经济学工具来帮助理解国际关系中的这一重要问题。
{"title":"China, India and the contest for the Indo-Pacific","authors":"P. Robertson, Jingdong Yuan, Harsha Konara Mudiyanselage","doi":"10.1108/igdr-06-2019-0055","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1108/igdr-06-2019-0055","url":null,"abstract":"\u0000Purpose\u0000The purpose of this paper is to describe how China’s rapid growth and increasing resource dependence have changed its relationship with India and their respective defense strategies. In particular, we consider China's Belt and Road Initiative, India's “Act East” policy and the strategic and economic value of the Indian Ocean and South China Sea regions.\u0000\u0000\u0000Design/methodology/approach\u0000The authors find no econometric evidence of interactions between China and India’s military spending using a Richardson-Baumol arms race model. Likewise, in a cross-county panel data study of military spending, they find that China’s military spending has no independent effect on military spending in other countries. The authors also show that once wage costs and other sources of military inflation are accounted for, the pattern of real defense spending growth is much less intense than is suggested by nominal data. Nevertheless, they show that China has been undertaking intense military modernization with rapidly rising capital-labor ratios in its defense spending.\u0000\u0000\u0000Findings\u0000The authors find little evidence of a traditional arms race, but also show that China, and to a lesser extent India, have been realigning their military capabilities to these new security risks while maintaining overall military burden on the economy.\u0000\u0000\u0000Research limitations/implications\u0000Econometric analysis is limited by data availability and is necessarily historical, whereas the security situation is very fluid and may change in the short term.\u0000\u0000\u0000Practical implications\u0000The paper identifies factors that are likely to influence China and India's attitudes to defense spending in the coming years.\u0000\u0000\u0000Social implications\u0000The paper finds that there is not an arms race in the traditional sense but may be an arms race in terms of new technologies and military modernization.\u0000\u0000\u0000Originality/value\u0000This is a very much underexplored topic in economics. The authors take an interdisciplinary approach showing how economics tools can be used to help understand this important issue in international relations.\u0000","PeriodicalId":42861,"journal":{"name":"Indian Growth and Development Review","volume":" ","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":1.4,"publicationDate":"2019-11-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1108/igdr-06-2019-0055","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"43980682","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Structural change and technical efficiency: a study of Indian pulp and paper industry 结构变化与技术效率:印度纸浆造纸工业研究
IF 1.4 Q4 DEVELOPMENT STUDIES Pub Date : 2019-11-01 DOI: 10.1108/igdr-11-2018-0121
V. Kathuria
PurposeThe pulp and paper industry has been the focus of government policies ever since independence. This is the only industry where government plays a multi-dimensional role – not only as the regulator but also as the supplier of raw material and as the buyer. Despite the government's omnipotent role, there is evidence that industry is not very competitive, as it has very high energy and water intensity and poor productivity. A potent factor identified in the literature for the underperformance of the industry or for that matter any economy is the kind of technology used by the firms in the sector. This paper aims to look into the role of government policy in affecting the growth of the industry and what role embodied technology has played in influencing the efficiency of firms in Indian pulp and paper industry.Design/methodology/approachFor the first question, the study uses 66 years of production data of the industry from 1951 to 2016 and tests for the structural break. For the second question, the study uses cross-section plant-level data for the year 2011-2012 of 160 paper manufacturing units to first estimate the stochastic production frontier (stochastic frontier analysis [SFA]) and then uses the output of SFA to find an association between embodied technology gap (TG) and technical efficiency. A methodological problem in earlier literature is the use of the productivity gap as a proxy for embodied TG. The present study uses technical parameters of papermaking – machine deckle and operating speed – to construct an index of TG.FindingsThe results show a structural break in the production trend occurring in 1999 with the delicensing in July 1997 as the possible cause. The SFA results show that the average technical inefficiency (TE) of the firms in the sector is 74 per cent with half of the firms having TE higher than 76 per cent. The study, however, does not find any impact of embodied TG on technical efficiency; rather it is the age, size, ownership and location that have an impact on it.Originality/valueThis is an original research, as the author has not come across any study in Indian context or elsewhere using technical parameters to construct TG variable.
自独立以来,纸浆和造纸工业一直是政府政策的重点。这是唯一一个政府扮演多维角色的行业——不仅作为监管者,而且作为原材料供应商和买家。尽管政府发挥着无所不能的作用,但有证据表明,工业竞争力不强,因为它的能源和水强度非常高,生产率很低。在文献中确定的行业或任何经济体表现不佳的一个有力因素是该部门企业使用的技术类型。本文旨在研究政府政策在影响行业增长方面的作用,以及体现技术在影响印度纸浆和造纸行业企业效率方面发挥的作用。设计/方法/方法对于第一个问题,本研究使用了该行业从1951年到2016年66年的生产数据,并对结构断裂进行了测试。对于第二个问题,本研究使用2011-2012年160家造纸单位的工厂横截面数据,首先估算随机生产前沿(stochastic frontier analysis [SFA]),然后使用SFA的输出来寻找具体技术差距(TG)与技术效率之间的关联。早期文献中的一个方法论问题是使用生产率差距作为具体化TG的代理。本研究利用造纸机械的工艺参数—减径和运转速度—来构建热重指标。结果表明:1999年生产趋势出现结构性断裂,可能是1997年7月的市场降温造成的。SFA结果表明,该行业企业的平均技术效率低下(TE)为74%,其中一半企业的技术效率低下(TE)高于76%。然而,研究并未发现隐含TG对技术效率有任何影响;相反,对它产生影响的是它的年龄、规模、所有权和位置。原创性/价值这是一项原创研究,因为作者没有在印度或其他地方遇到过任何使用技术参数构建TG变量的研究。
{"title":"Structural change and technical efficiency: a study of Indian pulp and paper industry","authors":"V. Kathuria","doi":"10.1108/igdr-11-2018-0121","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1108/igdr-11-2018-0121","url":null,"abstract":"\u0000Purpose\u0000The pulp and paper industry has been the focus of government policies ever since independence. This is the only industry where government plays a multi-dimensional role – not only as the regulator but also as the supplier of raw material and as the buyer. Despite the government's omnipotent role, there is evidence that industry is not very competitive, as it has very high energy and water intensity and poor productivity. A potent factor identified in the literature for the underperformance of the industry or for that matter any economy is the kind of technology used by the firms in the sector. This paper aims to look into the role of government policy in affecting the growth of the industry and what role embodied technology has played in influencing the efficiency of firms in Indian pulp and paper industry.\u0000\u0000\u0000Design/methodology/approach\u0000For the first question, the study uses 66 years of production data of the industry from 1951 to 2016 and tests for the structural break. For the second question, the study uses cross-section plant-level data for the year 2011-2012 of 160 paper manufacturing units to first estimate the stochastic production frontier (stochastic frontier analysis [SFA]) and then uses the output of SFA to find an association between embodied technology gap (TG) and technical efficiency. A methodological problem in earlier literature is the use of the productivity gap as a proxy for embodied TG. The present study uses technical parameters of papermaking – machine deckle and operating speed – to construct an index of TG.\u0000\u0000\u0000Findings\u0000The results show a structural break in the production trend occurring in 1999 with the delicensing in July 1997 as the possible cause. The SFA results show that the average technical inefficiency (TE) of the firms in the sector is 74 per cent with half of the firms having TE higher than 76 per cent. The study, however, does not find any impact of embodied TG on technical efficiency; rather it is the age, size, ownership and location that have an impact on it.\u0000\u0000\u0000Originality/value\u0000This is an original research, as the author has not come across any study in Indian context or elsewhere using technical parameters to construct TG variable.\u0000","PeriodicalId":42861,"journal":{"name":"Indian Growth and Development Review","volume":"1 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":1.4,"publicationDate":"2019-11-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1108/igdr-11-2018-0121","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"41866500","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Aid and terrorism: a dynamic contracts approach with interlinked moral hazard 援助与恐怖主义:具有相互关联的道德风险的动态契约方法
IF 1.4 Q4 DEVELOPMENT STUDIES Pub Date : 2019-10-29 DOI: 10.1108/igdr-01-2019-0004
J. Roy, Prabal Roy Chowdhury
PurposeIn a global environment where terrorist organisations based in a poor country target a rich nation, this paper aims to study the properties of a dynamically incentive compatible contract designed by the target nation that involves joint counter-terror tasks with costly participation by each country. The counter-terror operations are however subject to ex post moral hazard, so that to incentivise counter-terror, the rich country supplies developmental aid. Development aid also helps avoid unrest arising from counter-terror activities in the target nation. However, aid itself can be diverted to non-developmental projects, generating a novel interlinked moral hazard problem spanning both tasks and rewards.Design/methodology/approachThe authors use a dynamic model where the aid giving countries and aid receiving countries behave strategically. Then they solve for the sub game perfect Nash equilibrium of this game.FindingsThe authors characterise the optimal contract, showing that the dynamic structure of counter-terror resembles the shock-and-awe discussed by military strategists. The authors then prove that it is not necessarily the case that a more hawkish (resp. altruistic) donor is less pro-development (resp. softer on terror). In addition, the authors show that it may be easier to contract for higher counter-terror inputs when the recipient is more sympathetic to terrorists. The authors also discuss other problems faced by developing nations where this model can be readily adopted and the results can endorse appealing policy implications.Originality/valueThe authors characterise the optimal contract, showing that the dynamic structure of counter-terror resembles the shock-and-awe discussed by military strategists. It is proved that it is not necessarily the case that a more hawkish (resp. altruistic) donor is less pro-development (resp. softer on terror). In addition, the authors show that it may be easier to contract for higher counter-terror inputs when the recipient is more sympathetic to terrorists. Other problems faced by developing nations are also discussed where this model can be readily adopted, and the results can endorse appealing policy implications. These results have important policy implications, in particular in today’s world.
在以穷国为基地的恐怖组织以富国为目标的全球环境中,本文旨在研究由目标国设计的涉及各国昂贵参与的联合反恐任务的动态激励相容契约的性质。然而,反恐行动受到事后道德风险的影响,因此,为了激励反恐,富国提供发展援助。发展援助还有助于避免因目标国家的反恐活动而引起的动乱。然而,援助本身可以被转移到非发展性项目,从而产生一种跨越任务和回报的新的相互关联的道德风险问题。设计/方法/方法作者使用了一个动态模型,其中援助国和受援国的行为具有战略意义。然后解出这个博弈的子博弈的完美纳什均衡。研究结果:作者描述了最优契约,表明反恐的动态结构类似于军事战略家所讨论的震慑。作者随后证明,一个更鹰派的总统并不一定是这样。利他主义的捐赠者不太支持发展。对恐怖主义软化)。此外,作者还指出,当接受者更同情恐怖分子时,可能更容易签订更高的反恐投入合同。作者还讨论了发展中国家面临的其他问题,在这些问题上,这种模式可以很容易地被采用,其结果可以支持有吸引力的政策含义。作者描述了最优契约,表明反恐的动态结构类似于军事战略家所讨论的震慑。事实证明,一个更强硬的总统并不一定会成为美国总统。利他主义的捐赠者不太支持发展。对恐怖主义软化)。此外,作者还指出,当接受者更同情恐怖分子时,可能更容易签订更高的反恐投入合同。本文还讨论了发展中国家面临的其他问题,在这些问题上可以很容易地采用这种模式,其结果可以支持有吸引力的政策含义。这些结果具有重要的政策意义,特别是在当今世界。
{"title":"Aid and terrorism: a dynamic contracts approach with interlinked moral hazard","authors":"J. Roy, Prabal Roy Chowdhury","doi":"10.1108/igdr-01-2019-0004","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1108/igdr-01-2019-0004","url":null,"abstract":"\u0000Purpose\u0000In a global environment where terrorist organisations based in a poor country target a rich nation, this paper aims to study the properties of a dynamically incentive compatible contract designed by the target nation that involves joint counter-terror tasks with costly participation by each country. The counter-terror operations are however subject to ex post moral hazard, so that to incentivise counter-terror, the rich country supplies developmental aid. Development aid also helps avoid unrest arising from counter-terror activities in the target nation. However, aid itself can be diverted to non-developmental projects, generating a novel interlinked moral hazard problem spanning both tasks and rewards.\u0000\u0000\u0000Design/methodology/approach\u0000The authors use a dynamic model where the aid giving countries and aid receiving countries behave strategically. Then they solve for the sub game perfect Nash equilibrium of this game.\u0000\u0000\u0000Findings\u0000The authors characterise the optimal contract, showing that the dynamic structure of counter-terror resembles the shock-and-awe discussed by military strategists. The authors then prove that it is not necessarily the case that a more hawkish (resp. altruistic) donor is less pro-development (resp. softer on terror). In addition, the authors show that it may be easier to contract for higher counter-terror inputs when the recipient is more sympathetic to terrorists. The authors also discuss other problems faced by developing nations where this model can be readily adopted and the results can endorse appealing policy implications.\u0000\u0000\u0000Originality/value\u0000The authors characterise the optimal contract, showing that the dynamic structure of counter-terror resembles the shock-and-awe discussed by military strategists. It is proved that it is not necessarily the case that a more hawkish (resp. altruistic) donor is less pro-development (resp. softer on terror). In addition, the authors show that it may be easier to contract for higher counter-terror inputs when the recipient is more sympathetic to terrorists. Other problems faced by developing nations are also discussed where this model can be readily adopted, and the results can endorse appealing policy implications. These results have important policy implications, in particular in today’s world.\u0000","PeriodicalId":42861,"journal":{"name":"Indian Growth and Development Review","volume":" ","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":1.4,"publicationDate":"2019-10-29","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1108/igdr-01-2019-0004","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"48409302","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Leadership preferences and ethnic bargaining: theory and illustrations 领导偏好与种族讨价还价:理论与例证
IF 1.4 Q4 DEVELOPMENT STUDIES Pub Date : 2019-10-18 DOI: 10.1108/igdr-07-2019-0070
S. Horowitz, Min Ye
PurposeIn explaining ethno-territorial conflicts, leadership preferences have an odd status. In case studies, leadership preferences are often viewed as highly significant causes but are not usually defined and measured explicitly. In large-sample statistical studies, leadership preferences are only captured by weakly related proxy variables. This paper aims to fill this gap by developing suitable theory, which can be used consistently in both case study and statistical applications.Design/methodology/approachFormal bargaining models are used to examine the expected impact of variation in leadership preferences. Relevant leadership characteristics are then used to construct measures of variation in leadership preferences, which are applied in case studies.FindingsIn bargaining models, variation in leadership preferences is expected to have a significant impact on ethno-territorial conflict outcomes. More extreme nationalist leaders and, more conditionally, strongly power-seeking leaders, should be more likely to be willing to use force to modify the status quo – although more moderate nationalist leaderships are also willing to do so under certain conditions. In five case studies, these formally derived hypotheses receive initial empirical support.Originality/valueTheoretically and empirically, further refinement of research on variation in leadership preferences promises to add significant value. Formally, it is worth investigating the expected impact of additional preference types. Empirically, it is important to invest in measures of leadership preferences across large samples.
目的在解释民族-领土冲突时,领导偏好具有奇怪的地位。在案例研究中,领导偏好通常被视为非常重要的原因,但通常没有明确定义和衡量。在大样本统计研究中,领导偏好只被弱相关的代理变量所捕获。本文旨在通过开发合适的理论来填补这一空白,这些理论可以在案例研究和统计应用中得到一致的应用。设计/方法论/方法正式的谈判模型用于检验领导偏好变化的预期影响。然后,利用相关的领导特征来构建领导偏好变化的衡量标准,并将其应用于案例研究。发现在谈判模型中,领导偏好的变化预计会对种族-领土冲突的结果产生重大影响。更极端的民族主义领导人,以及更有条件的强烈追求权力的领导人,应该更有可能愿意使用武力来改变现状——尽管在某些条件下,更温和的民族主义领袖也愿意这样做。在五个案例研究中,这些正式推导的假设得到了初步的实证支持。原创性/价值从理论和经验上讲,对领导偏好变化的研究的进一步完善有望增加显著的价值。从形式上讲,值得研究额外偏好类型的预期影响。从经验上讲,投资于衡量大样本中的领导偏好是很重要的。
{"title":"Leadership preferences and ethnic bargaining: theory and illustrations","authors":"S. Horowitz, Min Ye","doi":"10.1108/igdr-07-2019-0070","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1108/igdr-07-2019-0070","url":null,"abstract":"\u0000Purpose\u0000In explaining ethno-territorial conflicts, leadership preferences have an odd status. In case studies, leadership preferences are often viewed as highly significant causes but are not usually defined and measured explicitly. In large-sample statistical studies, leadership preferences are only captured by weakly related proxy variables. This paper aims to fill this gap by developing suitable theory, which can be used consistently in both case study and statistical applications.\u0000\u0000\u0000Design/methodology/approach\u0000Formal bargaining models are used to examine the expected impact of variation in leadership preferences. Relevant leadership characteristics are then used to construct measures of variation in leadership preferences, which are applied in case studies.\u0000\u0000\u0000Findings\u0000In bargaining models, variation in leadership preferences is expected to have a significant impact on ethno-territorial conflict outcomes. More extreme nationalist leaders and, more conditionally, strongly power-seeking leaders, should be more likely to be willing to use force to modify the status quo – although more moderate nationalist leaderships are also willing to do so under certain conditions. In five case studies, these formally derived hypotheses receive initial empirical support.\u0000\u0000\u0000Originality/value\u0000Theoretically and empirically, further refinement of research on variation in leadership preferences promises to add significant value. Formally, it is worth investigating the expected impact of additional preference types. Empirically, it is important to invest in measures of leadership preferences across large samples.\u0000","PeriodicalId":42861,"journal":{"name":"Indian Growth and Development Review","volume":" ","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":1.4,"publicationDate":"2019-10-18","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1108/igdr-07-2019-0070","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"49525381","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Terrorism risk and optimal policy response: theory and empirics 恐怖主义风险与最优政策应对:理论与经验
IF 1.4 Q4 DEVELOPMENT STUDIES Pub Date : 2019-10-18 DOI: 10.1108/igdr-08-2019-0090
H. Mohtadi, Bryan S. Weber
PurposeThe proliferation of terrorism worldwide raises the risk that terrorist strategies could evolve from conventional methods (e.g. suicide attacks) to biological, chemical and even radioactive and nuclear attacks (commonly abbreviated as CBRN) which are potentially much more dangerous. The authors make three contributions toward a better understanding of this risk and how it responds to counterterrorism measures.Design/methodology/approachThe authors develop a game that captures the terrorists’ potential strategic substitution between conventional and CBRN-type attacks; the authors calibrate the parameters of the game to real data using a novel calibration method and a partially unique dataset; they estimate the heavy-tailed distribution of attack severity and thus the probability of a successful attack, the underlying effort to launch an attack and the intrinsic difficulty of launching different types of attacks.FindingsThe authors find that in equilibrium, CBRN attacks, though less likely and more difficult to execute, are more deadly. In the end, the trade-off between, on one hand, the greater difficulty of carrying out a CBRN attack, and on the other, the greater deadliness of such an attack, points to a level of optimal counterterrorism spending by governments that weighs toward defending against CBRN attacks. The authors discuss these results and compare them with the actual level of counterterrorism spending by the US Government.Originality/valueThe framework of the game allows for substitution between the conventional and CBRN weapon types. These aspects of this paper, together with the unique calibration methodology, and the use of some unique terrorism data for the first time, are what distinguish this work from similar game theoretic papers in this area.
世界范围内恐怖主义的扩散增加了恐怖主义战略可能从传统方法(例如自杀式袭击)演变为潜在危险得多的生物,化学甚至放射性和核攻击(通常缩写为CBRN)的风险。为了更好地理解这种风险及其对反恐措施的反应,作者做出了三点贡献。设计/方法/方法作者开发了一个游戏,捕捉恐怖分子在传统和cbrn类型攻击之间的潜在战略替代;作者使用一种新颖的校准方法和部分唯一的数据集将游戏参数校准为真实数据;他们估计攻击严重程度的重尾分布,从而估计攻击成功的概率,发动攻击的潜在努力以及发动不同类型攻击的内在难度。研究结果作者发现,在平衡状态下,尽管CBRN攻击的可能性更小,实施起来也更困难,但却更致命。最后,一方面,实施CBRN袭击的难度更大,另一方面,这种袭击的致命性更大,两者之间的权衡表明,政府在反恐方面的最佳支出水平是倾向于防御CBRN袭击的。作者讨论了这些结果,并将其与美国政府反恐支出的实际水平进行了比较。游戏框架允许在常规武器和CBRN武器类型之间进行替换。本文的这些方面,加上独特的校准方法,以及首次使用一些独特的恐怖主义数据,是本研究与该领域类似博弈论论文的区别所在。
{"title":"Terrorism risk and optimal policy response: theory and empirics","authors":"H. Mohtadi, Bryan S. Weber","doi":"10.1108/igdr-08-2019-0090","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1108/igdr-08-2019-0090","url":null,"abstract":"\u0000Purpose\u0000The proliferation of terrorism worldwide raises the risk that terrorist strategies could evolve from conventional methods (e.g. suicide attacks) to biological, chemical and even radioactive and nuclear attacks (commonly abbreviated as CBRN) which are potentially much more dangerous. The authors make three contributions toward a better understanding of this risk and how it responds to counterterrorism measures.\u0000\u0000\u0000Design/methodology/approach\u0000The authors develop a game that captures the terrorists’ potential strategic substitution between conventional and CBRN-type attacks; the authors calibrate the parameters of the game to real data using a novel calibration method and a partially unique dataset; they estimate the heavy-tailed distribution of attack severity and thus the probability of a successful attack, the underlying effort to launch an attack and the intrinsic difficulty of launching different types of attacks.\u0000\u0000\u0000Findings\u0000The authors find that in equilibrium, CBRN attacks, though less likely and more difficult to execute, are more deadly. In the end, the trade-off between, on one hand, the greater difficulty of carrying out a CBRN attack, and on the other, the greater deadliness of such an attack, points to a level of optimal counterterrorism spending by governments that weighs toward defending against CBRN attacks. The authors discuss these results and compare them with the actual level of counterterrorism spending by the US Government.\u0000\u0000\u0000Originality/value\u0000The framework of the game allows for substitution between the conventional and CBRN weapon types. These aspects of this paper, together with the unique calibration methodology, and the use of some unique terrorism data for the first time, are what distinguish this work from similar game theoretic papers in this area.\u0000","PeriodicalId":42861,"journal":{"name":"Indian Growth and Development Review","volume":" ","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":1.4,"publicationDate":"2019-10-18","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1108/igdr-08-2019-0090","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"46781060","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Understanding subnational conflicts in Myanmar 了解缅甸的地方冲突
IF 1.4 Q4 DEVELOPMENT STUDIES Pub Date : 2019-10-14 DOI: 10.1108/igdr-08-2019-0084
Partha Gangopadhyay, Siddharth Jain
PurposeThis paper aims to examine the interrelationships between subnational conflicts in Myanmar and other variables of interests from the following four major domains: economic, human security and vulnerability of people, aggressiveness or militancy of the armed forces and global and regional climates.Design/methodology/approachAutoregressive distributed lag (ARDL) bounds testing approach has been applied on annual data from 1960-2017, to deal with the problems of autocorrelation and non-stationarity of key variables.FindingsFirst, an increase in crop yield, cereal productivity, food productivity and per capita availability of arable land unequivocally and significantly lower the severity of conflict in Myanmar in the long run. Second, the authors uncover strong evidence that the intensity of conflicts bears a positive relationship with the vulnerability of the people of Myanmar. Third, the authors detect that both regional and global climate variables have limited and rather inconsistent impacts on subnational conflicts in Myanmar. Finally, the authors find that the aggressiveness (militancy index) of the armed forces has significant impacts upon subnational conflicts and economic variables of Myanmar in the long run.Originality/valueThis paper is completely data-driven and explains the long-term dynamics of the intensity of the civil war in Myanmar. ARDL bounds testing approach has been used to examine the interrelationships between subnational conflicts in Myanmar and other variables of interests. It is a novel approach, which overcomes the problems of autocorrelation and nonstationarity and offers reliable results.
目的本文旨在从以下四个主要领域考察缅甸地方冲突与其他利益变量之间的相互关系:经济、人的安全和人民的脆弱性、武装部队的侵略性或战斗性以及全球和地区气候。设计/方法/方法自回归分布滞后(ARDL)边界检验方法已应用于1960-2017年的年度数据,以解决关键变量的自相关和非平稳性问题。发现首先,从长远来看,作物产量、谷物生产率、粮食生产率和人均可耕地面积的增加明确而显著地降低了缅甸冲突的严重程度。其次,作者发现了强有力的证据,证明冲突的激烈程度与缅甸人民的脆弱性有着积极的关系。第三,作者发现,区域和全球气候变量对缅甸国内冲突的影响有限,而且相当不一致。最后,作者发现,从长远来看,武装部队的侵略性(战斗指数)对缅甸的国家以下冲突和经济变量有重大影响。原创性/价值本文完全由数据驱动,解释了缅甸内战强度的长期动态。ARDL边界检验方法已被用于检验缅甸地方冲突与其他利益变量之间的相互关系。这是一种新的方法,它克服了自相关和非平稳性的问题,并提供了可靠的结果。
{"title":"Understanding subnational conflicts in Myanmar","authors":"Partha Gangopadhyay, Siddharth Jain","doi":"10.1108/igdr-08-2019-0084","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1108/igdr-08-2019-0084","url":null,"abstract":"\u0000Purpose\u0000This paper aims to examine the interrelationships between subnational conflicts in Myanmar and other variables of interests from the following four major domains: economic, human security and vulnerability of people, aggressiveness or militancy of the armed forces and global and regional climates.\u0000\u0000\u0000Design/methodology/approach\u0000Autoregressive distributed lag (ARDL) bounds testing approach has been applied on annual data from 1960-2017, to deal with the problems of autocorrelation and non-stationarity of key variables.\u0000\u0000\u0000Findings\u0000First, an increase in crop yield, cereal productivity, food productivity and per capita availability of arable land unequivocally and significantly lower the severity of conflict in Myanmar in the long run. Second, the authors uncover strong evidence that the intensity of conflicts bears a positive relationship with the vulnerability of the people of Myanmar. Third, the authors detect that both regional and global climate variables have limited and rather inconsistent impacts on subnational conflicts in Myanmar. Finally, the authors find that the aggressiveness (militancy index) of the armed forces has significant impacts upon subnational conflicts and economic variables of Myanmar in the long run.\u0000\u0000\u0000Originality/value\u0000This paper is completely data-driven and explains the long-term dynamics of the intensity of the civil war in Myanmar. ARDL bounds testing approach has been used to examine the interrelationships between subnational conflicts in Myanmar and other variables of interests. It is a novel approach, which overcomes the problems of autocorrelation and nonstationarity and offers reliable results.\u0000","PeriodicalId":42861,"journal":{"name":"Indian Growth and Development Review","volume":" ","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":1.4,"publicationDate":"2019-10-14","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1108/igdr-08-2019-0084","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"46416830","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2
Industry level analysis of productivity growth under market imperfections 市场不完善条件下生产率增长的行业层面分析
IF 1.4 Q4 DEVELOPMENT STUDIES Pub Date : 2019-10-09 DOI: 10.1108/igdr-11-2018-0115
R. Kumar, M. Paul
PurposeThis study aims to estimate total factor productivity (TFP) growth for the post-2008 period for selected industries in the manufacturing sector at NIC 3-digit. Total factor productivity growth (TFPG) estimates are based on the theoretical framework provided by studies such Hall (1988), Abraham et al. (2009) and Crepon et al. (2005) that incorporate market imperfection in labour and product market, thereby modifying the traditional TFP estimation as Solow Residual.Design/methodology/approachBased on the theoretical model that incorporates market imperfections in labour as well as product market in modifying the TFP estimates using the Levinsohn–Petrin framework of empirical estimation, the authors have calculated industry wise TFPG for 62 industries at NIC 3-digit level.FindingsThe study finds three distinct trends: first, there are considerable industrial disparities in productivity growth in terms of TFP. The estimates have been found to be higher than the conventional Solow Residual for most industries, indicating the role played by market imperfections in affecting the conventional measure of productivity growth. Second, estimates of bargaining power are found to be lower than those compared to the earlier estimates in Maiti (2013) for the Indian organised manufacturing case for 1998-2005. This observation is commensurate with the observation in recent years of a falling share in labour wage in total output in organised manufacturing sector. Finally, the study also found a statistically significant contribution of greater mechanisation on TFPG while an adverse effect of the rising dependence of organised manufacturing on contractual labour.Originality/valueThe role of market imperfections in measuring TFPG has been undertaken, and it has been found to be an important factor, as the estimated measures vary from the conventional measures of TFPG. Moreover, the study has considered a very recent period from 2008-2015 in estimating TFPG, as well as analysing the factors behind the trends in TFPG at industrial level.
目的本研究旨在估计2008年后制造业中选定行业的全要素生产率(TFP)以NIC 3位数增长。全要素生产率增长(TFPG)估计基于Hall(1988)、Abraham等(2009)和Crepon等(2005)等研究提供的理论框架,这些研究将劳动力和产品市场的市场不完全性纳入其中,从而将传统的全要素生产率估计修改为索洛残差。设计/方法/方法基于理论模型,结合劳动力和产品市场的市场缺陷,使用经验估计的Levinsohn-Petrin框架修改TFP估计,作者计算了62个行业在NIC 3位数水平上的行业明智的TFP。研究发现了三个明显的趋势:首先,就全要素生产率而言,生产率增长存在相当大的产业差异。研究发现,对于大多数行业,这些估计值高于传统的索洛残差,这表明市场不完善在影响传统的生产率增长衡量标准方面所起的作用。其次,与Maiti(2013)对1998-2005年印度有组织制造业案例的早期估计相比,对议价能力的估计要低。这一观察结果与近年来有组织制造业劳动工资在总产出中所占比例下降的观察结果相符。最后,该研究还发现,在统计上,更大的机械化对TFPG的贡献是显著的,而有组织的制造业对合同劳动力依赖程度的上升则产生了不利影响。原创性/价值市场不完善在衡量TFPG中的作用已经进行了研究,并且已经发现它是一个重要因素,因为估计的措施与传统的TFPG措施不同。此外,该研究考虑了2008-2015年这段非常近的时期来估计TFPG,并分析了工业水平上TFPG趋势背后的因素。
{"title":"Industry level analysis of productivity growth under market imperfections","authors":"R. Kumar, M. Paul","doi":"10.1108/igdr-11-2018-0115","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1108/igdr-11-2018-0115","url":null,"abstract":"\u0000Purpose\u0000This study aims to estimate total factor productivity (TFP) growth for the post-2008 period for selected industries in the manufacturing sector at NIC 3-digit. Total factor productivity growth (TFPG) estimates are based on the theoretical framework provided by studies such Hall (1988), Abraham et al. (2009) and Crepon et al. (2005) that incorporate market imperfection in labour and product market, thereby modifying the traditional TFP estimation as Solow Residual.\u0000\u0000\u0000Design/methodology/approach\u0000Based on the theoretical model that incorporates market imperfections in labour as well as product market in modifying the TFP estimates using the Levinsohn–Petrin framework of empirical estimation, the authors have calculated industry wise TFPG for 62 industries at NIC 3-digit level.\u0000\u0000\u0000Findings\u0000The study finds three distinct trends: first, there are considerable industrial disparities in productivity growth in terms of TFP. The estimates have been found to be higher than the conventional Solow Residual for most industries, indicating the role played by market imperfections in affecting the conventional measure of productivity growth. Second, estimates of bargaining power are found to be lower than those compared to the earlier estimates in Maiti (2013) for the Indian organised manufacturing case for 1998-2005. This observation is commensurate with the observation in recent years of a falling share in labour wage in total output in organised manufacturing sector. Finally, the study also found a statistically significant contribution of greater mechanisation on TFPG while an adverse effect of the rising dependence of organised manufacturing on contractual labour.\u0000\u0000\u0000Originality/value\u0000The role of market imperfections in measuring TFPG has been undertaken, and it has been found to be an important factor, as the estimated measures vary from the conventional measures of TFPG. Moreover, the study has considered a very recent period from 2008-2015 in estimating TFPG, as well as analysing the factors behind the trends in TFPG at industrial level.\u0000","PeriodicalId":42861,"journal":{"name":"Indian Growth and Development Review","volume":" ","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":1.4,"publicationDate":"2019-10-09","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1108/igdr-11-2018-0115","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"43081092","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 8
Conflict, caste and resolution: a quantitative analysis for Indian villages 冲突、种姓制度与解决:对印度村庄的定量分析
IF 1.4 Q4 DEVELOPMENT STUDIES Pub Date : 2019-10-09 DOI: 10.1108/igdr-08-2019-0087
V. Borooah, A. Tagat, V. Mishra
PurposeThe purpose of this paper is to provide a quantitative assessment of caste-based conflict in India. The data for this paper are from the Rural Economic and Demographic Survey (REDS) of 2006 encompassing 8,659 households in 242 villages in 18 Indian states.Design/methodology/approachUsing these data, the authors examine two broad issues: the sources of conflict in rural India and the degree to which these sources contribute to caste-basted, as opposed to non-caste-based conflict; the sources of conflict resolution in rural India: are some conflict-resolving agencies more effective at dealing with caste-based conflicts and others more effective with non-caste-based conflicts?FindingsThere was a rise in caste-based conflict over the (approximate) period 1996-2006. There are several reasons for the rise in caste-based conflict but, in the main, is the rise in assertiveness of persons belonging to India’s lower castes. In terms of conflict resolution, panchayats and prominent individuals were important in resolving village conflicts: 69 per cent of caste-based, and 65 per cent of non-caste based, conflicts were resolved by one or the other of these two agents.Originality/valueThis is the first attempt, using econometric methodology, to study caste conflict at a village level in India.
本文的目的是对印度基于种姓的冲突进行定量评估。本文的数据来自2006年农村经济和人口调查(REDS),涵盖了印度18个邦242个村庄的8659户家庭。利用这些数据,作者研究了两个广泛的问题:印度农村冲突的根源,以及这些根源在多大程度上导致了基于种姓的冲突,而不是基于种姓的冲突;印度农村冲突解决的根源:一些冲突解决机构在处理基于种姓的冲突方面更有效,而其他机构在处理非种姓冲突方面更有效吗?研究结果:在1996年至2006年(大致)期间,基于种姓的冲突有所增加。种姓冲突的增加有几个原因,但最主要的原因是印度较低种姓的人越来越自信。在解决冲突方面,村务委员会和知名人士在解决村庄冲突方面很重要:69%的种姓冲突和65%的非种姓冲突由这两种机构中的一种或另一种解决。原创性/价值这是第一次尝试使用计量经济学方法来研究印度村庄层面的种姓冲突。
{"title":"Conflict, caste and resolution: a quantitative analysis for Indian villages","authors":"V. Borooah, A. Tagat, V. Mishra","doi":"10.1108/igdr-08-2019-0087","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1108/igdr-08-2019-0087","url":null,"abstract":"\u0000Purpose\u0000The purpose of this paper is to provide a quantitative assessment of caste-based conflict in India. The data for this paper are from the Rural Economic and Demographic Survey (REDS) of 2006 encompassing 8,659 households in 242 villages in 18 Indian states.\u0000\u0000\u0000Design/methodology/approach\u0000Using these data, the authors examine two broad issues: the sources of conflict in rural India and the degree to which these sources contribute to caste-basted, as opposed to non-caste-based conflict; the sources of conflict resolution in rural India: are some conflict-resolving agencies more effective at dealing with caste-based conflicts and others more effective with non-caste-based conflicts?\u0000\u0000\u0000Findings\u0000There was a rise in caste-based conflict over the (approximate) period 1996-2006. There are several reasons for the rise in caste-based conflict but, in the main, is the rise in assertiveness of persons belonging to India’s lower castes. In terms of conflict resolution, panchayats and prominent individuals were important in resolving village conflicts: 69 per cent of caste-based, and 65 per cent of non-caste based, conflicts were resolved by one or the other of these two agents.\u0000\u0000\u0000Originality/value\u0000This is the first attempt, using econometric methodology, to study caste conflict at a village level in India.\u0000","PeriodicalId":42861,"journal":{"name":"Indian Growth and Development Review","volume":" ","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":1.4,"publicationDate":"2019-10-09","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1108/igdr-08-2019-0087","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"47232612","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2
Determinants of total factor productivity in Indian states 印度各邦全要素生产率的决定因素
IF 1.4 Q4 DEVELOPMENT STUDIES Pub Date : 2019-10-09 DOI: 10.1108/igdr-01-2019-0008
B. S. Misra
PurposeThis paper aims to compute total factor productivity (TFP) growth for India as well as for its 19 major states and to explore the determinants of TFP at the state level by considering the spillover effects.Design/methodology/approachTFP growth has been obtained using growth accounting equation. Further, the TFP growth estimates were used to derive TFP levels using the translog index procedure. Given the policy focus on building infrastructure and expanding financial access, we have estimated the impact of irrigation, electricity, road, health, education and financial depth on TFP using the Spatial Durbin Model to account for spillover effects.FindingsComputing TFP growth for two sub periods, namely, 2001-2008 and 2009-2015, the study finds a deterioration in TFP growth for India as well as for 10 of the 19 states under study in the post global financial crisis period. The author find that TFP is positively impacted by irrigation, health and road infrastructure. While financial depth and education were statistically insignificant, installed capacity of electricity had a negative impact on state level TFP.Research limitations/implications'The author provides rationale for the empirical findings considering the country context. The findings of this study act as pointers for shaping higher growth on a sustained basis in India. The study helps to assess the productivity growth in the new states, namely, Jharkhand, Chhattisgarh and Uttarakhand, that were carved out in 2000 vis a vis their parent states. This assessment is useful especially for the states of Jharkhand and Chhattisgarh which were created to address economic backwardness in certain pockets of the parent states.Originality/valueFirst, it provides TFPG estimates for India as well as 19 major states during the 2000-2015 period. Second, this study helps to understand how TFPG for India as well as each of the 19 states have behaved in the post global financial crisis period. Third, the study helps to assess the productivity growth in the three newly created states in 2000 vis a vis their parent states. Fourth, this is the first attempt which considers the spatial interdependence among the states to estimate the impact of financial and infrastructural development on productivity in the Indian states.
本文旨在计算印度及其19个主要邦的全要素生产率(TFP)增长,并通过考虑溢出效应,探讨邦一级全要素生产率的决定因素。设计/方法/方法tfp的增长是使用增长会计方程获得的。此外,TFP增长估计值被用于使用超对数指数程序推导TFP水平。鉴于政策重点是建设基础设施和扩大融资渠道,我们利用空间德宾模型(Spatial Durbin Model)估计了灌溉、电力、道路、卫生、教育和金融深度对全要素生产率的影响,以解释溢出效应。通过计算2001-2008年和2009-2015年两个子时期的全要素生产率增长,该研究发现,在全球金融危机后的时期,印度以及所研究的19个邦中的10个邦的全要素生产率增长出现恶化。研究发现,灌溉、卫生和道路基础设施对全要素生产率有正向影响。虽然金融深度和教育程度在统计上不显著,但电力装机容量对州一级TFP有负面影响。研究的局限性/启示:考虑到国家背景,作者提供了实证研究结果的基本原理。这项研究的结果为印度在持续的基础上实现更高的增长提供了指导。这项研究有助于评估2000年新成立的贾坎德邦、恰蒂斯加尔邦和北阿坎德邦相对于母邦的生产率增长情况。这一评估对贾坎德邦和恰蒂斯加尔邦特别有用,这两个邦是为了解决母邦某些地区的经济落后而创建的。首先,它提供了2000-2015年期间印度以及19个主要邦的TFPG估计。其次,本研究有助于了解印度以及19个邦的TFPG在后全球金融危机时期的表现。第三,该研究有助于评估2000年三个新成立的州相对于其母国的生产率增长。第四,这是第一次考虑到邦间的空间相互依赖,以估计印度邦的金融和基础设施发展对生产力的影响。
{"title":"Determinants of total factor productivity in Indian states","authors":"B. S. Misra","doi":"10.1108/igdr-01-2019-0008","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1108/igdr-01-2019-0008","url":null,"abstract":"\u0000Purpose\u0000This paper aims to compute total factor productivity (TFP) growth for India as well as for its 19 major states and to explore the determinants of TFP at the state level by considering the spillover effects.\u0000\u0000\u0000Design/methodology/approach\u0000TFP growth has been obtained using growth accounting equation. Further, the TFP growth estimates were used to derive TFP levels using the translog index procedure. Given the policy focus on building infrastructure and expanding financial access, we have estimated the impact of irrigation, electricity, road, health, education and financial depth on TFP using the Spatial Durbin Model to account for spillover effects.\u0000\u0000\u0000Findings\u0000Computing TFP growth for two sub periods, namely, 2001-2008 and 2009-2015, the study finds a deterioration in TFP growth for India as well as for 10 of the 19 states under study in the post global financial crisis period. The author find that TFP is positively impacted by irrigation, health and road infrastructure. While financial depth and education were statistically insignificant, installed capacity of electricity had a negative impact on state level TFP.\u0000\u0000\u0000Research limitations/implications\u0000'The author provides rationale for the empirical findings considering the country context. The findings of this study act as pointers for shaping higher growth on a sustained basis in India. The study helps to assess the productivity growth in the new states, namely, Jharkhand, Chhattisgarh and Uttarakhand, that were carved out in 2000 vis a vis their parent states. This assessment is useful especially for the states of Jharkhand and Chhattisgarh which were created to address economic backwardness in certain pockets of the parent states.\u0000\u0000\u0000Originality/value\u0000First, it provides TFPG estimates for India as well as 19 major states during the 2000-2015 period. Second, this study helps to understand how TFPG for India as well as each of the 19 states have behaved in the post global financial crisis period. Third, the study helps to assess the productivity growth in the three newly created states in 2000 vis a vis their parent states. Fourth, this is the first attempt which considers the spatial interdependence among the states to estimate the impact of financial and infrastructural development on productivity in the Indian states.\u0000","PeriodicalId":42861,"journal":{"name":"Indian Growth and Development Review","volume":" ","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":1.4,"publicationDate":"2019-10-09","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1108/igdr-01-2019-0008","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"43863598","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 6
Policies for resolving insurgencies – lessons from third-party intervention in India 解决叛乱的政策——印度第三方干预的经验教训
IF 1.4 Q4 DEVELOPMENT STUDIES Pub Date : 2019-09-23 DOI: 10.1108/igdr-04-2017-0033
D. Gupta
PurposeIn this paper, the author develops a game theoretical model to understand why Union Government of India, as a third party, has used different schemes at different times in history to assist the State Governments in fighting the Naxalite insurgency. Comparing across schemes, it was found that though Matching Security Grants scheme was preferred in general, during asymmetric information scenario it led to an emergency situation wherein the Union Government had to provide the less preferred Bulk Security Grants. Later, it became difficult to withdraw these grants as the State Governments free rode by reducing own security contribution. The author finds that instead, in this scenario, Matching Development Grants are more suitable, as they incentivize the State Governments to reveal private information and help the Union Government exit its third-party role. For a practitioner involved in conflict resolution, these conclusions imply that as the desirability of policies can change diametrically overtime, Union Government must spend resources only on those heads of expenditure that provide both security and development benefits provided they aid in preventing flow of resources to Naxalites. Further, to end its assistance, the Union Government’s expenditures should also complement the capabilities of the State Government rather than substituting them. These results can also guide policy in other protracted civil wars with substantial third-party intervention, which are common these days.Design/methodology/approachThe paper is an historical analysis of strategies used by Union and State Governments and Naxalites. The analysis is based on game theoretic tools supported with examples.FindingsThe Union Government must provide matching grants instead of bulk grants such as Central Armed Police Forces, and the grants should be aimed at building complementarities with the state governments’ security contributions. Under asymmetric information scenario, the Union and State Governments reduce their expenses incurred to fight the Naxalites. A Matching Development Grants scheme would have done better. Union Government must spend resources on heads of expenditure that provides both Development and Security benefits, to curb flow of resources to Naxalites, besides complementing the Security Contributions of the State Government.Research limitations/implicationsThe research is limited by disaggregated data to test the hypotheses. It is also limited by the data on hidden variables like the contribution of the Naxalites to fighting. The research is also limited to the extent that individual groups in the war like police commanders, politicians and Naxalite commanders are not incorporated. Multiple asymmetric parties are also not considered; that may generalize the model to other theaters of insurgency.Practical implicationsCertain heads of expenditure such as roads, mobile communication, improving quality of investigation, preventing human right
目的在本文中,作者建立了一个博弈论模型来理解为什么印度联邦政府作为第三方在历史的不同时期使用不同的方案来协助邦政府打击纳萨尔派叛乱。通过对不同方案的比较,发现尽管匹配安全补助金方案总体上是首选方案,但在信息不对称的情况下,它导致了紧急情况,联邦政府不得不提供不太首选的批量安全补助金。后来,由于各州政府通过减少自己的安全捐款来搭便车,因此很难撤回这些赠款。作者发现,相反,在这种情况下,匹配发展补助金更合适,因为它们激励州政府披露私人信息,并帮助联邦政府退出其第三方角色。对于参与解决冲突的从业者来说,这些结论意味着,由于政策的可取性可能会随着时间的推移而发生根本性的变化,联邦政府必须仅将资源用于那些既能提供安全利益又能带来发展利益的支出目上,前提是这些支出目有助于防止资源流向纳萨尔派。此外,为了结束其援助,联邦政府的支出也应补充州政府的能力,而不是取而代之。这些结果也可以指导其他旷日持久的内战中的政策,而第三方的大量干预目前很常见。设计/方法论/方法本文是对联邦和州政府以及纳萨尔派使用的战略的历史分析。该分析基于博弈论工具并辅以实例。发现联邦政府必须提供配套拨款,而不是中央武装警察部队等大量拨款,这些拨款应旨在与州政府的安全捐款建立互补性。在信息不对称的情况下,联邦政府和州政府减少了与纳萨尔派作战的费用。配套发展补助金计划会做得更好。联邦政府除了补充州政府的安全贡献外,还必须将资源用于提供发展和安全福利的支出,以遏制资源流向纳萨尔派。研究局限性/含义研究受到分类数据的限制,以检验假设。它还受到隐藏变量数据的限制,比如纳萨尔派对战斗的贡献。这项研究也局限于战争中的个别群体,如警察指挥官、政治家和纳萨尔派指挥官,没有被纳入其中。多个不对称方也不被考虑;这可能会将该模型推广到其他叛乱地区。实际意义某些支出项目,如道路、移动通信、提高调查质量、防止安全部队侵犯人权等,既有利于安全,也有利于发展。联邦政府的支出必须用于此目的。因此,从从业者的角度来看,贪婪与委屈之间的争论并不是一种限制,而是一种引导。必须根据这些原则重新起草《印度宪法》的相关条款。根据这些结论,可以重新审视第三方对其他叛乱的干预。社会影响安全和发展政策是控制纳萨尔派叛乱的工具,也可用于防止资源流向纳萨尔派。解决叛乱的安全和发展政策在不同的信息场景下都很有用。因此,应首选信息中立的策略。原创性/价值本文在建模纳萨尔派叛乱等持续冲突方面做出了明确的理论贡献。作者还表明,尽管内战领域可能是随着贪婪与悲伤的辩论而演变的(Collier和Hoeffler,2004),但对于从业者来说,在解决方案方面,界限是模糊的,因为许多支出主管都具有安全和发展的特征。本文还表明,当联邦政府面临信息不对称的情况时,匹配发展补助金的政策虽然在短期内价值有限,但从长远来看是有益的。这是一个重要的结论,因为在最激烈的暴力时期之前是信息不对称的情况。此外,它还与其他有第三方干预的内战有关,例如北约在阿富汗的干预。
{"title":"Policies for resolving insurgencies – lessons from third-party intervention in India","authors":"D. Gupta","doi":"10.1108/igdr-04-2017-0033","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1108/igdr-04-2017-0033","url":null,"abstract":"\u0000Purpose\u0000In this paper, the author develops a game theoretical model to understand why Union Government of India, as a third party, has used different schemes at different times in history to assist the State Governments in fighting the Naxalite insurgency. Comparing across schemes, it was found that though Matching Security Grants scheme was preferred in general, during asymmetric information scenario it led to an emergency situation wherein the Union Government had to provide the less preferred Bulk Security Grants. Later, it became difficult to withdraw these grants as the State Governments free rode by reducing own security contribution. The author finds that instead, in this scenario, Matching Development Grants are more suitable, as they incentivize the State Governments to reveal private information and help the Union Government exit its third-party role. For a practitioner involved in conflict resolution, these conclusions imply that as the desirability of policies can change diametrically overtime, Union Government must spend resources only on those heads of expenditure that provide both security and development benefits provided they aid in preventing flow of resources to Naxalites. Further, to end its assistance, the Union Government’s expenditures should also complement the capabilities of the State Government rather than substituting them. These results can also guide policy in other protracted civil wars with substantial third-party intervention, which are common these days.\u0000\u0000\u0000Design/methodology/approach\u0000The paper is an historical analysis of strategies used by Union and State Governments and Naxalites. The analysis is based on game theoretic tools supported with examples.\u0000\u0000\u0000Findings\u0000The Union Government must provide matching grants instead of bulk grants such as Central Armed Police Forces, and the grants should be aimed at building complementarities with the state governments’ security contributions. Under asymmetric information scenario, the Union and State Governments reduce their expenses incurred to fight the Naxalites. A Matching Development Grants scheme would have done better. Union Government must spend resources on heads of expenditure that provides both Development and Security benefits, to curb flow of resources to Naxalites, besides complementing the Security Contributions of the State Government.\u0000\u0000\u0000Research limitations/implications\u0000The research is limited by disaggregated data to test the hypotheses. It is also limited by the data on hidden variables like the contribution of the Naxalites to fighting. The research is also limited to the extent that individual groups in the war like police commanders, politicians and Naxalite commanders are not incorporated. Multiple asymmetric parties are also not considered; that may generalize the model to other theaters of insurgency.\u0000\u0000\u0000Practical implications\u0000Certain heads of expenditure such as roads, mobile communication, improving quality of investigation, preventing human right","PeriodicalId":42861,"journal":{"name":"Indian Growth and Development Review","volume":" ","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":1.4,"publicationDate":"2019-09-23","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1108/igdr-04-2017-0033","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"48147072","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
期刊
Indian Growth and Development Review
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1