首页 > 最新文献

Australian Economic Papers最新文献

英文 中文
The tone from above: Does tunnelling by ultimate owners impinge on the relations between managerial compensation and earnings management? 上面的基调是:最终所有者的挖洞行为是否会影响管理层薪酬与盈余管理之间的关系?
IF 1.9 4区 经济学 Q2 Economics, Econometrics and Finance Pub Date : 2022-06-24 DOI: 10.1111/1467-8454.12270
Wenzhou Li, Liang Chen, Pengfei Sheng

This study aims to explore the impact of tunnelling by ultimate owners on the relation between managerial compensation and earnings management. Using a sample of the Chinese listed firms from 2009 to 2019, we find that tunnelling by ultimate owners leads to adjustments in pay-performance sensitivity and impinges on the magnitude of earnings management. In private-dominated firms, tunnelling by ultimate owners reduces pay-performance sensitivity, and the decreased pay-performance incentives do not motivate managers to inflate corporate profits by manipulating earnings information. Moreover, owing to managers' resistances, tunnelling does not generate more severe problems in the quality of earnings information. In state-dominated firms, due to government regulation, tunnelling by ultimate owners does not induce significant adjustments in pay-performance sensitivity. However, due to the strong motivation of managers delighting their superiors in the administrative hierarchy by adjusting financial reporting, the quality of earnings information of state-dominated firms may be worse. Our results suggest that in firms with concentrated ownership structures-irrespective of the nature of ownership, both the formulation and implementation of managerial compensation incentive programmes, and the magnitude of earnings management, are equilibrium results of a dynamic game between ultimate owners and managers.

本研究旨在探讨最终所有者掏空行为对管理层薪酬与盈余管理关系的影响。以2009 - 2019年的中国上市公司为样本,我们发现最终所有者的掏空导致薪酬绩效敏感性的调整,并影响盈余管理的规模。在私人主导的企业中,最终所有者的挖掘降低了薪酬绩效的敏感性,而薪酬绩效激励的减少也不会激励管理者通过操纵盈利信息来夸大公司利润。此外,由于管理者的抵制,隧道挖掘不会对盈余信息的质量产生更严重的问题。在国有企业中,由于政府监管,最终所有者挖隧道并不会引起薪酬绩效敏感性的重大调整。然而,由于管理者通过调整财务报告取悦上级的强烈动机,国有控股企业的盈余信息质量可能更差。我们的研究结果表明,在所有权结构集中的公司中,无论所有权的性质如何,管理层薪酬激励计划的制定和实施,以及盈余管理的规模,都是最终所有者和管理者之间动态博弈的均衡结果。
{"title":"The tone from above: Does tunnelling by ultimate owners impinge on the relations between managerial compensation and earnings management?","authors":"Wenzhou Li,&nbsp;Liang Chen,&nbsp;Pengfei Sheng","doi":"10.1111/1467-8454.12270","DOIUrl":"10.1111/1467-8454.12270","url":null,"abstract":"<p>This study aims to explore the impact of tunnelling by ultimate owners on the relation between managerial compensation and earnings management. Using a sample of the Chinese listed firms from 2009 to 2019, we find that tunnelling by ultimate owners leads to adjustments in pay-performance sensitivity and impinges on the magnitude of earnings management. In private-dominated firms, tunnelling by ultimate owners reduces pay-performance sensitivity, and the decreased pay-performance incentives do not motivate managers to inflate corporate profits by manipulating earnings information. Moreover, owing to managers' resistances, tunnelling does not generate more severe problems in the quality of earnings information. In state-dominated firms, due to government regulation, tunnelling by ultimate owners does not induce significant adjustments in pay-performance sensitivity. However, due to the strong motivation of managers delighting their superiors in the administrative hierarchy by adjusting financial reporting, the quality of earnings information of state-dominated firms may be worse. Our results suggest that in firms with concentrated ownership structures-irrespective of the nature of ownership, both the formulation and implementation of managerial compensation incentive programmes, and the magnitude of earnings management, are equilibrium results of a dynamic game between ultimate owners and managers.</p>","PeriodicalId":46169,"journal":{"name":"Australian Economic Papers","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":1.9,"publicationDate":"2022-06-24","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"46688012","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
How do FDI inflows curvilinearly affect carbon emissions? Threshold effects of energy service availability and cleanliness FDI流入如何以曲线形式影响碳排放?能源服务可获得性和清洁度的阈值效应
IF 1.9 4区 经济学 Q2 Economics, Econometrics and Finance Pub Date : 2022-06-22 DOI: 10.1111/1467-8454.12273
Fuzhong Chen, Guohai Jiang, Kangyin Dong

To examine the relationship between foreign direct investment (FDI) inflows and carbon emissions from the perspective of the threshold effects of energy service availability and energy consumption cleanliness, this study employs the panel data of 16 Regional Comprehensive Economic Partnership member countries for the period 1990–2019. Using panel threshold models, this study finds that energy service availability and energy consumption cleanliness are two significant threshold variables in the process by which FDI inflows affect carbon emissions. Before they reach a certain level, FDI inflows aggravate carbon emissions, but this association becomes negative after reaching the threshold level. Furthermore, this study also indicates that the threshold values are different depending on national conditions. Specifically, countries with favourable technological development or stronger environmental regulations have lower threshold values for the two variables, while countries with a higher degree of industrial added value have higher threshold values. Based on these findings, this study recommends enhancing energy service availability and energy consumption cleanliness and formulating related industrial, technological and legal policies based on different national conditions.

为了从能源服务可获得性和能源消费清洁度阈值效应的角度考察外国直接投资(FDI)流入与碳排放的关系,本研究采用了1990-2019年16个区域全面经济伙伴关系(rcep)成员国的面板数据。利用面板阈值模型,研究发现能源服务可获得性和能源消费清洁度是FDI流入影响碳排放过程中的两个显著阈值变量。在达到一定水平之前,FDI流入加剧了碳排放,但在达到阈值水平后,这种关联变为负相关。此外,本研究还表明,阈值因国情而异。具体而言,技术发展较好或环境法规较强的国家,这两个变量的阈值较低,而工业增加值较高的国家,这两个变量的阈值较高。在此基础上,本研究建议提高能源服务可及性和能源消费清洁度,并根据不同国情制定相关的产业、技术和法律政策。
{"title":"How do FDI inflows curvilinearly affect carbon emissions? Threshold effects of energy service availability and cleanliness","authors":"Fuzhong Chen,&nbsp;Guohai Jiang,&nbsp;Kangyin Dong","doi":"10.1111/1467-8454.12273","DOIUrl":"10.1111/1467-8454.12273","url":null,"abstract":"<p>To examine the relationship between foreign direct investment (FDI) inflows and carbon emissions from the perspective of the threshold effects of energy service availability and energy consumption cleanliness, this study employs the panel data of 16 Regional Comprehensive Economic Partnership member countries for the period 1990–2019. Using panel threshold models, this study finds that energy service availability and energy consumption cleanliness are two significant threshold variables in the process by which FDI inflows affect carbon emissions. Before they reach a certain level, FDI inflows aggravate carbon emissions, but this association becomes negative after reaching the threshold level. Furthermore, this study also indicates that the threshold values are different depending on national conditions. Specifically, countries with favourable technological development or stronger environmental regulations have lower threshold values for the two variables, while countries with a higher degree of industrial added value have higher threshold values. Based on these findings, this study recommends enhancing energy service availability and energy consumption cleanliness and formulating related industrial, technological and legal policies based on different national conditions.</p>","PeriodicalId":46169,"journal":{"name":"Australian Economic Papers","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":1.9,"publicationDate":"2022-06-22","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"41686718","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 3
Persistence analysis of research intensity in OECD countries since 1870 1870年以来经合组织国家研究强度的持续性分析
IF 1.9 4区 经济学 Q2 Economics, Econometrics and Finance Pub Date : 2022-06-21 DOI: 10.1111/1467-8454.12271
Sakiru Adebola Solarin, Gema Lopez, Luis A. Gil-Alana

This paper analyses the persistence of research intensity in the OECD over the period 1870–2018. The goal is to test if the conclusion of the study conducted by Ang and Madsen (Ang, J. B., & Madsen, J. B. (2011). Can second-generation endogenous growth models explain the productivity trends and knowledge production in the Asian miracle economies? The Review of Economics and Statistics 2011, 93(4), 1360–1373), namely that the Schumpeterian growth models predict that research intensity is stationary, is correct. Using fractional integration methods on annual research intensity from 16 OECD countries, we observe that the series are very persistent. The order of integration is observed to be statistically higher than 1 in all the countries except Spain, rejecting thus the hypothesis of stationarity. When the likelihood of non-linear trends is considered in the analysis, the results are not materially different. An implication of the results is that policies aimed at boosting research activities will have a long-term impact on research intensity.

本文分析了1870-2018年期间经合组织研究强度的持续性。目的是测试Ang和Madsen (Ang, J. B., &;Madsen, j.b.(2011)。第二代内生增长模型能否解释亚洲奇迹经济体的生产率趋势和知识生产?The Review of Economics and Statistics, 2011, 93(4), 1360-1373),即熊彼特增长模型预测研究强度是平稳的,是正确的。采用分数积分方法对16个经合组织国家的年度研究强度进行分析,我们观察到该序列非常持久。除西班牙外,所有国家的整合顺序在统计上都高于1,因此拒绝了平稳性假设。当分析中考虑非线性趋势的可能性时,结果并没有实质性的不同。研究结果的一个含义是,旨在促进研究活动的政策将对研究强度产生长期影响。
{"title":"Persistence analysis of research intensity in OECD countries since 1870","authors":"Sakiru Adebola Solarin,&nbsp;Gema Lopez,&nbsp;Luis A. Gil-Alana","doi":"10.1111/1467-8454.12271","DOIUrl":"10.1111/1467-8454.12271","url":null,"abstract":"<p>This paper analyses the persistence of research intensity in the OECD over the period 1870–2018. The goal is to test if the conclusion of the study conducted by Ang and Madsen (Ang, J. B., &amp; Madsen, J. B. (2011). Can second-generation endogenous growth models explain the productivity trends and knowledge production in the Asian miracle economies? <i>The Review of Economics and Statistics</i> 2011, <i>93</i>(4), 1360–1373), namely that the Schumpeterian growth models predict that research intensity is stationary, is correct. Using fractional integration methods on annual research intensity from 16 OECD countries, we observe that the series are very persistent. The order of integration is observed to be statistically higher than 1 in all the countries except Spain, rejecting thus the hypothesis of stationarity. When the likelihood of non-linear trends is considered in the analysis, the results are not materially different. An implication of the results is that policies aimed at boosting research activities will have a long-term impact on research intensity.</p>","PeriodicalId":46169,"journal":{"name":"Australian Economic Papers","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":1.9,"publicationDate":"2022-06-21","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"41832874","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
The effect of sanitation and safe drinking water on child mortality and life expectancy: Evidence from a global sample of 100 countries 卫生设施和安全饮用水对儿童死亡率和预期寿命的影响:来自全球100个国家样本的证据
IF 1.9 4区 经济学 Q2 Economics, Econometrics and Finance Pub Date : 2022-05-05 DOI: 10.1111/1467-8454.12265
Mallesh Ummalla, Asharani Samal, Abdulrasheed Zakari, Sathu Lingamurthy

This paper aims to answer two important questions: first, does child mortality reduce with better access to sanitation and safe drinking water? second, does life expectancy improve by adopting safer sanitation and drinking water facilities? The study also accounts for other important variables in the models, such as household final consumption expenditure, per capita income, and urbanisation. The study employs robust panel econometric techniques to achieve the study objectives using annual data of 100 countries from 1990 to 2015. Our findings establish that sanitation and safe drinking water facilities have a significant negative and positive impacts on child mortality and life expectancy, respectively. Our results also suggest that the effect is more from safe drinking water facilities than the sanitation across both models. The robustness check results confirm that access to sanitation and water facilities in rural and urban areas also plays a vital role in reducing child mortality and improving quality of life by increasing life expectancy. Our study provides some policy suggestions and adds value to the body of knowledge.

本文旨在回答两个重要问题:第一,儿童死亡率是否会随着卫生设施和安全饮用水的改善而降低?第二,采用更安全的卫生设施和饮用水设施是否能提高预期寿命?该研究还考虑了模型中的其他重要变量,如家庭最终消费支出、人均收入和城市化程度。该研究采用稳健的面板计量经济学技术,利用1990年至2015年100个国家的年度数据来实现研究目标。我们的研究结果表明,卫生设施和安全饮用水设施分别对儿童死亡率和预期寿命产生显著的消极和积极影响。我们的研究结果还表明,在两种模型中,安全饮用水设施的影响大于卫生设施的影响。稳健性检查结果证实,农村和城市地区获得卫生设施和供水设施也在降低儿童死亡率和通过延长预期寿命提高生活质量方面发挥着至关重要的作用。我们的研究提供了一些政策建议,并增加了知识体系的价值。
{"title":"The effect of sanitation and safe drinking water on child mortality and life expectancy: Evidence from a global sample of 100 countries","authors":"Mallesh Ummalla,&nbsp;Asharani Samal,&nbsp;Abdulrasheed Zakari,&nbsp;Sathu Lingamurthy","doi":"10.1111/1467-8454.12265","DOIUrl":"10.1111/1467-8454.12265","url":null,"abstract":"<p>This paper aims to answer two important questions: first, does child mortality reduce with better access to sanitation and safe drinking water? second, does life expectancy improve by adopting safer sanitation and drinking water facilities? The study also accounts for other important variables in the models, such as household final consumption expenditure, per capita income, and urbanisation. The study employs robust panel econometric techniques to achieve the study objectives using annual data of 100 countries from 1990 to 2015. Our findings establish that sanitation and safe drinking water facilities have a significant negative and positive impacts on child mortality and life expectancy, respectively. Our results also suggest that the effect is more from safe drinking water facilities than the sanitation across both models. The robustness check results confirm that access to sanitation and water facilities in rural and urban areas also plays a vital role in reducing child mortality and improving quality of life by increasing life expectancy. Our study provides some policy suggestions and adds value to the body of knowledge.</p>","PeriodicalId":46169,"journal":{"name":"Australian Economic Papers","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":1.9,"publicationDate":"2022-05-05","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"43210484","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 5
Geoff Harcourt: A Portrait (27 June 1931–7 December 2021) 杰夫·哈考特:肖像(1931年6月27日- 2021年12月7日)
IF 1.9 4区 经济学 Q2 Economics, Econometrics and Finance Pub Date : 2022-05-04 DOI: 10.1111/1467-8454.12260
K. Vela Velupillai

Geoff Harcourt's narrative about his connections with the Australian Economic Papers -henceforth AEP - (Harcourt, 2014) is most enlightening, as is the Interview with Dr. Tran-Nam (Harcourt, 2016) also in AEP. This Portrait for the AEP is complemented by them.

Although a ‘complete’ portrait of this remarkable man can only be gleaned from his publishing and academic activities of over 65 years, as a defender and, more importantly, an indefatigable progenitor of post-Keynesianism, his writings and editorial activities of the last seven or eight years are most telling.

However, I should emphasise the fact that by choice, Harcourt has avoided axioms, theorems and proofs of a mathematical nature - except in Harcourt (1972; but see p.13), but even in that neither theorems nor proofs are in the index to that book; this is natural for someone who thinks that ‘mathematics is a bad master’ (Harcourt, 2003, p. 70).

In his literally last publication before he, and his wife, Joan, left for Cambridge - which was their home for 28 years - Harcourt paid homage to Lorie Tarshis (Harcourt, 1982a, p. 609, ff1) as an ‘early post Keynesian’ and referred to it as ‘a loose term designed to cover those who either were pupils of and/or worked with and/or were strongly influenced by Keynes.’ Tarshis, together with Mabel Timlin, were two Canadians whom he had great respect for as early propagators of the Keynes of the GT, although they had, via Wynne Plumptree, mastered Keynes of the Treatise, as well. In the book of Sinha and Thomas (2019, p. 99), reflecting on his past convictions, he felt able to say that ‘[he] took a post-Keynesian approach long before [he] knew what post-Keynesian economics was Harcourt (2019, p. 99).’

However, the third period in Cambridge - from 1982 to 2010 - consolidated his post-Keynesianism, in particular his allegiance to the methodology and macroeconomic analysis of Keynes, Kalecki and Joan Robinson. Harcourt's adherence to Kahn, Kaldor and Sraffa were also strengthened but they reflected his interests, particularly, in the time-scale and multiplier of macroeconomics, income distribution and returns to scale. He remained wedded to equilibrium, but not necessarily competitive, analysis. Harcourt felt, increasingly, that it was Kalecki who provided the impetus for fiscal and monetary intervention via his distribution considerations, whilst Joan Robinson gave the rationale - with her golden age analysis - the bridge between the economists and the accountants. Keynes, in his path from the Tract to the GT, via the Treatise (and the ‘Circus’), provided a much-improved argument for the fallacy of composition in a largely capitalist economy, which cemented the concepts and activism of the post-Keynesians.

However, Harcourt continued to rely on one of his earlies

杰夫·哈考特(Geoff Harcourt)关于他与《澳大利亚经济论文》(即AEP)的联系的叙述(哈考特,2014年)是最具启发性的,对Tran-Nam博士的采访(哈考特,2016年)也是在AEP上。这幅《亚太经合组织的肖像》得到了它们的补充。尽管对这位杰出人物的“完整”描述只能从他超过65年的出版和学术活动中收集到,但作为后凯恩斯主义的捍卫者,更重要的是,他是一位不知疲倦的先驱,他过去七八年的著作和编辑活动最能说明问题。然而,我应该强调的事实是,哈考特选择避免公理、定理和数学性质的证明——除了哈考特(1972;但见第13页),但即使在那本书的索引中既没有定理也没有证明;对于那些认为“数学是一个糟糕的主人”的人来说,这是很自然的(Harcourt, 2003, p. 70)。在他和他的妻子琼(Joan)离开剑桥(他们在剑桥生活了28年)之前的最后一篇文章中,哈考特将洛里·塔希斯(Harcourt, 1982a, p. 609, ff1)称为“早期后凯恩斯主义者”,并将其称为“一个宽松的术语,旨在涵盖那些曾经是凯恩斯的学生和/或与凯恩斯一起工作和/或受到凯恩斯强烈影响的人”。塔希斯和梅布尔·蒂姆林是他非常尊敬的两位加拿大人,他们是凯恩斯的早期传播者,尽管他们也通过温恩·普拉普特里掌握了凯恩斯的《人性论》。在辛哈和托马斯(2019年,第99页)的书中,反思他过去的信念,他觉得能够说,“在[他]知道什么是后凯恩斯主义经济学之前很久,[他]就采取了后凯恩斯主义的方法。”然而,在剑桥的第三个时期——1982年至2010年——巩固了他的后凯恩斯主义,特别是他对凯恩斯、卡莱茨基和琼·罗宾逊的方法论和宏观经济分析的忠诚。Harcourt对Kahn, Kaldor和straffa的坚持也得到了加强,但它们反映了他的兴趣,特别是在宏观经济学的时间尺度和乘数,收入分配和规模回报方面。他仍然执着于平衡分析,但不一定是竞争分析。哈考特越来越觉得,正是卡莱茨基通过他对分配的考虑,为财政和货币干预提供了动力,而琼·罗宾逊则用她的黄金时代分析,为经济学家和会计师之间的桥梁提供了理论依据。凯恩斯通过《人物论》(和《马戏团》),从《小册子》走向《经济学总论》,为资本主义经济中的构成谬误提供了一个更完善的论证,巩固了后凯恩斯主义者的概念和行动主义。然而,哈考特继续依靠他最早的灵感之一,罗斯柴尔德的克劳斯维茨启发的寡头垄断分析,在市场经济中寻求期望价值的理由,受到宏观经济主导的后凯恩斯主义的缓和。杰夫·哈考特不仅通过巧妙地运用琼·罗宾逊的黄金时代论点来衡量前者对后者利润率概念的使用,从而弥合了会计师和经济学家之间的差距,后者的利润率概念“具有明确的含义”,没有不确定性和预期的实现;然后,他富有想象力地提出了以下问题:“在假设的条件下,使用会计的利润率测量方法得到的答案是否与已知的正确答案相一致?即,事后收益率等于事前收益率(Harcourt, 1965, p. 66)。”他推断出收入的统计指标,因为他知道,即使在均衡状态下,也不可能定义一个纯粹的经济理论概念。按照斯拉法(1961,p.305)的说法,通过这种方式,他能够利用黄金时代——伴随增长的稳态资本理论——弥合实用的会计兼统计学家与经济理论家之间的差距,避免陷入希克斯所陷入的“陷阱”。在许多著作中,例如在《论文集导言》中,哈考特(2001)慷慨地承认了诺姆·乔姆斯基和休·斯特莱顿的影响,他们表明意识形态和分析——尤其是经济分析——是交织在一起的(在越南战争的背景下——但在更广泛的情况下也是如此)。杰夫的经济学,尤其是后凯恩斯主义的经济学,是直接行动的一个方面。杰夫·哈考特特别关注斯拉法的非均衡、非恒定的规模回报理论;这就是为什么他在1982年Prue Kerr编辑的书(Harcourt, 1982 -我想,不幸的是,名字错了)的第四部分中专门写了五篇关于斯拉法的文章。通过斯拉法和多布对资本主义各个方面的批判态度(无可挑剔地研究和记录),他研究了马克思;但和琼·罗宾逊(以及凯恩斯)一样,他并不是马克思所推崇的政治经济学大师。第三部分是关于索尔特的。 在这里,杰夫·哈考特的立场更加“熟悉”。他能够用自己在公司账目上的工作——这是他分析黄金时代假设下会计行为的垫脚石——带着同情来解释索尔特的技术进步功能。然而,尽管他钦佩阿罗,也“不情愿”——但却是发自内心地——喜欢哈恩,他却无法赞同新古典主义的方法论和经济学;也许这是由于他对后凯恩斯主义的坚持和干预主义的立场!进化经济学协会(与简·克雷格尔一起)授予他“凡勃伦公地奖”(Veblen- commons Award)是恰当的,因为是索斯坦·凡勃伦首先定义并使用了“新古典主义”这个词,这让人想起了哈考特的批判观点!他在许多文章中对当时的宏观经济状况进行了有力的批判,因此更容易否定新古典主义。他在Harald Hagemann Festschrift上发表的文章《宏观经济学的危机》(Harcourt, 2012)发现了卢卡斯主义对所谓事实的历史陈述的错误——这是有道理的。杰夫·哈考特身兼数职,其中之一是经济思想史学家;作为一个严格遵守教条历史事实的人,他发现卢卡斯和其他新古典主义者有些不足;但是,新古典主义所宣扬的基本统计和数学方法论的追随者们,并没有被纯粹的教条——历史事实的违反所吓倒;因此,唉,哈考特和类似的学者,通过指出对这些人无关紧要的缺陷,并没有实现他们的崇高目标。1984年,Harcourt试图通过考虑诺贝尔经济学奖得主的观点来解决同样的问题,并希望在一位年轻同事的帮助下更新研究(Harcourt, 2016,第494页)。然而,Offer和Söderberg(2016)有效地完成了“更新”。杰夫·哈考特(Geoff Harcourt)在他90多岁的一生中,无论是活着还是死去,都过着文明、人道、奉献、智力丰富和忠诚的生活;无论是作为一名专业经济学家,还是作为一个独立的个体,他都很有人情心。他以顾问、导师和导师的身份,全身心地投入到他的(大家庭)家庭、朋友、老师、同事和学生身上。知识的丰富性部分来自于他发现自己的职业是后凯恩斯主义经济学,并能够在梅纳德·凯恩斯、米夏沃夫·卡莱茨基和乔安·罗宾逊身上找到根源,在较小程度上,尽管他认为他们也是先驱(哈考特,2006年,尤其是第158页),他的剑桥同事理查德·卡恩、尼基·卡尔多和皮耶罗·斯拉法;其他在剑桥工作的经济学家理查德·斯通、韦恩·戈德利、马里奥·努蒂、莫里斯·多布、约翰·伊特韦尔和理查德·古德温对他也很重要。他个人和职业上都致力于许多事业——其中一些是激进的,但所有的都是人道的;但最重要的是,他热情地致力于他深思熟虑的信念。我认为,从古典意义上说,他是一位政治经济学家,继承了佩蒂、休谟、斯密、李嘉图、马尔萨斯和马克思的伟大传统,这并不夸张。他的妻子琼-恩萨梅·巴特罗普(Joan - ne Bartrop)去世超过67年,他们的四个“孩子”——温迪、罗伯特、蒂姆和丽贝卡(丽贝卡是温迪的丈夫,意大利经济学家克劳迪奥·萨多尼(Claudio Sardoni, Harcourt, 2016年,第501页),一位杰出的后凯恩斯主义者,对卡莱茨基有特殊兴趣),蒂姆的妻子乔·博斯本(Jo
{"title":"Geoff Harcourt: A Portrait (27 June 1931–7 December 2021)","authors":"K. Vela Velupillai","doi":"10.1111/1467-8454.12260","DOIUrl":"10.1111/1467-8454.12260","url":null,"abstract":"<p>Geoff Harcourt's narrative about his connections with the <i>Australian Economic Papers</i> -henceforth <i>AEP</i> - (Harcourt, <span>2014</span>) is most enlightening, as is the Interview with Dr. Tran-Nam (Harcourt, <span>2016</span>) also in <i>AEP</i>. This <i>Portrait</i> for the <i>AEP</i> is complemented by them.</p><p>Although a ‘complete’ portrait of this remarkable man can only be gleaned from his publishing and academic activities of over 65 years, as a defender and, more importantly, an indefatigable progenitor of post-Keynesianism, his writings and editorial activities of the last seven or eight years are most telling.</p><p>However, I should emphasise the fact that by choice, Harcourt has avoided axioms, theorems and proofs of a mathematical nature - except in Harcourt (<span>1972</span>; but see p.13), but even in that neither theorems nor proofs are in the index to that book; this is natural for someone who thinks that ‘mathematics is a bad master’ (Harcourt, <span>2003</span>, p. 70).</p><p>In his literally last publication before he, and his wife, Joan, left for Cambridge - which was their home for 28 years - Harcourt paid <i>homage</i> to Lorie Tarshis (Harcourt, <span>1982a</span>, p. 609, ff<sup>1</sup>) as an ‘early post Keynesian’ and referred to it as ‘a loose term designed to cover those who either were pupils of and/or worked with and/or were strongly influenced by Keynes.’ Tarshis, together with Mabel Timlin, were two Canadians whom he had great respect for as early propagators of the Keynes of the <i>GT</i>, although they had, <i>via</i> Wynne Plumptree, mastered Keynes of the <i>Treatise</i>, as well. In the book of Sinha and Thomas (2019, p. 99), reflecting on his past convictions, he felt able to say that ‘[he] took a post-Keynesian approach long before [he] knew what post-Keynesian economics was Harcourt (2019, p. 99).’</p><p>However, the third period in Cambridge - from 1982 to 2010 - consolidated his post-Keynesianism, in particular his allegiance to the methodology and macroeconomic analysis of Keynes, Kalecki and Joan Robinson. Harcourt's adherence to Kahn, Kaldor and Sraffa were also strengthened but they reflected his interests, particularly, in the time-scale and multiplier of macroeconomics, income distribution and returns to scale. He remained wedded to equilibrium, but not necessarily competitive, analysis. Harcourt felt, increasingly, that it was Kalecki who provided the impetus for fiscal and monetary intervention <i>via</i> his distribution considerations, whilst Joan Robinson gave the rationale - with her golden age analysis - the bridge between the economists and the accountants. Keynes, in his path from the Tract to the <i>GT</i>, via the <i>Treatise</i> (and the ‘Circus’), provided a much-improved argument for the fallacy of composition in a largely capitalist economy, which cemented the concepts and activism of the post-Keynesians.</p><p>However, Harcourt continued to rely on one of his earlies","PeriodicalId":46169,"journal":{"name":"Australian Economic Papers","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":1.9,"publicationDate":"2022-05-04","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/1467-8454.12260","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"47982304","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"OA","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Geoff Harcourt (27.6.1931 to 7.12.2021) 杰夫·哈考特(27.6.1931至7.12.2021)
IF 1.9 4区 经济学 Q2 Economics, Econometrics and Finance Pub Date : 2022-05-04 DOI: 10.1111/1467-8454.12261
Tim Harcourt

Geoff Harcourt was an Australian economist who split his time between Australia and Cambridge, UK with stints in Toronto, Canada and Tokyo, Japan. He passed away on 7th December 2021 aged 90 after several illnesses that had plagued his health since his early sixties after a particularly vigorous and active sports loving middle age. He regarded himself as ‘a Cambridge economist and an Australian patriot’ and was always proud of his contribution to Australian economic policy whilst at the University of Adelaide especially the founding of Australian Economic Papers (AEP).

Geoffrey Colin Harcourt was born in Melbourne in 1931 into a warm hearted secular Jewish family. Harcourt's paternal grandparents Israel and Dinah Harkowitz had come to Australia from Romania (Transylvania) and Poland in the 19th century and owned a series of General Stores in the New South Wales country supplied by the family paddle steamer ‘the Wandering Jew’ owned by Dinah's brother Daniel Berger. The Transylvanian heritage often brought remarks of the natural progression of Dracula to Blood Suckers and Economists!

Geoff's maternal grandparents Daniel and Edith Gans came from Germany and originally Lithuania (although Edith Isaacs was Australian born and related to Sir Isaac Isaacs the nation's first Australian born Governor General). Geoff is related on his mother's side to Joshua Gans, an Australian economist (now based in Toronto).

Geoff's own father, Kopel Harkowitz, and brother Sam, (the much loved Uncle Sam), changed the family name from Harkowitz to Harcourt, to get into golf clubs, surf clubs (in Bondi family lore has it they went from the Goldbergs to the Icebergs) and turf clubs (they even had a radio show named after them called ‘The Racing Harcourts’).

After struggling at secondary school, at Wesley College, despite help from a very academic twin brother John Harcourt (who later became an eminent Dental Academic) and cousin Richard (a successful Chemistry academic) Geoff was a brilliant student at the University of Melbourne in the Commerce Department and at Queens College, (tutored by eminent Labour Economist Joe Isaac). Geoff was trained in the applied tradition of Melbourne and the great Melbourne Institute for Applied Economics and Social Research (MIAESR) and conducted mainly empirically-based surveys supervised by the charismatic Richard ‘Dick’ Downing. In fact, Geoff's cousin Richard Harcourt married Alison Harcourt (previously Alison Doig) was also part of that tradition as she worked as the Statistician on the influential poverty line research of MIAESR, together with Ronald Henderson and John Harper which resulted in the important policy recommendations and the famous Henderson, Harper and Harcourt research that become known as ‘The Henderson Poverty Line’.

After completing his M. Comm at Melbourne Geoff won a PhD scholarship to study at Kings College at the University of Cambridge, which was exc

杰夫·哈考特(Geoff Harcourt)是一位澳大利亚经济学家,他在澳大利亚和英国剑桥两地工作,在加拿大多伦多和日本东京工作。他于2021年12月7日去世,享年90岁。自60岁出头以来,他的健康一直受到几次疾病的困扰。他认为自己是“剑桥经济学家和澳大利亚爱国者”,并一直为自己在阿德莱德大学期间对澳大利亚经济政策的贡献感到自豪,尤其是创办了澳大利亚经济论文(AEP)。杰弗里·科林·哈考特1931年出生于墨尔本一个热情的世俗犹太家庭。哈考特的祖父母以色列和黛娜·哈科维茨在19世纪从罗马尼亚(特兰西瓦尼亚)和波兰来到澳大利亚,在新南威尔士州拥有一系列杂货店,由黛娜的兄弟丹尼尔·伯杰拥有的家族“流浪犹太人”轮船供应。特兰西瓦尼亚的遗产经常给吸血鬼和经济学家带来德古拉自然发展的评论!杰夫的外祖父母丹尼尔和伊迪丝·甘斯来自德国,最初来自立陶宛(尽管伊迪丝·艾萨克是澳大利亚出生的,并且与该国第一位澳大利亚出生的总督艾萨克·艾萨克爵士有亲戚关系)。Geoff的母亲是澳大利亚经济学家Joshua Gans(现居多伦多)的亲戚。杰夫的父亲科佩尔·哈科维茨(Kopel Harkowitz)和弟弟萨姆(Sam,也就是大家喜爱的山姆大叔)把姓氏从哈科维茨改成了哈考特,以便加入高尔夫俱乐部、冲浪俱乐部(在邦迪家族的传说中,他们从戈德伯格家转到了冰山家)和草皮俱乐部(他们甚至有一个以他们的名字命名的广播节目《赛马哈考特》(the Racing Harcourts))。杰夫在中学和卫斯理学院(Wesley College)度过了艰难的时期,尽管他的双胞胎兄弟约翰·哈考特(John Harcourt,后来成为了一位杰出的牙科学者)和堂兄理查德(Richard,一位成功的化学学者)对他有所帮助,但他还是成为了墨尔本大学商科和皇后学院(Queens College,由著名的劳动经济学家乔·艾萨克(Joe Isaac)指导)的优秀学生。Geoff在墨尔本的应用传统和伟大的墨尔本应用经济与社会研究所(MIAESR)接受过培训,并在富有魅力的Richard ' Dick ' Downing的指导下进行了主要基于经验的调查。事实上,杰夫的堂兄弟理查德·哈考特娶了艾莉森·哈考特(以前是艾莉森·多伊格),也是这一传统的一部分,因为她作为统计学家在MIAESR的有影响力的贫困线研究中工作,与罗纳德·亨德森和约翰·哈珀一起,产生了重要的政策建议和著名的亨德森,哈珀和哈考特研究,被称为“亨德森贫困线”。在墨尔本完成了他的硕士学位后,杰夫获得了在剑桥大学国王学院学习的博士奖学金,这是令人兴奋的,因为国王学院是约翰·梅纳德·凯恩斯的学院。最重要的是,在墨尔本,他遇到了巴拉瑞特大学的琼·巴特罗普(Joan Bartrop),毕业后就和她结婚了,然后去了剑桥大学。琼之前和剧作家艾伦·霍普古德约会过,霍普古德是《大家伙飞》的作者,《大家伙飞》是澳大利亚足球最著名的戏剧,还有大卫·威廉姆森的《俱乐部》。这一联盟持续了令人印象深刻的66年。琼对社会政策,特别是住房政策有浓厚的兴趣。她是墨尔本研究所进行的贫困线研究的采访者。她的父亲埃德加·巴特罗普(Edgar Bartrop)曾是战时财政部长兼总理本·奇夫利(Ben Chifley)的顾问,也曾担任过联邦住宿总监,该职位负责在第二次世界大战期间为澳大利亚地区重新安置的军火工人提供住房。Bartrop还在他的家乡巴拉瑞特创立了海棠节,并帮助建立了Sovereign Hill博物馆和娱乐公园,致力于19世纪50年代巴拉瑞特的淘金热时期。新婚的杰夫·哈考特和琼·哈考特在维多利亚州冲浪海岸的托基度过了短暂的蜜月后,于1955年首次乘船离开澳大利亚海岸前往英国。杰夫来到剑桥时,正值其富有传奇色彩的经济学学院最成功的时代之一。他沉浸在凯恩斯的圈子里,凯恩斯的学生和继承人,著名的经济学家,如尼古拉斯·卡尔多,理查德·卡恩,皮耶罗·斯拉法,当然还有杰夫的英雄,琼·罗宾逊。杰夫不仅成为了圈子里最受欢迎的研究生,尤其是琼·罗宾逊,而且还为他在资本理论的辩论中播下了重要的思想种子,这些辩论是在英国剑桥大学的经济学家和麻省理工学院的新兴知识力量之间进行的。由于在剑桥的早期工作,杰夫决定经济理论是他的真爱,尽管他非常感谢他在墨尔本获得的应用经济学基础。 杰夫和琼于1958年回到澳大利亚,在阿德莱德大学经济系担任研究助理。1955年,他们在前往英国的途中曾在阿德莱德停留,两人一见钟情。回国途中,他们的船停靠在斯里兰卡的科伦坡,敲定了在南澳大利亚定居的协议。随后,他们的邀请被电报升级为阿德莱德大学(University of Adelaide)的讲师。1962年,杰夫在阿德莱德帮助创办了《澳大利亚经济报》(AEP),他在阿德莱德的同事休·哈德森(Hugh Hudson)担任首任编辑(哈德森后来在唐·邓斯坦(Don Dunstan)总理领导的南澳工党政府中担任教育部长和副总理)。AEP的成立是为了在澳大利亚提供一个良好的应用经济政策期刊,这是阿德莱德经济学在20世纪60年代和70年代的比较优势。哈德森离开大学从政后,杰夫于1967年成为AEP的联合编辑,并与许多同事(主要是基思·汉考克、默文·刘易斯和鲍勃·华莱士)一起担任了近20年的主编。在社交方面,这也是一个不错的选择。杰夫和琼是一对来自维多利亚州的年轻夫妇,他们带着年幼的孩子,在阿德莱德认识的人不多,但他们大学时代的很多朋友也搬到了阿德莱德,所以他们有鲍勃和帕特·华莱士、基思和琼·汉考克、布莱恩和特雷西塔·本蒂克的陪伴,还有埃里克和朱迪思·罗素、彼得和利亚·卡梅尔的好意。这是阿德莱德一些快乐时光的开始。但剑桥对杰夫的吸引力依然存在。1962年,杰夫一家(杰夫、琼、温迪和罗伯特)去了剑桥,在那里呆了四年,杰夫在剑桥著名的经济与政治经济学院担任讲师,并在三一学院获得了奖学金,重新认识了“圈子”。作为一名30多岁的年轻学者,这本书巩固了杰夫在剑桥的声誉,并使他能够建立一个由大西洋两岸、欧洲以及非洲、美洲和亚太新兴经济体的顶尖经济学家组成的网络。剑桥是最优秀和最聪明的人的灯塔,使杰夫(和他的家人)与来自印度、意大利、伊朗、巴西和全球各个角落的经济学家建立了非常密切的友谊。1966年,随着经济学再次蓬勃发展,全家回到阿德莱德(带着另一个孩子,1965年出生的蒂姆),现在在新的大学——南澳大利亚弗林德斯大学建立了一所新学校,由彼得·卡梅尔领导,他带着基思·汉考克(!)。(两人都成了弗林德斯大学的副校长)。在阿德莱德,这也是一个激动人心的时刻,因为普莱福德时代已经结束,“邓斯坦十年”开始了。争取越南和平和反对征兵的运动也成为该国的主要社会力量,工党议员吉姆·凯恩斯博士在墨尔本领导了暂停运动,杰夫在阿德莱德也在做同样的事情。1969年,杰夫在日本庆应义大学休假,把他的《资本论》文章写成了一本书(他决定去一个不会说日语的地方,这样可以帮助他集中精力完成这本书!),他的家人(包括1968年出生的第四个孩子贝基)也得到了在日本生活的好处!在那些日子里,很少有西方家庭住在日本,我们是当地人好奇的对象(尤其是4岁的蒂姆,一头鲜红的头发)和难以置信的友善。我们的寄宿家庭离开了他们的家,让我们一家六口在那里住
{"title":"Geoff Harcourt (27.6.1931 to 7.12.2021)","authors":"Tim Harcourt","doi":"10.1111/1467-8454.12261","DOIUrl":"10.1111/1467-8454.12261","url":null,"abstract":"<p>Geoff Harcourt was an Australian economist who split his time between Australia and Cambridge, UK with stints in Toronto, Canada and Tokyo, Japan. He passed away on 7<sup>th</sup> December 2021 aged 90 after several illnesses that had plagued his health since his early sixties after a particularly vigorous and active sports loving middle age. He regarded himself as ‘a Cambridge economist <i>and</i> an Australian patriot’ and was always proud of his contribution to Australian economic policy whilst at the University of Adelaide especially the founding of Australian Economic Papers (AEP).</p><p>Geoffrey Colin Harcourt was born in Melbourne in 1931 into a warm hearted secular Jewish family. Harcourt's paternal grandparents Israel and Dinah Harkowitz had come to Australia from Romania (Transylvania) and Poland in the 19<sup>th</sup> century and owned a series of General Stores in the New South Wales country supplied by the family paddle steamer ‘the Wandering Jew’ owned by Dinah's brother Daniel Berger. The Transylvanian heritage often brought remarks of the natural progression of Dracula to Blood Suckers and Economists!</p><p>Geoff's maternal grandparents Daniel and Edith Gans came from Germany and originally Lithuania (although Edith Isaacs was Australian born and related to Sir Isaac Isaacs the nation's first Australian born Governor General). Geoff is related on his mother's side to Joshua Gans, an Australian economist (now based in Toronto).</p><p>Geoff's own father, Kopel Harkowitz, and brother Sam, (the much loved Uncle Sam), changed the family name from Harkowitz to Harcourt, to get into golf clubs, surf clubs (in Bondi family lore has it they went from the Goldbergs to the Icebergs) and turf clubs (they even had a radio show named after them called ‘The Racing Harcourts’).</p><p>After struggling at secondary school, at Wesley College, despite help from a very academic twin brother John Harcourt (who later became an eminent Dental Academic) and cousin Richard (a successful Chemistry academic) Geoff was a brilliant student at the University of Melbourne in the Commerce Department and at Queens College, (tutored by eminent Labour Economist Joe Isaac). Geoff was trained in the applied tradition of Melbourne and the great Melbourne Institute for Applied Economics and Social Research (MIAESR) and conducted mainly empirically-based surveys supervised by the charismatic Richard ‘Dick’ Downing. In fact, Geoff's cousin Richard Harcourt married Alison Harcourt (previously Alison Doig) was also part of that tradition as she worked as the Statistician on the influential poverty line research of MIAESR, together with Ronald Henderson and John Harper which resulted in the important policy recommendations and the famous Henderson, Harper and Harcourt research that become known as ‘The Henderson Poverty Line’.</p><p>After completing his M. Comm at Melbourne Geoff won a PhD scholarship to study at Kings College at the University of Cambridge, which was exc","PeriodicalId":46169,"journal":{"name":"Australian Economic Papers","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":1.9,"publicationDate":"2022-05-04","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/1467-8454.12261","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"47097715","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"OA","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Methods to evaluate institutional responses to performance-based research funding systems 评估机构对基于绩效的研究资助制度反应的方法
IF 1.9 4区 经济学 Q2 Economics, Econometrics and Finance Pub Date : 2022-05-01 DOI: 10.1111/1467-8454.12263
Robert A. Buckle, John Creedy

Performance-based research funding systems (PBRFS) have been introduced in many countries for allocating funding to research institutions. There continues to be considerable debate about the effectiveness and consequences of these systems. This paper suggests several methods that can be applied to evaluate how institutions respond to new incentives created by the introduction of a PBRFS. The methods are illustrated using longitudinal data from the New Zealand PBRFS, which assesses institutional performance and allocates funds based on individual researcher performance, although not all methods require individual data. Longitudinal data enable the identification of entry, exit and quality transformation of researchers and the contribution of these dynamics to changes in university and discipline research quality. The approach enables a deeper understanding of individual and institutional responses to PBRFSs, the sustainability of changes and the contributions of changes in researcher quality and discipline composition to changes in institutional performance.

许多国家已经引入了基于绩效的研究资助制度(PBRFS),用于向研究机构分配资金。关于这些系统的有效性和后果,仍然存在相当大的争论。本文提出了几种可用于评估机构如何对引入PBRFS所产生的新激励作出反应的方法。这些方法使用新西兰PBRFS的纵向数据进行说明,该数据评估机构绩效并根据研究人员的个人表现分配资金,尽管并非所有方法都需要个人数据。纵向数据可以识别研究人员的进入、退出和质量转变,以及这些动态对大学和学科研究质量变化的贡献。该方法能够更深入地了解个人和机构对PBRFSs的反应、变化的可持续性以及研究人员质量和学科组成的变化对机构绩效变化的贡献。
{"title":"Methods to evaluate institutional responses to performance-based research funding systems","authors":"Robert A. Buckle,&nbsp;John Creedy","doi":"10.1111/1467-8454.12263","DOIUrl":"10.1111/1467-8454.12263","url":null,"abstract":"<p>Performance-based research funding systems (PBRFS) have been introduced in many countries for allocating funding to research institutions. There continues to be considerable debate about the effectiveness and consequences of these systems. This paper suggests several methods that can be applied to evaluate how institutions respond to new incentives created by the introduction of a PBRFS. The methods are illustrated using longitudinal data from the New Zealand PBRFS, which assesses institutional performance and allocates funds based on individual researcher performance, although not all methods require individual data. Longitudinal data enable the identification of entry, exit and quality transformation of researchers and the contribution of these dynamics to changes in university and discipline research quality. The approach enables a deeper understanding of individual and institutional responses to PBRFSs, the sustainability of changes and the contributions of changes in researcher quality and discipline composition to changes in institutional performance.</p>","PeriodicalId":46169,"journal":{"name":"Australian Economic Papers","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":1.9,"publicationDate":"2022-05-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/1467-8454.12263","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"47644866","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"OA","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Agricultural green efficiency and productivity incorporating waste recycling 农业绿色效率和生产力,包括废物回收利用
IF 1.9 4区 经济学 Q2 Economics, Econometrics and Finance Pub Date : 2022-04-27 DOI: 10.1111/1467-8454.12264
Ruomei Xu, Yanrui Wu, Chen Chen

This paper analyses agricultural green efficiency and productivity by using the farming and livestock industries as case studies. To do so, nitrogen and phosphorus surpluses in arable land are measured by considering recycling of agricultural wastes in the farming and livestock ecosystem and defined as the undesirable output in agricultural production. The empirical analysis is based on data of rural areas in Anhui province, China, over the period of 2000 to 2017. It shows the existence of considerable nitrogen and phosphorus nutrient surplus in arable land, with phosphorus surplus keeps increasing. It also illustrates that nitrogen and phosphorus nutrients from manure were decreasing while those from the crop residues were increasing. The empirical assessment demonstrates that agricultural green efficiency tended to converge over time. Furthermore, agricultural green total factor productivity showed an overall increasing trend, although its components, efficiency change and technological progress, moved in opposite directions in most years. Finally, some useful policy recommendations are provided in this paper.

本文以农牧业为例,对农业绿色效率和农业生产力进行了分析。为此,通过考虑农业和畜牧业生态系统中农业废弃物的循环利用来衡量耕地中的氮和磷过剩,并将其定义为农业生产中的不良产出。实证分析基于2000 - 2017年中国安徽省农村地区的数据。表明耕地存在相当的氮磷养分过剩,且磷的过剩量不断增加。有机肥氮磷养分呈减少趋势,作物残茬氮磷养分呈增加趋势。实证分析表明,随着时间的推移,农业绿色效率趋于收敛。农业绿色全要素生产率总体呈上升趋势,但其构成要素效率变化和技术进步在多数年份呈相反趋势。最后,本文提出了一些有益的政策建议。
{"title":"Agricultural green efficiency and productivity incorporating waste recycling","authors":"Ruomei Xu,&nbsp;Yanrui Wu,&nbsp;Chen Chen","doi":"10.1111/1467-8454.12264","DOIUrl":"10.1111/1467-8454.12264","url":null,"abstract":"<p>This paper analyses agricultural green efficiency and productivity by using the farming and livestock industries as case studies. To do so, nitrogen and phosphorus surpluses in arable land are measured by considering recycling of agricultural wastes in the farming and livestock ecosystem and defined as the undesirable output in agricultural production. The empirical analysis is based on data of rural areas in Anhui province, China, over the period of 2000 to 2017. It shows the existence of considerable nitrogen and phosphorus nutrient surplus in arable land, with phosphorus surplus keeps increasing. It also illustrates that nitrogen and phosphorus nutrients from manure were decreasing while those from the crop residues were increasing. The empirical assessment demonstrates that agricultural green efficiency tended to converge over time. Furthermore, agricultural green total factor productivity showed an overall increasing trend, although its components, efficiency change and technological progress, moved in opposite directions in most years. Finally, some useful policy recommendations are provided in this paper.</p>","PeriodicalId":46169,"journal":{"name":"Australian Economic Papers","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":1.9,"publicationDate":"2022-04-27","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/1467-8454.12264","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"44958161","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"OA","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 3
Quantifying the economy-wide returns to innovation for Australia 量化澳大利亚创新在整个经济中的回报
IF 1.9 4区 经济学 Q2 Economics, Econometrics and Finance Pub Date : 2022-04-23 DOI: 10.1111/1467-8454.12262
Katherine Wynn, Mingji Liu, Jasmine Cohen

Innovation plays a vital role in driving Australia's economic growth, and the desire to quantify this relationship is ever present. This article quantifies the relationship between domestic gross expenditure on research and development (R&D) and gross domestic product (GDP) per capita growth to estimate the return on investment (ROI) to innovation for Australia. This article adopts the Jones and Summers (2020) approach to quantify the ROI of gross R&D spending for Australia. This novel yet simple macroeconomic approach complements other existing methodologies. It quantifies only economic benefits, excluding non-monetary societal and environmental benefits. The baseline results state that $1 of R&D investment creates an average of $20.8 in economy-wide benefits in today's dollars, and investment in R&D creates an average annual return of 104% for Australia. Importantly, this baseline result can be recalculated with adjustments to account for specific features of innovation activity. Incorporating a 10-year delay between R&D and payoffs, combined with a correction for building R&D into new capital inputs (known as embodied capital deepening) to account for the additional time and costs associated with R&D expenditure yields lower results of $3.5 of economy-wide benefits and 10% average annual return for every dollar spent on R&D. Even when corrections are applied to the baseline for conservative estimates, the economy-wide returns to innovation are comparable to historical private investment returns in Australia.

创新在推动澳大利亚经济增长方面发挥着至关重要的作用,量化这种关系的愿望一直存在。本文量化了国内研发总支出(R&D)与人均国内生产总值(GDP)增长之间的关系,以估计澳大利亚创新的投资回报率(ROI)。本文采用Jones和Summers(2020)的方法来量化澳大利亚总研发支出的投资回报率。这种新颖而简单的宏观经济方法是对其他现有方法的补充。它只量化经济效益,不包括非货币性的社会和环境效益。基线结果表明,以今天的美元计算,1美元的研发投资平均创造20.8美元的经济效益,而研发投资为澳大利亚创造了104%的平均年回报率。重要的是,这个基线结果可以通过调整来重新计算,以考虑创新活动的具体特征。将研发与回报之间的10年延迟,结合将研发纳入新资本投入的修正(称为隐含资本深化),以解释与研发支出相关的额外时间和成本,产生较低的结果,即3.5美元的经济效益和研发每花费1美元的平均年回报率为10%。即使对保守估计的基线进行修正,整个经济的创新回报也与澳大利亚历史上的私人投资回报相当。
{"title":"Quantifying the economy-wide returns to innovation for Australia","authors":"Katherine Wynn,&nbsp;Mingji Liu,&nbsp;Jasmine Cohen","doi":"10.1111/1467-8454.12262","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1111/1467-8454.12262","url":null,"abstract":"<p>Innovation plays a vital role in driving Australia's economic growth, and the desire to quantify this relationship is ever present. This article quantifies the relationship between domestic gross expenditure on research and development (R&amp;D) and gross domestic product (GDP) per capita growth to estimate the return on investment (ROI) to innovation for Australia. This article adopts the Jones and Summers (2020) approach to quantify the ROI of gross R&amp;D spending for Australia. This novel yet simple macroeconomic approach complements other existing methodologies. It quantifies only economic benefits, excluding non-monetary societal and environmental benefits. The baseline results state that $1 of R&amp;D investment creates an average of $20.8 in economy-wide benefits in today's dollars, and investment in R&amp;D creates an average annual return of 104% for Australia. Importantly, this baseline result can be recalculated with adjustments to account for specific features of innovation activity. Incorporating a 10-year delay between R&amp;D and payoffs, combined with a correction for building R&amp;D into new capital inputs (known as embodied capital deepening) to account for the additional time and costs associated with R&amp;D expenditure yields lower results of $3.5 of economy-wide benefits and 10% average annual return for every dollar spent on R&amp;D. Even when corrections are applied to the baseline for conservative estimates, the economy-wide returns to innovation are comparable to historical private investment returns in Australia.</p>","PeriodicalId":46169,"journal":{"name":"Australian Economic Papers","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":1.9,"publicationDate":"2022-04-23","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/1467-8454.12262","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"137961931","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"OA","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Common ownership and stock price crash risk: Evidence from China 共同持股与股价崩盘风险:来自中国的证据
IF 1.9 4区 经济学 Q2 Economics, Econometrics and Finance Pub Date : 2022-03-20 DOI: 10.1111/1467-8454.12259
Ping Jiang, Yunbiao Ma, Beibei Shi

This study examines whether common ownership affects stock price crash risk (SPCR). Using 3,159 companies listed in China between 2006 and 2019, this paper finds that companies with common ownership are associated with lower SPCR. This finding can be explained by the monitoring effect of common ownership which holds that common ownership can curb the hoarding of bad news by managers and thereby reduces SPCR. We further show that the effect is more evident when common owners hold a relatively larger number of same-industry firms, when common owners hold more shares, and for state-owned-enterprises. Moreover, this paper also demonstrates how common ownership facilitates effective monitoring and finds that common ownership reduces earnings management and increases accounting conservatism in firms. Our evidence suggests that common ownership serves as an effective form of monitoring by constraining managers' opportunistic behaviour, thereby reducing SPCR.

本研究探讨普通股是否会影响股价崩盘风险。本文以2006 - 2019年在中国上市的3159家公司为研究对象,发现共有股权公司的SPCR较低。这一发现可以用共同所有权的监控效应来解释,即共同所有权可以抑制管理者囤积坏消息,从而降低SPCR。我们进一步表明,当普通股所有者持有相对较多的同行业企业时,当普通股所有者持有更多的股份时,以及对于国有企业,这种效应更为明显。此外,本文还论证了共同所有权如何促进有效的监督,并发现共同所有权减少了盈余管理,增加了公司的会计稳健性。我们的证据表明,共同所有权是一种有效的监督形式,它约束了管理者的机会主义行为,从而降低了SPCR。
{"title":"Common ownership and stock price crash risk: Evidence from China","authors":"Ping Jiang,&nbsp;Yunbiao Ma,&nbsp;Beibei Shi","doi":"10.1111/1467-8454.12259","DOIUrl":"10.1111/1467-8454.12259","url":null,"abstract":"<p>This study examines whether common ownership affects stock price crash risk (SPCR). Using 3,159 companies listed in China between 2006 and 2019, this paper finds that companies with common ownership are associated with lower SPCR. This finding can be explained by the monitoring effect of common ownership which holds that common ownership can curb the hoarding of bad news by managers and thereby reduces SPCR. We further show that the effect is more evident when common owners hold a relatively larger number of same-industry firms, when common owners hold more shares, and for state-owned-enterprises. Moreover, this paper also demonstrates how common ownership facilitates effective monitoring and finds that common ownership reduces earnings management and increases accounting conservatism in firms. Our evidence suggests that common ownership serves as an effective form of monitoring by constraining managers' opportunistic behaviour, thereby reducing SPCR.</p>","PeriodicalId":46169,"journal":{"name":"Australian Economic Papers","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":1.9,"publicationDate":"2022-03-20","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"46347799","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 3
期刊
Australian Economic Papers
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1