首页 > 最新文献

George Washington Law Review最新文献

英文 中文
Disentangling privacy from property: toward a deeper understanding of genetic privacy. 从财产中分离隐私:走向对基因隐私更深层次的理解。
IF 1.5 3区 社会学 Q1 Social Sciences Pub Date : 2004-04-01
Sonia M Suter

With the mapping of the human genome, genetic privacy has become a concern to many. People care about genetic privacy because genes play an important role in shaping us--our genetic information is about us, and it is deeply connected to our sense of ourselves. In addition, unwanted disclosure of our genetic information, like a great deal of other personal information, makes us vulnerable to unwanted exposure, stigmatization, and discrimination. One recent approach to protecting genetic privacy is to create property rights in genetic information. This Article argues against that approach. Privacy and property are fundamentally different concepts. At heart, the term "property" connotes control within the marketplace and over something that is disaggregated or alienable from the self. "Privacy," in contrast, connotes control over access to the self as well as things close to, intimately connected to, and about the self. Given these different meanings, a regime of property rights in genetic information would impoverish our understanding of that information, ourselves, and the relationships we hope will be built around and through its disclosure. This Article explores our interests in genetic information in order to deepen our understanding of the ongoing discourse about the distinction between property and privacy. It develops a conception of genetic privacy with a strong relational component. We ordinarily share genetic information in the context of relationships in which disclosure is important to the relationship--family, intimate, doctor-patient, researcher-participant, employer-employee, and insurer-insured relationships. Such disclosure makes us vulnerable to and dependent on the person to whom we disclose it. As a result, trust is essential to the integrity of these relationships and our sharing of genetic information. Genetic privacy can protect our vulnerability in these relationships and enhance the trust we hope to have in them. Property, in contrast, by connoting commodification, disaggregation, and arms-length dealings, can negatively affect the self and harm these relationships. This Article concludes that a deeper understanding of genetic privacy calls for remedies for privacy violations that address dignitary harm and breach of trust, as opposed to market harms, as the property model suggests.

随着人类基因组的绘制,基因隐私已成为许多人关注的问题。人们关心基因隐私,因为基因在塑造我们的过程中扮演着重要的角色——我们的基因信息是关于我们的,它与我们的自我意识密切相关。此外,像许多其他个人信息一样,我们的基因信息被无意地披露,使我们容易受到无意的曝光、污名化和歧视。最近保护基因隐私的一种方法是在基因信息中建立产权。本文反对这种做法。隐私和财产是根本不同的概念。本质上,“财产”一词意味着对市场的控制,以及对与自我分离或剥夺的东西的控制。相比之下,“隐私”意味着控制对自我的访问,以及与自我接近、密切相关和关于自我的事物。考虑到这些不同的含义,基因信息的产权制度会削弱我们对这些信息的理解,削弱我们自己的理解,削弱我们希望围绕并通过披露这些信息建立的关系。本文探讨了我们对遗传信息的兴趣,以加深我们对正在进行的关于财产和隐私之间区别的论述的理解。它发展了一种具有强烈关系成分的遗传隐私概念。我们通常在这样的关系中分享基因信息,在这种关系中,披露对家庭关系、亲密关系、医生与病人、研究人员与参与者、雇主与雇员以及保险公司与保险公司的关系是很重要的。这种披露使我们容易受到我们披露的人的伤害,并依赖于我们披露的人。因此,信任对于这些关系的完整性和我们分享遗传信息至关重要。基因隐私可以保护我们在这些关系中的脆弱性,并增强我们希望在这些关系中拥有的信任。相比之下,财产意味着商品化、解体和公平交易,会对自我产生负面影响,损害这些关系。本文的结论是,要更深入地理解遗传隐私,就需要对侵犯隐私的行为采取补救措施,解决尊严损害和信任违约问题,而不是像财产模型所建议的那样对市场造成损害。
{"title":"Disentangling privacy from property: toward a deeper understanding of genetic privacy.","authors":"Sonia M Suter","doi":"","DOIUrl":"","url":null,"abstract":"<p><p>With the mapping of the human genome, genetic privacy has become a concern to many. People care about genetic privacy because genes play an important role in shaping us--our genetic information is about us, and it is deeply connected to our sense of ourselves. In addition, unwanted disclosure of our genetic information, like a great deal of other personal information, makes us vulnerable to unwanted exposure, stigmatization, and discrimination. One recent approach to protecting genetic privacy is to create property rights in genetic information. This Article argues against that approach. Privacy and property are fundamentally different concepts. At heart, the term \"property\" connotes control within the marketplace and over something that is disaggregated or alienable from the self. \"Privacy,\" in contrast, connotes control over access to the self as well as things close to, intimately connected to, and about the self. Given these different meanings, a regime of property rights in genetic information would impoverish our understanding of that information, ourselves, and the relationships we hope will be built around and through its disclosure. This Article explores our interests in genetic information in order to deepen our understanding of the ongoing discourse about the distinction between property and privacy. It develops a conception of genetic privacy with a strong relational component. We ordinarily share genetic information in the context of relationships in which disclosure is important to the relationship--family, intimate, doctor-patient, researcher-participant, employer-employee, and insurer-insured relationships. Such disclosure makes us vulnerable to and dependent on the person to whom we disclose it. As a result, trust is essential to the integrity of these relationships and our sharing of genetic information. Genetic privacy can protect our vulnerability in these relationships and enhance the trust we hope to have in them. Property, in contrast, by connoting commodification, disaggregation, and arms-length dealings, can negatively affect the self and harm these relationships. This Article concludes that a deeper understanding of genetic privacy calls for remedies for privacy violations that address dignitary harm and breach of trust, as opposed to market harms, as the property model suggests.</p>","PeriodicalId":47068,"journal":{"name":"George Washington Law Review","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":1.5,"publicationDate":"2004-04-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"25879705","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
'The Friendship of the People': Citizen Participation in Environmental Enforcement “人民的友谊”:公民参与环境执法
IF 1.5 3区 社会学 Q1 Social Sciences Pub Date : 2004-02-01 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.509105
M. Seidenfeld
There is a tension between citizen participation in environmental enforcement and an agency's discretion to choose the optimal balance between deterrence and cooperative approaches to enforcement. Citizen participation can reduce the costs of monitoring violations and their impacts and can pick up some of the burden of prosecuting violators. Cooperative enforcement can also reduce monitoring costs by encouraging regulated entities to provide information on their regulatory performance and can decrease those entities costs of compliance, as well focusing compliance on violations that cause net harm to the society. Cooperative enforcement, however, itself must be monitored to make sure that the agency does not abuse the discretion granted to it under this approach. At some level, however, citizen participation threatens effective use of cooperative enforcement. Although citizen participation provides a mechanism for controlling agency abuse under the cooperative enforcement model, such participation also scares regulated entities by empowering them to take unreasonable stands, and hence discourages companies from self reporting violations and acting candidly about what it will take to bring their plants into regulatory compliance. This article suggests three approaches to alleviate this tension and thereby capture the benefits of both citizen participation and a balanced model of enforcement. The article shows that although each of these three approaches - tripartism, corporatism and deliberative participation - holds some promise, each also raises significant concerns that prevent it from becoming the principal means of implementing participation in regulatory enforcement.
在公民参与环境执法和机构自由裁量权之间选择威慑和合作执法方法之间的最佳平衡之间存在紧张关系。公民参与可以降低监督违法行为及其影响的成本,还可以减轻起诉违法者的负担。合作执法还可以通过鼓励受监管实体提供关于其监管绩效的信息来降低监测成本,还可以降低这些实体的合规成本,并将合规重点放在对社会造成净损害的违规行为上。然而,合作执法本身必须受到监督,以确保该机构不会滥用根据这种方法授予它的自由裁量权。然而,在某种程度上,公民参与威胁到合作执法的有效使用。尽管在合作执法模式下,公民参与提供了一种控制机构滥用的机制,但这种参与也使受监管的实体感到害怕,因为它们有权采取不合理的立场,因此阻碍了公司自我报告违规行为,也阻碍了公司坦率地说明如何使其工厂符合监管要求。本文提出了三种方法来缓解这种紧张关系,从而抓住公民参与和平衡的执法模式的好处。这篇文章表明,虽然这三种方法-三方主义、社团主义和协商参与-中的每一种都有一些希望,但每一种方法也都引起了严重的关切,使其无法成为实施参与监管执法的主要手段。
{"title":"'The Friendship of the People': Citizen Participation in Environmental Enforcement","authors":"M. Seidenfeld","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.509105","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.509105","url":null,"abstract":"There is a tension between citizen participation in environmental enforcement and an agency's discretion to choose the optimal balance between deterrence and cooperative approaches to enforcement. Citizen participation can reduce the costs of monitoring violations and their impacts and can pick up some of the burden of prosecuting violators. Cooperative enforcement can also reduce monitoring costs by encouraging regulated entities to provide information on their regulatory performance and can decrease those entities costs of compliance, as well focusing compliance on violations that cause net harm to the society. Cooperative enforcement, however, itself must be monitored to make sure that the agency does not abuse the discretion granted to it under this approach. At some level, however, citizen participation threatens effective use of cooperative enforcement. Although citizen participation provides a mechanism for controlling agency abuse under the cooperative enforcement model, such participation also scares regulated entities by empowering them to take unreasonable stands, and hence discourages companies from self reporting violations and acting candidly about what it will take to bring their plants into regulatory compliance. This article suggests three approaches to alleviate this tension and thereby capture the benefits of both citizen participation and a balanced model of enforcement. The article shows that although each of these three approaches - tripartism, corporatism and deliberative participation - holds some promise, each also raises significant concerns that prevent it from becoming the principal means of implementing participation in regulatory enforcement.","PeriodicalId":47068,"journal":{"name":"George Washington Law Review","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":1.5,"publicationDate":"2004-02-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"67754394","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 3
The U.S. Tax Treatment of Foreign Source Income Earned in Developing Countries: A Policy Analysis 美国对发展中国家外国来源收入的税收待遇:政策分析
IF 1.5 3区 社会学 Q1 Social Sciences Pub Date : 2003-12-08 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.476581
P. McDaniel
The purpose of this Article is to explore whether the United States should amend its international tax rules in ways that might encourage U.S. companies to invest in developing countries. Some scholars, notably Professor Karen Brown, have argued that the current U.S. international tax regime works against the interests of developing countries and should be replaced by one that, she asserts, would benefit developing countries in general and African nations in particular.1 She has proposed that the United States replace its foreign tax credit mechanism with an exemption system for developing countries, at the least for Africa. One of the reasons for the proposal is that, as explained below, the current U.S. system prevents developing countries from offering tax incentives, such as tax holidays, to attract foreign direct investment (FDI) by U.S. multinational corporations (MNCs). Certainly, it is the case that little U.S. FDI finds its way to developing countries. At the end of 2001, total U.S.-owner assets earned abroad totaled $6.2 trillion (valued at cost). But the following shows how little of these assets were in developing countries (in $ billions):2 There is thus a real shortfall in U.S. FDI in developing countries as compared to its FDI in other developed countries. But, proposals such as the one put forward by Professor Brown raise several questions. Is FDI an unqualified good for developing countries? What are the determinants in the location of FDI? Are tax incentives offered by developing countries effective in attracting FDI, even in situations where home country tax rules do not thwart them? Can tax incentives alone attract FDI or are there necessary preconditions a developing country must satisfy before there is FDI at all? Are home country unilateral tax incentives effective in increasing FDI by its MNCs? Is it better for developed countries to assist developing countries by offering tax subsidies to its MNCs or by providing direct financial assistance to developing countries? This paper is an effort to explore these questions to see where the evidence supports clear answers and where it is inconclusive. Part I of this Article provides a broad overview of international tax systems, which countries can adopt, with particular attention to aspects of the system adopted by the United States. Part II examines how, and under what circumstances, the current U.S. system defeats the objectives of developing countries in offering tax holidays to U.S. MNCs. It then proposes a structural solution that would address the problem in the context of the ciirrent system. It is, of course, possible that the proposal would not be acceptable to the U.S. Treasury or to developing countries in general. Thus, the remainder of this Article examines Professor Brown's proposal and others that might be considered in meeting the objectives of increasing the FDI of U.S. MNCs in developing countries. Part III identifies the economic, social, and political factors
本文的目的是探讨美国是否应该修改其国际税收规则,以鼓励美国公司在发展中国家投资。以凯伦·布朗教授为代表的一些学者认为,美国现行的国际税收制度不利于发展中国家的利益,应该被一种有利于发展中国家,尤其是非洲国家的制度所取代她建议美国用一种针对发展中国家的豁免制度取代其外国税收抵免机制,至少是针对非洲国家。提议的原因之一是,如下所述,美国现行制度阻止发展中国家提供税收优惠,如免税期,以吸引美国跨国公司的外国直接投资(FDI)。当然,美国对发展中国家的直接投资很少。2001年底,美国所有者在海外赚取的资产总额为6.2万亿美元(按成本计算)。但下面的图表显示,这些资产在发展中国家所占的比例是多么的少(以十亿美元计):2因此,与在其他发达国家的外国直接投资相比,美国在发展中国家的外国直接投资确实不足。但是,像布朗教授提出的建议提出了几个问题。外国直接投资对发展中国家有绝对好处吗?外商直接投资的区位决定因素是什么?发展中国家提供的税收优惠是否有效地吸引外国直接投资,即使在母国税收规则不妨碍它们的情况下?仅靠税收优惠就能吸引外国直接投资吗?还是发展中国家在吸引外国直接投资之前必须满足一些必要的先决条件?母国单方面的税收优惠对增加跨国公司的外国直接投资是否有效?发达国家向发展中国家提供税收补贴好,还是向发展中国家提供直接资金援助好?本文试图探索这些问题,看看证据在哪里支持明确的答案,在哪里是不确定的。本文的第一部分对各国可以采用的国际税收制度进行了广泛的概述,并特别关注美国所采用的制度的各个方面。第二部分考察了美国现行制度是如何以及在何种情况下辜负了发展中国家向美国跨国公司提供免税期的目标。然后,它提出了一个结构性的解决方案,可以在当前系统的上下文中解决问题。当然,美国财政部或发展中国家也有可能不接受这一提议。因此,本文的其余部分将探讨布朗教授的建议以及其他可能被考虑的建议,以实现增加美国跨国公司在发展中国家的外国直接投资的目标。第三部分确定了对发展中国家产生不利影响的经济、社会和政治因素和力量。本讨论的目的是为评估美国的特定税收变化是否会对这些力量和因素产生积极影响奠定基础。第三部分还审查了联合国(un)和经济合作与发展组织(OECD)最近的报告,这些报告分析了发达国家援助发展中国家的水平和方式。将特别注意外国直接投资在这些分析中的作用。第四部分回顾了税收政策对FDI水平和区位影响的经济证据。第五部分介绍了美国国际税收制度的几种不同变化,包括它们的效率和简化效果,以及它们在解决第三部分所确定的问题方面的有效性。最后一节阐述了我自己的政策结论。1 .国际税收制度:概述所有国家都必须有一些制度,根据这些制度,它们将所得税适用于本国国民的跨境商业和投资过渡。…
{"title":"The U.S. Tax Treatment of Foreign Source Income Earned in Developing Countries: A Policy Analysis","authors":"P. McDaniel","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.476581","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.476581","url":null,"abstract":"The purpose of this Article is to explore whether the United States should amend its international tax rules in ways that might encourage U.S. companies to invest in developing countries. Some scholars, notably Professor Karen Brown, have argued that the current U.S. international tax regime works against the interests of developing countries and should be replaced by one that, she asserts, would benefit developing countries in general and African nations in particular.1 She has proposed that the United States replace its foreign tax credit mechanism with an exemption system for developing countries, at the least for Africa. One of the reasons for the proposal is that, as explained below, the current U.S. system prevents developing countries from offering tax incentives, such as tax holidays, to attract foreign direct investment (FDI) by U.S. multinational corporations (MNCs). Certainly, it is the case that little U.S. FDI finds its way to developing countries. At the end of 2001, total U.S.-owner assets earned abroad totaled $6.2 trillion (valued at cost). But the following shows how little of these assets were in developing countries (in $ billions):2 There is thus a real shortfall in U.S. FDI in developing countries as compared to its FDI in other developed countries. But, proposals such as the one put forward by Professor Brown raise several questions. Is FDI an unqualified good for developing countries? What are the determinants in the location of FDI? Are tax incentives offered by developing countries effective in attracting FDI, even in situations where home country tax rules do not thwart them? Can tax incentives alone attract FDI or are there necessary preconditions a developing country must satisfy before there is FDI at all? Are home country unilateral tax incentives effective in increasing FDI by its MNCs? Is it better for developed countries to assist developing countries by offering tax subsidies to its MNCs or by providing direct financial assistance to developing countries? This paper is an effort to explore these questions to see where the evidence supports clear answers and where it is inconclusive. Part I of this Article provides a broad overview of international tax systems, which countries can adopt, with particular attention to aspects of the system adopted by the United States. Part II examines how, and under what circumstances, the current U.S. system defeats the objectives of developing countries in offering tax holidays to U.S. MNCs. It then proposes a structural solution that would address the problem in the context of the ciirrent system. It is, of course, possible that the proposal would not be acceptable to the U.S. Treasury or to developing countries in general. Thus, the remainder of this Article examines Professor Brown's proposal and others that might be considered in meeting the objectives of increasing the FDI of U.S. MNCs in developing countries. Part III identifies the economic, social, and political factors ","PeriodicalId":47068,"journal":{"name":"George Washington Law Review","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":1.5,"publicationDate":"2003-12-08","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"86187467","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 8
Judicial Review and the War on Terrorism 司法审查与反恐战争
IF 1.5 3区 社会学 Q1 Social Sciences Pub Date : 2003-11-12 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.461721
J. Yoo
This article examines the role of the federal courts in the war on terrorism, and contrasts the different judicial roles in reviewing decisions about the conduct of war abroad and within the United States. It explains that judicial refusal to adjudicate questions concerning the initiation and conduct of the war abroad is consistent with a narrow view of judicial review and the political question doctrine. Because the Constitution allocates different war powers to the President and Congress, allowing them to shape warmaking through the interaction of these powers, there is no single, constitutionally-required process for making war that requires judicial enforcement. This view has been borne out in practice, as most recently demonstrated in the wars in Afghanistan and Iraq. The paper also reviews the role played by federal courts with regard to the domestic effects of war, particularly when the war involves American citizens as enemies or when operations occur within the territory of the United States itself. It illustrates the wartime role of judicial review by examining cases arising from the current war against the al Qaeda terrorist organization. In the context of surveillance, the federal courts have granted warrants under the Foreign Intelligence Surveillance Act (FISA) using more flexible standards than exist for a normal search warrant, to permit surveillance of terrorist suspects. With American citizens detained as enemy combatants, the courts have entertained habeas corpus petitions, but have followed a deferential standard of scrutiny for the executive branch's war making decisions. These cases show that while the courts have exercised judicial review over the consequences of the decision to go to war, they have adopted a more flexible, deferential standard of review than would apply to normal, peacetime governmental actions, in order to accommodate the imperatives of conducting war. Thus, judicial review may apply to domestic wartime measures, but in a manner that provides options to the political branches for the conduct of the war, rather than simply serving as a negative check on government action.
本文考察了联邦法院在反恐战争中的作用,并对比了在审查有关海外和美国境内战争行为的决定时不同的司法角色。它解释说,司法拒绝裁决有关海外战争的发起和进行的问题,与司法审查的狭隘观点和政治问题学说是一致的。因为宪法给总统和国会分配了不同的战争权力,允许他们通过这些权力的相互作用来塑造战争,所以没有宪法要求的单一的、需要司法强制执行的战争程序。这种观点已经在实践中得到了证实,最近在阿富汗和伊拉克的战争就证明了这一点。本文还回顾了联邦法院在战争的国内影响方面所发挥的作用,特别是当战争涉及美国公民作为敌人或当行动发生在美国境内时。它通过审查目前与基地恐怖组织的战争中产生的案件,说明了司法审查的战时作用。在监视方面,联邦法院根据《外国情报监视法》(Foreign Intelligence surveillance Act,简称FISA),使用比普通搜查令更为灵活的标准,批准了对恐怖分子嫌疑人的监视。在美国公民作为敌方战斗人员被拘留的情况下,法院受理了人身保护令的请愿,但对行政部门的战争决策遵循了一种恭敬的审查标准。这些案件表明,虽然法院对发动战争的决定的后果进行了司法审查,但它们采取了一种比适用于正常的和平时期政府行动的更灵活、更尊重的审查标准,以便适应进行战争的必要性。因此,司法审查可能适用于国内战时措施,但其方式是为政治部门提供战争行为的选择,而不是简单地对政府行为进行负面检查。
{"title":"Judicial Review and the War on Terrorism","authors":"J. Yoo","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.461721","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.461721","url":null,"abstract":"This article examines the role of the federal courts in the war on terrorism, and contrasts the different judicial roles in reviewing decisions about the conduct of war abroad and within the United States. It explains that judicial refusal to adjudicate questions concerning the initiation and conduct of the war abroad is consistent with a narrow view of judicial review and the political question doctrine. Because the Constitution allocates different war powers to the President and Congress, allowing them to shape warmaking through the interaction of these powers, there is no single, constitutionally-required process for making war that requires judicial enforcement. This view has been borne out in practice, as most recently demonstrated in the wars in Afghanistan and Iraq. The paper also reviews the role played by federal courts with regard to the domestic effects of war, particularly when the war involves American citizens as enemies or when operations occur within the territory of the United States itself. It illustrates the wartime role of judicial review by examining cases arising from the current war against the al Qaeda terrorist organization. In the context of surveillance, the federal courts have granted warrants under the Foreign Intelligence Surveillance Act (FISA) using more flexible standards than exist for a normal search warrant, to permit surveillance of terrorist suspects. With American citizens detained as enemy combatants, the courts have entertained habeas corpus petitions, but have followed a deferential standard of scrutiny for the executive branch's war making decisions. These cases show that while the courts have exercised judicial review over the consequences of the decision to go to war, they have adopted a more flexible, deferential standard of review than would apply to normal, peacetime governmental actions, in order to accommodate the imperatives of conducting war. Thus, judicial review may apply to domestic wartime measures, but in a manner that provides options to the political branches for the conduct of the war, rather than simply serving as a negative check on government action.","PeriodicalId":47068,"journal":{"name":"George Washington Law Review","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":1.5,"publicationDate":"2003-11-12","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"67738937","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 13
A Review of Globalization and its Discontents 回顾全球化及其不满
IF 1.5 3区 社会学 Q1 Social Sciences Pub Date : 2003-10-23 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.460481
K. Kennedy
Globalization and Its Discontents by Joseph Stiglitz is an insider's account of the failings of the Bretton Woods institutions during the Clinton Administration. The author, the 2001 Nobel laureate in economics, gives an insider's view of the role played by the Bretton Woods institutions in the globalization process. Professor Stiglitz's presents several case studies to illustrate how the IMF, with the aid and encouragement of the U.S. Treasury Department, failed to properly manage a number of financial crises that took place during the last decade of the 20th Century. Regrettably, his account is nothing less than a diatribe - unfortunately at times personalized - attacking the entire Bretton Woods system, and in particular the IMF. Stiglitz makes no pretense of being balanced or of writing a scholarly work. Globalization and Its Discontents generates a tremendous amount of heat, but sheds very little light on a critically important subject.
约瑟夫•斯蒂格利茨(Joseph Stiglitz)的《全球化及其不满》(Globalization and Its Discontents)是一位内部人对克林顿政府时期布雷顿森林体系失败的描述。作者是2001年诺贝尔经济学奖得主,他从局内人的角度阐述了布雷顿森林体系在全球化进程中所扮演的角色。斯蒂格利茨教授提出了几个案例研究,以说明国际货币基金组织如何在美国财政部的帮助和鼓励下,未能妥善管理发生在20世纪最后十年的一系列金融危机。令人遗憾的是,他的描述完全是对整个布雷顿森林体系的抨击——不幸的是,有时是个人化的——尤其是对国际货币基金组织。斯蒂格利茨并没有假装自己是平衡的,也没有假装在写一本学术著作。《全球化及其不满》引起了巨大的热议,但对一个至关重要的问题却知之甚少。
{"title":"A Review of Globalization and its Discontents","authors":"K. Kennedy","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.460481","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.460481","url":null,"abstract":"Globalization and Its Discontents by Joseph Stiglitz is an insider's account of the failings of the Bretton Woods institutions during the Clinton Administration. The author, the 2001 Nobel laureate in economics, gives an insider's view of the role played by the Bretton Woods institutions in the globalization process. Professor Stiglitz's presents several case studies to illustrate how the IMF, with the aid and encouragement of the U.S. Treasury Department, failed to properly manage a number of financial crises that took place during the last decade of the 20th Century. Regrettably, his account is nothing less than a diatribe - unfortunately at times personalized - attacking the entire Bretton Woods system, and in particular the IMF. Stiglitz makes no pretense of being balanced or of writing a scholarly work. Globalization and Its Discontents generates a tremendous amount of heat, but sheds very little light on a critically important subject.","PeriodicalId":47068,"journal":{"name":"George Washington Law Review","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":1.5,"publicationDate":"2003-10-23","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"85398401","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 4
A User's Guide to the Stored Communications Act, and a Legislator's Guide to Amending it 《存储通信法案用户指南》和《立法者修改指南》
IF 1.5 3区 社会学 Q1 Social Sciences Pub Date : 2003-08-05 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.421860
Orin S. Kerr
Americans care deeply about their Internet privacy. But if they want to know how federal law protects the privacy of their stored Internet communications, they'll quickly learn that it's surprisingly difficult to figure out. The federal statute that protects the privacy of stored Internet communications is the Stored Communications Act (SCA), passed as part of the Electronic Communications Privacy Act of 1986 and codified at 18 U.S.C. section 2701-11. But courts, legislators, and even legal scholars have had a very hard time understanding the method behind the madness of the SCA. The statute is dense and confusing, and that confusion has made it difficult for legislators to legislate in the field, reporters to report about it, and scholars to write scholarship in this very important area.This Article presents a user's guide to the SCA. It explains in relatively simple terms the structure and text of the Act so that legislators, courts, academics, and students can understand how it works - and in some cases, how it doesn't work. I hope to explain the basic nuts and bolts of the statute and show that the statute works reasonably effectively, although certainly not perfectly. My second goal is to show how Congress needs to amend the SCA. I recommend three ways that Congress should rethink the SCA to better protect the privacy of stored Internet communications, clarify its protections, and update the statute for the present. Specifically, I argue that Congress should raise the threshold the government must satisfy to compel the contents of certain Internet communications; that it should simplify the statute dramatically by eliminating the confusing categories of electronic communication service and remote computing service, and eliminating redundant text; and that it should restructure the remedies scheme for violations of the statute.
美国人非常关心他们的网络隐私。但如果他们想知道联邦法律是如何保护他们存储的互联网通信隐私的,他们很快就会发现,要弄清楚这一点是非常困难的。保护存储互联网通信隐私的联邦法规是《存储通信法案》(SCA),该法案作为1986年《电子通信隐私法案》的一部分通过,并在《美国法典》第18编第2701-11条中编纂。但是,法院、立法者,甚至法律学者都很难理解SCA疯狂背后的方法。这个法规是密集而混乱的,这种混乱使得立法者很难在这个领域立法,记者很难报道它,学者也很难在这个非常重要的领域撰写学术论文。本文提供了SCA的用户指南。它以相对简单的语言解释了该法案的结构和文本,以便立法者、法院、学者和学生能够理解它是如何运作的——在某些情况下,它是如何不起作用的。我希望解释该法规的基本细节,并表明该法规合理有效地发挥作用,尽管肯定不是完美的。我的第二个目标是展示国会需要如何修改SCA。我建议国会通过三种方式重新考虑SCA,以更好地保护存储的互联网通信的隐私,澄清其保护,并更新当前的法规。具体来说,我认为国会应该提高政府必须满足的门槛,以强制提供某些互联网通信的内容;它应该通过消除电子通信服务和远程计算服务的混淆类别以及消除冗余的文本来大幅简化法规;它应该对违反法令的补救方案进行重组。
{"title":"A User's Guide to the Stored Communications Act, and a Legislator's Guide to Amending it","authors":"Orin S. Kerr","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.421860","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.421860","url":null,"abstract":"Americans care deeply about their Internet privacy. But if they want to know how federal law protects the privacy of their stored Internet communications, they'll quickly learn that it's surprisingly difficult to figure out. The federal statute that protects the privacy of stored Internet communications is the Stored Communications Act (SCA), passed as part of the Electronic Communications Privacy Act of 1986 and codified at 18 U.S.C. section 2701-11. But courts, legislators, and even legal scholars have had a very hard time understanding the method behind the madness of the SCA. The statute is dense and confusing, and that confusion has made it difficult for legislators to legislate in the field, reporters to report about it, and scholars to write scholarship in this very important area.This Article presents a user's guide to the SCA. It explains in relatively simple terms the structure and text of the Act so that legislators, courts, academics, and students can understand how it works - and in some cases, how it doesn't work. I hope to explain the basic nuts and bolts of the statute and show that the statute works reasonably effectively, although certainly not perfectly. My second goal is to show how Congress needs to amend the SCA. I recommend three ways that Congress should rethink the SCA to better protect the privacy of stored Internet communications, clarify its protections, and update the statute for the present. Specifically, I argue that Congress should raise the threshold the government must satisfy to compel the contents of certain Internet communications; that it should simplify the statute dramatically by eliminating the confusing categories of electronic communication service and remote computing service, and eliminating redundant text; and that it should restructure the remedies scheme for violations of the statute.","PeriodicalId":47068,"journal":{"name":"George Washington Law Review","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":1.5,"publicationDate":"2003-08-05","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"68734955","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 45
Signaling Behavior, Congressional-Executive Agreements, and the SALT I Interim Agreement 信号行为,国会-行政协议和SALT I临时协议
IF 1.5 3区 社会学 Q1 Social Sciences Pub Date : 2003-04-16 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.379280
Christopher B. Stone
This Article, using a law and behavioral economics perspective, carves out a "signaling exception" to the general rule that Presidents must ratify national security accords as treaties and international trade accords as congressional-executive agreements. Under this signaling exception, the President can submit national security accords as congressional-executive agreements when 1) the accord is temporary, and 2) the accord signals that the United States has engaged in learning behavior (as described in the political science literature) about the nature of international affairs. Signaling behavior is particularly common in temporary agreements. The interim nature of such agreements allows the United States to signal incremental trust in its counterparties while hedging its risk. Using the SALT I accords as a case study, this Article locates the President's power to signal in the well-accepted sole communication power, which, under the signaling exception, trumps the Senate's right to advise and consent when the accord in question contains a disproportionate signaling component vis-a-vis its substantive, bargained-for component. Presidents could thus send signals in the form of sole executive agreements or congressional-executive agreements. The Constitution requires the latter vehicle because signals display network effects; they become more credible to foreign powers, and hence more valuable, with congressional support.
本文运用法律和行为经济学的观点,对总统必须批准国家安全协定作为条约和国际贸易协定作为国会-行政协议的一般规则,提出了一个“信号例外”。根据这一信号例外,总统可以在以下情况下将国家安全协议作为国会-行政协议提交:1)该协议是临时的,2)该协议表明美国已经参与了有关国际事务性质的学习行为(如政治科学文献中所描述的)。信号行为在临时协议中尤为常见。此类协议的临时性质使美国能够在对冲风险的同时,对其交易对手发出增量信任的信号。本文以《第一阶段战略武器协定》为例,将总统的发信号权置于公认的唯一通信权中,在发信号例外情况下,当有关协议包含与其实质性、讨价还价的组成部分不成比例的信号组成部分时,总统的发信号权胜过参议院的建议和同意权。因此,总统可以以单独行政协议或国会行政协议的形式发出信号。宪法要求后一种交通工具,因为信号显示网络效应;在国会的支持下,它们对外国势力来说变得更加可信,因此也更有价值。
{"title":"Signaling Behavior, Congressional-Executive Agreements, and the SALT I Interim Agreement","authors":"Christopher B. Stone","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.379280","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.379280","url":null,"abstract":"This Article, using a law and behavioral economics perspective, carves out a \"signaling exception\" to the general rule that Presidents must ratify national security accords as treaties and international trade accords as congressional-executive agreements. Under this signaling exception, the President can submit national security accords as congressional-executive agreements when 1) the accord is temporary, and 2) the accord signals that the United States has engaged in learning behavior (as described in the political science literature) about the nature of international affairs. Signaling behavior is particularly common in temporary agreements. The interim nature of such agreements allows the United States to signal incremental trust in its counterparties while hedging its risk. Using the SALT I accords as a case study, this Article locates the President's power to signal in the well-accepted sole communication power, which, under the signaling exception, trumps the Senate's right to advise and consent when the accord in question contains a disproportionate signaling component vis-a-vis its substantive, bargained-for component. Presidents could thus send signals in the form of sole executive agreements or congressional-executive agreements. The Constitution requires the latter vehicle because signals display network effects; they become more credible to foreign powers, and hence more valuable, with congressional support.","PeriodicalId":47068,"journal":{"name":"George Washington Law Review","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":1.5,"publicationDate":"2003-04-16","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"88418855","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 3
Japanese Attitudes Towards Contracts: An Empirical Wrinkle in the Debate 日本人对契约的态度:争论中的经验皱纹
IF 1.5 3区 社会学 Q1 Social Sciences Pub Date : 2003-04-10 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.363400
Michael K. Young, Masanobu Kato, A. Fujimoto
In this article, we re-examine, from an empirical perspective, the debate about Japanese legal consciousness. In particular, we analyze the result of a survey we conducted among Japanese law and business students to determine their attitudes towards the use of contracts as a device to order economic exchanges. We hypothesized that if the generally accepted view of Japanese attitudes towards law were correct, Japanese respondents who had not studied law and therefore possessed the "traditional Japanese attitudes" towards law would be relatively disinclined to urge strict compliance with the terms of a contract. Respondents who had studied law, on the other hand, we hypothesized, would be more inclined to see the contract enforced as written. In other words, legal education would imbue in its recipients an "American" attitude towards law, that is, a preference for strict adherence to the precise contractual terms. The data suggested just the opposite. Law students had a decided preference, over their non-law counterparts, for flexibility in the interpretation and execution of contracts. The more law students studied, the stronger that preference. This preference seems to decline, however, when law students are placed in an advisory, as opposed to advocacy role. We also observed significant gender based differences, with women preferring flexibility to a significant degree over men. Some regional differences were also observed, but were comparatively minor. Finally, we also explored whether respondents were inclined to favor a company because it was Japanese. Generally speaking, we did not observe such bias in most cases. But interesting exceptions were found. For example, we observed some degree of bias against Japanese companies in cases in which the opposing company was Korean or Chinese. And when the opposing company was American, only law students exhibited any national bias in favor of the Japanese company. Non-law students did not show any bias in favor of companies from Japan in any of the samples.
本文从实证的角度重新审视日本法律意识之争。特别是,我们分析了我们在日本法律和商业学生中进行的一项调查的结果,以确定他们对使用合同作为安排经济交流的手段的态度。我们假设,如果普遍接受的关于日本人对待法律的态度的观点是正确的,那么没有学习过法律并因此对法律持有“传统日本态度”的日本受访者将相对不愿意敦促严格遵守合同条款。另一方面,我们假设,学习过法律的受访者更倾向于看到合同按照书面形式执行。换句话说,法律教育将向其接受者灌输一种对法律的“美国”态度,即偏爱严格遵守确切的合同条款。数据显示的情况正好相反。与非法律专业的学生相比,法律专业的学生更倾向于灵活地解释和执行合同。学法律的学生越多,这种偏好就越强烈。然而,当法律系学生被置于顾问而不是辩护角色时,这种偏好似乎有所下降。我们还观察到明显的性别差异,女性比男性更喜欢灵活性。也观察到一些区域差异,但相对较小。最后,我们还探讨了受访者是否倾向于支持一家公司,因为它是日本的。一般来说,我们在大多数情况下没有观察到这种偏差。但也发现了有趣的例外。例如,我们观察到,当对手是韩国公司或中国公司时,人们对日本公司有一定程度的偏见。当对手是美国公司时,只有法学院学生表现出支持日本公司的民族偏见。在所有样本中,非法律专业的学生都没有表现出对日本公司的偏好。
{"title":"Japanese Attitudes Towards Contracts: An Empirical Wrinkle in the Debate","authors":"Michael K. Young, Masanobu Kato, A. Fujimoto","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.363400","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.363400","url":null,"abstract":"In this article, we re-examine, from an empirical perspective, the debate about Japanese legal consciousness. In particular, we analyze the result of a survey we conducted among Japanese law and business students to determine their attitudes towards the use of contracts as a device to order economic exchanges. We hypothesized that if the generally accepted view of Japanese attitudes towards law were correct, Japanese respondents who had not studied law and therefore possessed the \"traditional Japanese attitudes\" towards law would be relatively disinclined to urge strict compliance with the terms of a contract. Respondents who had studied law, on the other hand, we hypothesized, would be more inclined to see the contract enforced as written. In other words, legal education would imbue in its recipients an \"American\" attitude towards law, that is, a preference for strict adherence to the precise contractual terms. The data suggested just the opposite. Law students had a decided preference, over their non-law counterparts, for flexibility in the interpretation and execution of contracts. The more law students studied, the stronger that preference. This preference seems to decline, however, when law students are placed in an advisory, as opposed to advocacy role. We also observed significant gender based differences, with women preferring flexibility to a significant degree over men. Some regional differences were also observed, but were comparatively minor. Finally, we also explored whether respondents were inclined to favor a company because it was Japanese. Generally speaking, we did not observe such bias in most cases. But interesting exceptions were found. For example, we observed some degree of bias against Japanese companies in cases in which the opposing company was Korean or Chinese. And when the opposing company was American, only law students exhibited any national bias in favor of the Japanese company. Non-law students did not show any bias in favor of companies from Japan in any of the samples.","PeriodicalId":47068,"journal":{"name":"George Washington Law Review","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":1.5,"publicationDate":"2003-04-10","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"84873527","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 3
Questions for the Critics of Judicial Review 司法审查批评者的问题
IF 1.5 3区 社会学 Q1 Social Sciences Pub Date : 2003-01-01 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.2857464
S. Prakash, J. Yoo
Judicial review remains one of the American Constitution's most controversial features. It has made American judges some of the most powerful in the world, with a potent role in shaping the everyday lives of Americans. Perhaps for this reason, scholars and judges continue to question its origins and legitimacy, with recent articles appearing in the Harvard Law Review and the Columbia Law Review,' and with Justices Stephen Breyer and David Souter challenging the constitutionality of judicial review in federalism cases. In earlier articles, we laid out the origins of judicial review. Rather than reiterating the affirmative case for judicial review, here we respond directly to the arguments of the leading recent critic, Professor Larry Kramer. We have no quarrel with Professor Kramer's uncontroversial (and indeed, so far as we know, uncontroverted) statement that the Founders envisioned that the Constitution would be enforced through popular means such as voting, petitioning, and mobbing. We likewise agree with his assertion that the Constitution was never meant to enshrine a Cooper v. Aaron type of judicial supremacy. Yet, we profoundly disagree with Professor Kramer's controversial claims that the Constitution, as originally understood, never authorized judicial review, and that the Founders regarded popular constitutional methods as the exclusive means of safeguarding the Constitution. First, Professor Kramer, like Professors Jesse Choper and Herbert Wechsler before him, ignores the constitutional text and structure. Fairly read, the Constitution's text and structure establishes judicial review in a number of ways. Second, the Constitution's text, as well as constitutional practice at the time of the Founding, contradicts Professor Kramer's theory that the Founders meant the Constitution to be a political-legal document ― a document to be enforced exclusively through popular means. Indeed, Professor Kramer's admission that the Constitution is judicially enforceable against the states undermines his own theory. Third, we believe that Professor Kramer has made methodological errors in his use of the historical materials. In particular, he never squares his claims with the secondary historical literature that runs counter to his thesis. Moreover, he implicitly adopts the stance that, in order for something to be historically established, there must be a solely quantitative level of historical proof; in his argument, the quality of the evidence is apparently of no moment. Fourth, the historical evidence, both quantitatively and qualitatively, refutes Professor Kramer's conclusions. The Founders acknowledged that the Constitution authorized judicial review dozens of times, and no Founder appears ever to have argued, during the ratification fight, that the Constitution either barred or did not permit judicial review. Ironically, though Professor Kramer belittles the evidence in favor of the constitutionality of judicial review, there is virtually no
司法审查仍然是美国宪法最具争议的特征之一。它使美国法官成为世界上最有权力的法官之一,在塑造美国人的日常生活中发挥着强有力的作用。也许正是因为这个原因,学者和法官们继续质疑它的起源和合法性,最近的文章出现在《哈佛法律评论》和《哥伦比亚法律评论》上,法官斯蒂芬·布雷耶和大卫·苏特质疑联邦主义案件中司法审查的合宪性。在之前的文章中,我们阐述了司法审查的起源。在这里,我们不是重申司法审查的肯定案例,而是直接回应最近的主要评论家拉里·克莱默教授的论点。我们对克雷默教授无可争议的(事实上,据我们所知,无可争议的)陈述没有异议,即开国元勋们设想宪法将通过投票、请愿和集会等大众手段来执行。我们同样同意他的主张,即《宪法》从来就不是要确立库珀诉亚伦式的司法至上。然而,我们完全不同意克莱默教授有争议的主张,即宪法在最初的理解中从未授权司法审查,开国元勋们认为大众的宪法方法是维护宪法的唯一手段。首先,克雷默教授,就像他之前的杰西·乔珀教授和赫伯特·韦克斯勒教授一样,忽视了宪法的文本和结构。公平地说,宪法的文本和结构以多种方式确立了司法审查。其次,宪法的文本,以及建国时的宪法实践,与克莱默教授的理论相矛盾,克莱默教授认为,开国元勋们的意思是宪法是一份政治法律文件,一份只能通过民众手段来执行的文件。事实上,克雷默教授承认宪法在司法上可以对各州强制执行,这削弱了他自己的理论。第三,我们认为克莱默教授在使用历史资料时犯了方法论上的错误。特别是,他从不将自己的主张与与他的论点背道而驰的二手历史文献相一致。此外,他还含蓄地认为,要使某一事物在历史上得到确立,就必须有一种定量的历史证据;在他的论证中,证据的质量显然无关紧要。第四,历史证据在数量和质量上都反驳了克莱默教授的结论。开国元勋们承认,宪法多次授权司法审查,而且在批准过程中,似乎没有一位开国元勋曾辩称,宪法禁止或不允许司法审查。具有讽刺意味的是,尽管克莱默教授贬低了支持司法审查合宪性的证据,但实际上没有证据支持他的观点,即宪法的政治保障没有给司法审查留下余地。
{"title":"Questions for the Critics of Judicial Review","authors":"S. Prakash, J. Yoo","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.2857464","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.2857464","url":null,"abstract":"Judicial review remains one of the American Constitution's most controversial features. It has made American judges some of the most powerful in the world, with a potent role in shaping the everyday lives of Americans. Perhaps for this reason, scholars and judges continue to question its origins and legitimacy, with recent articles appearing in the Harvard Law Review and the Columbia Law Review,' and with Justices Stephen Breyer and David Souter challenging the constitutionality of judicial review in federalism cases. In earlier articles, we laid out the origins of judicial review. Rather than reiterating the affirmative case for judicial review, here we respond directly to the arguments of the leading recent critic, Professor Larry Kramer. We have no quarrel with Professor Kramer's uncontroversial (and indeed, so far as we know, uncontroverted) statement that the Founders envisioned that the Constitution would be enforced through popular means such as voting, petitioning, and mobbing. We likewise agree with his assertion that the Constitution was never meant to enshrine a Cooper v. Aaron type of judicial supremacy. Yet, we profoundly disagree with Professor Kramer's controversial claims that the Constitution, as originally understood, never authorized judicial review, and that the Founders regarded popular constitutional methods as the exclusive means of safeguarding the Constitution. First, Professor Kramer, like Professors Jesse Choper and Herbert Wechsler before him, ignores the constitutional text and structure. Fairly read, the Constitution's text and structure establishes judicial review in a number of ways. Second, the Constitution's text, as well as constitutional practice at the time of the Founding, contradicts Professor Kramer's theory that the Founders meant the Constitution to be a political-legal document ― a document to be enforced exclusively through popular means. Indeed, Professor Kramer's admission that the Constitution is judicially enforceable against the states undermines his own theory. Third, we believe that Professor Kramer has made methodological errors in his use of the historical materials. In particular, he never squares his claims with the secondary historical literature that runs counter to his thesis. Moreover, he implicitly adopts the stance that, in order for something to be historically established, there must be a solely quantitative level of historical proof; in his argument, the quality of the evidence is apparently of no moment. Fourth, the historical evidence, both quantitatively and qualitatively, refutes Professor Kramer's conclusions. The Founders acknowledged that the Constitution authorized judicial review dozens of times, and no Founder appears ever to have argued, during the ratification fight, that the Constitution either barred or did not permit judicial review. Ironically, though Professor Kramer belittles the evidence in favor of the constitutionality of judicial review, there is virtually no ","PeriodicalId":47068,"journal":{"name":"George Washington Law Review","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":1.5,"publicationDate":"2003-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"68394862","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
E-formed consent: evaluating the interplay between interactive technology and informed consent. 电子形式的同意:评估互动技术与知情同意之间的相互作用。
IF 1.5 3区 社会学 Q1 Social Sciences Pub Date : 2002-06-01
Peter Brensilver
{"title":"E-formed consent: evaluating the interplay between interactive technology and informed consent.","authors":"Peter Brensilver","doi":"","DOIUrl":"","url":null,"abstract":"","PeriodicalId":47068,"journal":{"name":"George Washington Law Review","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":1.5,"publicationDate":"2002-06-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"24579571","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
期刊
George Washington Law Review
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1