首页 > 最新文献

American Business Law Journal最新文献

英文 中文
Squeezing linkLine: Rethinking Recoupment in Price Squeeze Cases 挤压链接线:价格挤压案例中的回溯再思考
IF 1.2 3区 社会学 Q3 BUSINESS Pub Date : 2020-07-20 DOI: 10.1111/ablj.12165
Patrick Kennedy

The Supreme Court's decision in Pacific Bell Telephone Co. v. linkLine Communications, Inc. removed an important tool from competition regulators’ arsenals. Not only did the Court express skepticism about the existence of a price squeeze cause of action, but it also applied the economically mismatched predatory pricing test to price squeeze cases. Unfortunately, the lack of clarity on linkLine's reach also caused significant confusion in the lower courts. Examining these issues, this article clarifies the distinction between price squeeze and predatory pricing claims, and argues that the second step of the predatory pricing test, probability of recoupment, is inappropriate for price squeeze cases and should either be dropped from the test or replaced with a presumption of recoupment.

美国最高法院在太平洋贝尔电话公司(Pacific Bell Telephone Co.)诉linkLine Communications, Inc.一案中做出的裁决,使竞争监管机构失去了一个重要工具。法院不仅对价格挤压诉因的存在表示怀疑,而且还将经济上不匹配的掠夺性定价测试应用于价格挤压案件。不幸的是,对linkLine的影响范围的不明确也在下级法院造成了严重的混乱。研究这些问题,本文澄清了价格挤压和掠夺性定价索赔之间的区别,并认为掠夺性定价测试的第二步,补偿概率,不适合价格挤压案件,应该从测试中删除或代之以补偿假设。
{"title":"Squeezing linkLine: Rethinking Recoupment in Price Squeeze Cases","authors":"Patrick Kennedy","doi":"10.1111/ablj.12165","DOIUrl":"10.1111/ablj.12165","url":null,"abstract":"<p><i>The Supreme Court's decision in</i> Pacific Bell Telephone Co. v. linkLine Communications, Inc. <i>removed an important tool from competition regulators’ arsenals. Not only did the Court express skepticism about the existence of a price squeeze cause of action, but it also applied the economically mismatched predatory pricing test to price squeeze cases. Unfortunately, the lack of clarity on</i> linkLine<i>'s reach also caused significant confusion in the lower courts. Examining these issues, this article clarifies the distinction between price squeeze and predatory pricing claims, and argues that the second step of the predatory pricing test, probability of recoupment, is inappropriate for price squeeze cases and should either be dropped from the test or replaced with a presumption of recoupment.</i></p>","PeriodicalId":54186,"journal":{"name":"American Business Law Journal","volume":"57 2","pages":"383-437"},"PeriodicalIF":1.2,"publicationDate":"2020-07-20","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1111/ablj.12165","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"48543429","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Enhancing Rescue in Chapter 11: Lessons from Reform Efforts in the United Kingdom 第十一章加强救助:英国改革的经验教训
IF 1.2 3区 社会学 Q3 BUSINESS Pub Date : 2020-07-20 DOI: 10.1111/ablj.12158
Robert J. Landry III

This is a dynamic time for insolvency law. Many jurisdictions have made or are considering reforms to their insolvency regimes. The United Kingdom has proposed a new standalone restructuring mechanism that incorporates many attributes of Chapter 11, including a cross-class cram down and the absolute priority rule. A distinctive feature of the UK proposal is the infusion of judicial discretion permitting courts to deviate from the absolute priority rule. This discretion is not permitted in the United States. This judicial discretion addresses a key problem with the application of the absolute priority rule in the United Statesit may serve as an impediment to reorganization. This impediment is exacerbated by the recent U.S. Supreme Court decision, Czyzewski v. Jevic Holding Corp., which impacts the effective use of Chapter 11 rescue tools. This article explores the absolute priority rule, the problems associated with it, and the effect of Jevic in the United States. Drawing on the UK reform proposal, I argue that the United States should implement reforms that infuse judicial discretion into the application of the absolute priority rule. Doing so will facilitate the underlying policy goal of rescuing the company in Chapter 11 and also promote a broader policy goal of rescuing the business.

这是破产法的一个动态时期。许多司法管辖区已经或正在考虑对其破产制度进行改革。英国提出了一种新的独立重组机制,该机制融合了破产法第11章的许多属性,包括跨类强制收购和绝对优先规则。英国提案的一个显著特点是引入司法自由裁量权,允许法院偏离绝对优先原则。这种自由裁量权在美国是不允许的。这种司法自由裁量权解决了绝对优先权规则在美国适用中的一个关键问题——它可能成为重组的障碍。最近美国最高法院对Czyzewski v. Jevic Holding Corp的裁决加剧了这一障碍,该裁决影响了第11章救助工具的有效使用。本文探讨了绝对优先原则、与之相关的问题以及犹太人在美国的影响。借鉴英国的改革建议,我认为美国应该实施改革,将司法自由裁量权注入到绝对优先规则的适用中。这样做将有助于实现《破产法》第11章中拯救公司的基本政策目标,并促进拯救企业的更广泛政策目标。
{"title":"Enhancing Rescue in Chapter 11: Lessons from Reform Efforts in the United Kingdom","authors":"Robert J. Landry III","doi":"10.1111/ablj.12158","DOIUrl":"10.1111/ablj.12158","url":null,"abstract":"<p><i>This is a dynamic time for insolvency law. Many jurisdictions have made or are considering reforms to their insolvency regimes. The United Kingdom has proposed a new standalone restructuring mechanism that incorporates many attributes of Chapter 11, including a cross-class cram down and the absolute priority rule. A distinctive feature of the UK proposal is the infusion of judicial discretion permitting courts to deviate from the absolute priority rule. This discretion is not permitted in the United States. This judicial discretion addresses a key problem with the application of the absolute priority rule in the United States</i>—<i>it may serve as an impediment to reorganization. This impediment is exacerbated by the recent U.S. Supreme Court decision,</i> Czyzewski v. Jevic Holding Corp., <i>which impacts the effective use of Chapter 11 rescue tools. This article explores the absolute priority rule, the problems associated with it, and the effect of</i> Jevic <i>in the United States. Drawing on the UK reform proposal, I argue that the United States should implement reforms that infuse judicial discretion into the application of the absolute priority rule. Doing so will facilitate the underlying policy goal of rescuing the company in Chapter 11 and also promote a broader policy goal of rescuing the business.</i></p>","PeriodicalId":54186,"journal":{"name":"American Business Law Journal","volume":"57 2","pages":"227-279"},"PeriodicalIF":1.2,"publicationDate":"2020-07-20","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1111/ablj.12158","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"46897489","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
The Trouble with Boycotts: Can Fossil Fuel Divest Campaigns Be Prohibited? 抵制的麻烦:化石燃料潜水活动可以被禁止吗?
IF 1.2 3区 社会学 Q3 BUSINESS Pub Date : 2020-04-15 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3593934
Inara K. Scott
Organizations like 350.org, Insure our Future, and DivestInvest are leading campaigns to urge boycott and divestment from fossil fuels as a means of addressing climate change. Increasingly, they are finding success, from individual consumers to massive pension and sovereign wealth funds. However, as organized group boycotts, divest campaigns may be vulnerable to prosecution under antitrust law. This article explores the likelihood of success in such a case, considering the history of the legal treatment of organized boycotts, the scope and purpose of antitrust law, and the possible application of the First Amendment to the divestment context. The article finds that fossil fuel boycotts straddle a number of contradictory characteristics, making application of existing theories inadequate. In particular, existing precedent protects political boycotts, but not those with primarily economic objectives, and fails to definitively address whether a non-competitive actor may undertake concerted action under antitrust law. In the context of climate change, where the political is economic, and political goals may seek significant economic changes (such as undermining an entire industry), we find existing theories may lead to a result that threatens both free expression and the health of the planet. The essential flexibility of the Sherman Act, however, provides room for protection of political activity, even where the ultimate objective is economic in nature.
350.org、Insure our Future和DivestInvest等组织正在领导运动,敦促抵制和撤资化石燃料,以此作为应对气候变化的手段。从个人消费者到庞大的养老金和主权财富基金,他们越来越成功。然而,由于有组织的团体抵制,撤资运动可能容易受到反垄断法的起诉。本文探讨了在这种情况下成功的可能性,考虑到有组织抵制的法律处理历史、反垄断法的范围和目的,以及第一修正案在撤资背景下的可能应用。文章发现,化石燃料抵制跨越了许多相互矛盾的特征,使得现有理论的应用不足。特别是,现有先例保护政治抵制,但不保护那些主要以经济目标为目的的抵制,并且未能明确解决非竞争行为者是否可以根据反垄断法采取一致行动的问题。在气候变化的背景下,政治就是经济,政治目标可能寻求重大的经济变化(例如破坏整个行业),我们发现现有的理论可能会导致威胁言论自由和地球健康的结果。然而,《谢尔曼法案》的基本灵活性为保护政治活动提供了空间,即使最终目标是经济性质的。
{"title":"The Trouble with Boycotts: Can Fossil Fuel Divest Campaigns Be Prohibited?","authors":"Inara K. Scott","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3593934","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3593934","url":null,"abstract":"Organizations like 350.org, Insure our Future, and DivestInvest are leading campaigns to urge boycott and divestment from fossil fuels as a means of addressing climate change. Increasingly, they are finding success, from individual consumers to massive pension and sovereign wealth funds. However, as organized group boycotts, divest campaigns may be vulnerable to prosecution under antitrust law. This article explores the likelihood of success in such a case, considering the history of the legal treatment of organized boycotts, the scope and purpose of antitrust law, and the possible application of the First Amendment to the divestment context. The article finds that fossil fuel boycotts straddle a number of contradictory characteristics, making application of existing theories inadequate. In particular, existing precedent protects political boycotts, but not those with primarily economic objectives, and fails to definitively address whether a non-competitive actor may undertake concerted action under antitrust law. In the context of climate change, where the political is economic, and political goals may seek significant economic changes (such as undermining an entire industry), we find existing theories may lead to a result that threatens both free expression and the health of the planet. The essential flexibility of the Sherman Act, however, provides room for protection of political activity, even where the ultimate objective is economic in nature.","PeriodicalId":54186,"journal":{"name":"American Business Law Journal","volume":" ","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":1.2,"publicationDate":"2020-04-15","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"42751825","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
NAFTA 2.0 and LGBTQ Employment Discrimination NAFTA 2.0与LGBTQ就业歧视
IF 1.2 3区 社会学 Q3 BUSINESS Pub Date : 2020-03-18 DOI: 10.1111/ablj.12154
Alex Reed

Because federal law does not expressly prohibit employment discrimination on the basis of sexual orientation or gender identity, LGBTQ Americans were thrilled to learn that a preliminary draft of the United States–Mexico–Canada Agreement (USMCA) included a provision (the Provision) requiring each nation to enact LGBTQ-inclusive nondiscrimination laws. That excitement promptly turned to despair, however, after the Trump administration insisted on the addition of a footnote (the Footnote) designed to exempt the United States from the Provision. To date, the Footnote has been derided by scholars and trade experts alike as a transparent attempt to evade the Provision's LGBTQ-inclusive mandate. Yet, by focusing only on what the USMCA does not do, these analyses overlook what the agreement does do, even if unintended, to benefit LGBTQ Americans. This article provides the first comprehensive analysis of the USMCA's implications for federal antidiscrimination law and demonstrates that—regardless of how the Supreme Court rules in a trio of LGBTQ employment cases—the Footnote actually stands to help, not hinder, the cause of LGBTQ equality.

由于联邦法律没有明确禁止基于性取向或性别认同的就业歧视,LGBTQ美国人兴奋地得知,美国-墨西哥-加拿大协议(USMCA)的初步草案包括了一项条款(该条款),要求每个国家制定包括LGBTQ的非歧视法律。然而,在特朗普政府坚持要增加一个旨在使美国不受该条款约束的脚注(the footnote)之后,这种兴奋很快变成了绝望。迄今为止,学者和贸易专家都嘲笑该脚注是在公然逃避该条款对lgbtq的包容性授权。然而,由于只关注USMCA没有做的事情,这些分析忽视了该协议对LGBTQ美国人的好处,即使是无意的。本文首次全面分析了USMCA对联邦反歧视法的影响,并证明了无论最高法院如何裁决LGBTQ就业案件,脚注实际上是在帮助而不是阻碍LGBTQ平等的事业。
{"title":"NAFTA 2.0 and LGBTQ Employment Discrimination","authors":"Alex Reed","doi":"10.1111/ablj.12154","DOIUrl":"10.1111/ablj.12154","url":null,"abstract":"<p>Because federal law does not expressly prohibit employment discrimination on the basis of sexual orientation or gender identity, LGBTQ Americans were thrilled to learn that a preliminary draft of the United States–Mexico–Canada Agreement (USMCA) included a provision (the Provision) requiring each nation to enact LGBTQ-inclusive nondiscrimination laws. That excitement promptly turned to despair, however, after the Trump administration insisted on the addition of a footnote (the Footnote) designed to exempt the United States from the Provision. To date, the Footnote has been derided by scholars and trade experts alike as a transparent attempt to evade the Provision's LGBTQ-inclusive mandate. Yet, by focusing only on what the USMCA does not do, these analyses overlook what the agreement does do, even if unintended, to benefit LGBTQ Americans. This article provides the first comprehensive analysis of the USMCA's implications for federal antidiscrimination law and demonstrates that—regardless of how the Supreme Court rules in a trio of LGBTQ employment cases—the Footnote actually stands to help, not hinder, the cause of LGBTQ equality.</p>","PeriodicalId":54186,"journal":{"name":"American Business Law Journal","volume":"57 1","pages":"5-44"},"PeriodicalIF":1.2,"publicationDate":"2020-03-18","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1111/ablj.12154","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"48757123","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
The Inefficiency of Quasi–Per Se Rules: Regulating Information Exchange in EU and U.S. Antitrust Law 准本质规则的无效性:欧盟和美国反垄断法对信息交换的规范
IF 1.2 3区 社会学 Q3 BUSINESS Pub Date : 2020-03-18 DOI: 10.1111/ablj.12155
Kenneth Khoo, Jerrold Soh

It is well understood that the exchange of information between horizontal competitors can violate competition law provisions in both the European Union (EU) and the United States, namely, article 101 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union and section 1 of the Sherman Act. However, despite ostensible similarities between EU and U.S. antitrust law concerning interfirm information exchange, substantial differences remain. In this article, we make a normative argument for the U.S. antitrust regime's approach, on the basis that the United States’ approach to information exchange is likely to be more efficient than the relevant approach under the EU competition regime. Using economic theories of harm concerning information exchange to understand the imposition of liability in relation to “stand-alone” instances of information exchange, we argue that such liability must be grounded on the conception of a prophylactic rule. We characterize this rule as a form of ex ante regulation and explain why it has no ex post counterpart in antitrust law. In contrast to the U.S. antitrust regime, we argue that the implementation of such a rule pursuant to EU competition law leads to higher error costs without a significant reduction in regulatory costs. As a majority of jurisdictions have competition law regimes that resemble EU competition law more closely than U.S. antitrust law, our thesis has important implications for competition regimes around the world.

众所周知,横向竞争对手之间的信息交流可能违反欧洲联盟和美国的竞争法规定,即《欧洲联盟运作条约》第101条和《谢尔曼法》第1节。然而,尽管欧盟和美国在公司间信息交换方面的反垄断法表面上有相似之处,但仍存在实质性差异。在这篇文章中,我们对美国反垄断制度的方法进行了规范性论证,因为美国的信息交换方法可能比欧盟竞争制度下的相关方法更有效。利用与信息交换有关的损害经济学理论来理解与信息交换的“独立”情况有关的责任的施加,我们认为这种责任必须以预防性规则的概念为基础。我们将这一规则定性为事前监管的一种形式,并解释为什么在反垄断法中没有事后监管。与美国的反垄断制度相比,我们认为,根据欧盟竞争法实施此类规则会导致更高的错误成本,而不会显著降低监管成本。由于大多数司法管辖区的竞争法制度与欧盟竞争法比美国反垄断法更为相似,我们的论文对世界各地的竞争制度具有重要意义。
{"title":"The Inefficiency of Quasi–Per Se Rules: Regulating Information Exchange in EU and U.S. Antitrust Law","authors":"Kenneth Khoo,&nbsp;Jerrold Soh","doi":"10.1111/ablj.12155","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1111/ablj.12155","url":null,"abstract":"<p>It is well understood that the exchange of information between horizontal competitors can violate competition law provisions in both the European Union (EU) and the United States, namely, article 101 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union and section 1 of the Sherman Act. However, despite ostensible similarities between EU and U.S. antitrust law concerning interfirm information exchange, substantial differences remain. In this article, we make a normative argument for the U.S. antitrust regime's approach, on the basis that the United States’ approach to information exchange is likely to be more efficient than the relevant approach under the EU competition regime. Using economic theories of harm concerning information exchange to understand the imposition of liability in relation to “stand-alone” instances of information exchange, we argue that such liability must be grounded on the conception of a prophylactic rule. We characterize this rule as a form of ex ante regulation and explain why it has no ex post counterpart in antitrust law. In contrast to the U.S. antitrust regime, we argue that the implementation of such a rule pursuant to EU competition law leads to higher error costs without a significant reduction in regulatory costs. As a majority of jurisdictions have competition law regimes that resemble EU competition law more closely than U.S. antitrust law, our thesis has important implications for competition regimes around the world.</p>","PeriodicalId":54186,"journal":{"name":"American Business Law Journal","volume":"57 1","pages":"45-111"},"PeriodicalIF":1.2,"publicationDate":"2020-03-18","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1111/ablj.12155","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"71972343","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Regulatory Categorization and Arbitrage: How Daily Fantasy Sports Companies Navigated Regulatory Categories Before and After Legalized Gambling 监管分类和套利:每日幻想体育公司在赌博合法化前后如何导航监管分类
IF 1.2 3区 社会学 Q3 BUSINESS Pub Date : 2020-03-18 DOI: 10.1111/ablj.12156
John T. Holden J.D., Ph.D., Christopher M. McLeod Ph.D., Marc Edelman J.D.

This article uses the context of daily fantasy sports (DFS) to analyze how companies use strategic categorization in regulatory arbitrage. Recent actions by two leaders in the DFS industry, DraftKings and FanDuel, provide an ideal context to study this issue. DraftKings and FanDuel categorized themselves differently to different audiences at different times in a manner that evaded categorization as an illegal gambling activity, only to then dominate the sports betting market after the Supreme Court's decision in Murphy v. NCAA. We examine how this type of strategic categorization, which we call “fluid categorization,” raises important questions for regulators and others concerned with regulatory arbitrage. We also explore how fluid categorization provides lessons for other businesses. While this article has broad implications for the sports gambling marketplace, it also contributes to meaningful discourse for the broader business community, as its findings are relevant to industries beyond DFS that offer gray market products and seek to fight categorical labels until there is a reclassification event.

本文利用日常幻想体育(DFS)的背景来分析公司如何在监管套利中使用战略分类。DFS行业的两位领导者DraftKings和FanDuel最近的行动为研究这一问题提供了理想的背景。DraftKings和FanDuel在不同的时间对不同的观众进行了不同的分类,以避免被归类为非法赌博活动,但在最高法院对Murphy诉NCAA案作出裁决后,他们才主导了体育博彩市场。我们研究了这种我们称之为“流动分类”的战略分类如何为监管机构和其他关注监管套利的机构提出重要问题。我们还探讨了流动分类如何为其他企业提供经验教训。虽然这篇文章对体育博彩市场有着广泛的影响,但它也有助于更广泛的商业界进行有意义的讨论,因为它的研究结果与DFS以外的行业有关,这些行业提供灰色市场产品,并寻求对抗分类标签,直到发生重新分类事件。
{"title":"Regulatory Categorization and Arbitrage: How Daily Fantasy Sports Companies Navigated Regulatory Categories Before and After Legalized Gambling","authors":"John T. Holden J.D., Ph.D.,&nbsp;Christopher M. McLeod Ph.D.,&nbsp;Marc Edelman J.D.","doi":"10.1111/ablj.12156","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1111/ablj.12156","url":null,"abstract":"<p>This article uses the context of daily fantasy sports (DFS) to analyze how companies use strategic categorization in regulatory arbitrage. Recent actions by two leaders in the DFS industry, DraftKings and FanDuel, provide an ideal context to study this issue. DraftKings and FanDuel categorized themselves differently to different audiences at different times in a manner that evaded categorization as an illegal gambling activity, only to then dominate the sports betting market after the Supreme Court's decision in <i>Murphy v. NCAA</i>. We examine how this type of strategic categorization, which we call “fluid categorization,” raises important questions for regulators and others concerned with regulatory arbitrage. We also explore how fluid categorization provides lessons for other businesses. While this article has broad implications for the sports gambling marketplace, it also contributes to meaningful discourse for the broader business community, as its findings are relevant to industries beyond DFS that offer gray market products and seek to fight categorical labels until there is a reclassification event.</p>","PeriodicalId":54186,"journal":{"name":"American Business Law Journal","volume":"57 1","pages":"113-167"},"PeriodicalIF":1.2,"publicationDate":"2020-03-18","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1111/ablj.12156","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"71965300","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 7
Can Common Business Practices Ever Be Anticompetitive? Redefining Monopolization 常见的商业行为会具有反竞争性吗?重新定义垄断
IF 1.2 3区 社会学 Q3 BUSINESS Pub Date : 2020-03-18 DOI: 10.1111/ablj.12157
Konstantinos Stylianou

For most of its modern history, antitrust law distinguished between normal competition and monopolization by looking for merit, legitimate business justifications, or efficiencies in the challenged business conduct. These proxies were seen as appropriate because they served antitrust law's welfare objectives well. However, the universal adoption of these proxies has overshadowed significant shortcomings, chief among them being that firms do not think in terms of legitimate business justifications or efficiencies, but rather in terms of long-term sustainability and appropriation of value. As a result, antitrust law becomes detached from the very subjects it purports to regulate. Against the backdrop of the recent resurgence of enforcement activity, particularly involving tech giants, this article attempts a conceptualization of monopolization that does not revolve around merit in any form or function. Instead it introduces the proxy of commonness of business practices to determine their legality. This helps highlight the importance of considering “how things are done” in the relevant market, and helps reground antitrust law in business realities, which can enhance the heuristic mechanism of distinguishing between normal and anticompetitive practices. To prove this point the article develops an error test framework, through which it compares current tests with the proposed test in terms of their error footprint and concludes that the integration of the commonness parameter delivers better results. Ultimately, the inquiry undertaken herein is not only about constructing a conception of normal competition different from the only standard we currently have, that is, variants of merit, but also about shifting the conversation from how to fine-tune existing standards to how to capture a more complete conception of competition.

在其现代历史的大部分时间里,反垄断法通过在被质疑的商业行为中寻找优点、合法的商业理由或效率来区分正常竞争和垄断。这些代理人被认为是合适的,因为它们很好地服务于反垄断法的福利目标。然而,这些代理的普遍采用掩盖了重大缺陷,其中最主要的缺陷是,公司没有从合法的商业理由或效率角度进行思考,而是从长期可持续性和价值分配角度进行思考。因此,反垄断法脱离了它声称要监管的主体。在最近执法活动死灰复燃的背景下,特别是涉及科技巨头的执法活动,本文试图将垄断概念化,而不是围绕任何形式或功能的优点。相反,它引入了商业惯例共性的代理来确定其合法性。这有助于强调在相关市场中考虑“如何做事”的重要性,并有助于在商业现实中重新审视反垄断法,这可以增强区分正常做法和反竞争做法的启发式机制。为了证明这一点,本文开发了一个错误测试框架,通过该框架,将当前测试与拟议测试的错误足迹进行了比较,并得出结论,通用性参数的集成提供了更好的结果。最终,本文所进行的调查不仅是为了构建一个不同于我们目前唯一标准的正常竞争概念,即优点的变体,而且是为了将对话从如何微调现有标准转移到如何获取更完整的竞争概念。
{"title":"Can Common Business Practices Ever Be Anticompetitive? Redefining Monopolization","authors":"Konstantinos Stylianou","doi":"10.1111/ablj.12157","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1111/ablj.12157","url":null,"abstract":"<p>For most of its modern history, antitrust law distinguished between normal competition and monopolization by looking for merit, legitimate business justifications, or efficiencies in the challenged business conduct. These proxies were seen as appropriate because they served antitrust law's welfare objectives well. However, the universal adoption of these proxies has overshadowed significant shortcomings, chief among them being that firms do not think in terms of legitimate business justifications or efficiencies, but rather in terms of long-term sustainability and appropriation of value. As a result, antitrust law becomes detached from the very subjects it purports to regulate. Against the backdrop of the recent resurgence of enforcement activity, particularly involving tech giants, this article attempts a conceptualization of monopolization that does not revolve around merit in any form or function. Instead it introduces the proxy of commonness of business practices to determine their legality. This helps highlight the importance of considering “how things are done” in the relevant market, and helps reground antitrust law in business realities, which can enhance the heuristic mechanism of distinguishing between normal and anticompetitive practices. To prove this point the article develops an error test framework, through which it compares current tests with the proposed test in terms of their error footprint and concludes that the integration of the commonness parameter delivers better results. Ultimately, the inquiry undertaken herein is not only about constructing a conception of normal competition different from the only standard we currently have, that is, variants of merit, but also about shifting the conversation from how to fine-tune existing standards to how to capture a more complete conception of competition.</p>","PeriodicalId":54186,"journal":{"name":"American Business Law Journal","volume":"57 1","pages":"169-221"},"PeriodicalIF":1.2,"publicationDate":"2020-03-18","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1111/ablj.12157","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"71965299","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Trade Secrecy Injunctions, Disclosure Risks, and eBay's Influence 商业秘密禁令、披露风险和eBay的影响
IF 1.2 3区 社会学 Q3 BUSINESS Pub Date : 2019-11-21 DOI: 10.1111/ablj.12153
Deepa Varadarajan

Historically, intellectual property (IP) owners could rely on injunctive remedies to prevent continued infringement. The Supreme Court's eBay v. MercExchange decision changed this, however. After eBay, patent courts no longer apply presumptions that push the deliberative scales in favor of injunctions (or “property rule” protection). Instead, patent injunctions require a careful four-factor analysis, where plaintiffs must demonstrate irreparable injury (i.e., that money damages cannot compensate). Without question, eBay has made it harder for patent plaintiffs to secure injunctions, and has led many district courts to consider innovation policy concerns (e.g., the strategic behavior of patent “troll” plaintiffs) in the injunction calculus. By and large, courts’ more deliberative approach to patent injunctions post-eBay has been viewed as beneficial for the patent system.

Over the past decade, eBay’s influence has migrated to other areas of IP. This article offers the first account of eBay’s impact on federal trade secrecy injunctions. Important differences between trade secret law and other areas of IP—for example, the hard-to-quantify risk that disclosure poses to trade secret owners—has lessened eBay’s influence on trade secrecy injunctions. This article argues that disclosure risks justify a bifurcated approach to trade secrecy injunctions. That is, in cases involving the dissemination of trade secrets, courts should presume irreparable injury in the injunction calculus. However, in cases involving the unauthorized use of a trade secret—that is, where a defendant builds upon a plaintiff's trade secret but does not disseminate it—courts should not presume irreparable harm and, instead, should apply the eBay framework. As part of this assessment, courts should consider policy concerns related to cumulative innovation and employee mobility.

从历史上看,知识产权所有者可以依靠禁令救济来防止继续侵权。然而,最高法院对eBay诉MercExchange案的裁决改变了这一点。在eBay之后,专利法院不再适用那些将审议尺度推向禁令(或“财产规则”保护)的假设。相反,专利禁令需要仔细的四因素分析,原告必须证明不可弥补的伤害(即金钱损害不能补偿)。毫无疑问,eBay使专利原告更难获得禁令,并导致许多地方法院在禁令计算中考虑创新政策问题(例如,专利“巨魔”原告的战略行为)。总的来说,法院对后ebay时代的专利禁令采取更为审慎的态度,被视为有利于专利制度。在过去的十年里,eBay的影响力已经转移到其他知识产权领域。本文首次介绍了eBay对联邦商业保密禁令的影响。商业秘密法与其他知识产权领域的重要区别——例如,披露商业秘密给商业秘密所有者带来的难以量化的风险——削弱了eBay对商业秘密禁令的影响。本文认为,披露风险证明了商业秘密禁令的两面性。也就是说,在涉及商业秘密传播的案件中,法院应该在禁令计算中假定不可弥补的损害。然而,在涉及未经授权使用商业秘密的案件中——也就是说,被告以原告的商业秘密为基础,但没有传播它——法院不应假定不可弥补的损害,而应适用eBay框架。作为评估的一部分,法院应考虑与累积创新和员工流动性相关的政策问题。
{"title":"Trade Secrecy Injunctions, Disclosure Risks, and eBay's Influence","authors":"Deepa Varadarajan","doi":"10.1111/ablj.12153","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1111/ablj.12153","url":null,"abstract":"<p>Historically, intellectual property (IP) owners could rely on injunctive remedies to prevent continued infringement. The Supreme Court's <i>eBay v. MercExchange</i> decision changed this, however. After <i>eBay</i>, patent courts no longer apply presumptions that push the deliberative scales in favor of injunctions (or “property rule” protection). Instead, patent injunctions require a careful four-factor analysis, where plaintiffs must demonstrate irreparable injury (i.e., that money damages cannot compensate). Without question, <i>eBay</i> has made it harder for patent plaintiffs to secure injunctions, and has led many district courts to consider innovation policy concerns (e.g., the strategic behavior of patent “troll” plaintiffs) in the injunction calculus. By and large, courts’ more deliberative approach to patent injunctions post-<i>eBay</i> has been viewed as beneficial for the patent system.</p><p>Over the past decade, <i>eBay</i>’s influence has migrated to other areas of IP. This article offers the first account of <i>eBay</i>’s impact on federal trade secrecy injunctions. Important differences between trade secret law and other areas of IP—for example, the hard-to-quantify risk that disclosure poses to trade secret owners—has lessened <i>eBay</i>’s influence on trade secrecy injunctions. This article argues that disclosure risks justify a bifurcated approach to trade secrecy injunctions. That is, in cases involving the dissemination of trade secrets, courts should presume irreparable injury in the injunction calculus. However, in cases involving the unauthorized use of a trade secret—that is, where a defendant builds upon a plaintiff's trade secret but does not disseminate it—courts should not presume irreparable harm and, instead, should apply the <i>eBay</i> framework. As part of this assessment, courts should consider policy concerns related to cumulative innovation and employee mobility.</p>","PeriodicalId":54186,"journal":{"name":"American Business Law Journal","volume":"56 4","pages":"879-925"},"PeriodicalIF":1.2,"publicationDate":"2019-11-21","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1111/ablj.12153","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"91857397","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Bribing the Machine: Protecting the Integrity of Algorithms as the Revolution Begins 贿赂机器:在革命开始时保护算法的完整性
IF 1.2 3区 社会学 Q3 BUSINESS Pub Date : 2019-11-21 DOI: 10.1111/ablj.12151
Philip M. Nichols

In the Industrial Revolution, machines took on the burden of physical labor; in the Big Data Revolution, machines are taking on the tasks of making decisions. Algorithms are the rules and processes that enable machines to make those decisions. Machines will make many decisions that affect general well-being. This article addresses a threat to the efficacy of those decisions: the intentional distortion or manipulation of the underlying algorithm so that machines make decisions that benefit self-interested third parties, rather than decisions that enhance public well-being. That threat has not been recognized or addressed by legal thinkers or policy makers. This article first examines the lifecycle of an algorithm, and then demonstrates the likelihood that self-interested third parties will attempt to corrupt the development and operation of algorithms. The article then argues that existing mechanisms cannot protect the integrity of algorithms. The article concludes with a discussion of policies that could protect the integrity of algorithms: transparency in both the development of and the content of algorithms that affect general well-being and holding persons who corrupt the integrity of such algorithms accountable. Just as the Industrial Revolution eventually improved the quality of life for many, so too does the Big Data Revolution offer enhancement of general well-being. That promise, however, will only be realized if policy makers take action to protect the integrity of underlying algorithms now, at the beginning of the revolution.

在工业革命中,机器承担了体力劳动的负担;在大数据革命中,机器正在承担决策的任务。算法是使机器能够做出这些决定的规则和过程。机器将做出许多影响整体福祉的决定。本文解决了对这些决策有效性的威胁:故意扭曲或操纵底层算法,以便机器做出有利于自利第三方的决策,而不是提高公共福祉的决策。法律思想家或政策制定者没有认识到或解决这一威胁。本文首先考察了算法的生命周期,然后演示了自利的第三方试图破坏算法的开发和操作的可能性。然后,文章认为现有机制不能保护算法的完整性。文章最后讨论了可以保护算法完整性的政策:影响一般福祉的算法的开发和内容的透明度,以及追究破坏此类算法完整性的人的责任。正如工业革命最终改善了许多人的生活质量一样,大数据革命也提高了人们的总体幸福感。然而,只有政策制定者在革命之初就采取行动保护底层算法的完整性,这一承诺才能实现。
{"title":"Bribing the Machine: Protecting the Integrity of Algorithms as the Revolution Begins","authors":"Philip M. Nichols","doi":"10.1111/ablj.12151","DOIUrl":"10.1111/ablj.12151","url":null,"abstract":"<p>In the Industrial Revolution, machines took on the burden of physical labor; in the Big Data Revolution, machines are taking on the tasks of making decisions. Algorithms are the rules and processes that enable machines to make those decisions. Machines will make many decisions that affect general well-being. This article addresses a threat to the efficacy of those decisions: the intentional distortion or manipulation of the underlying algorithm so that machines make decisions that benefit self-interested third parties, rather than decisions that enhance public well-being. That threat has not been recognized or addressed by legal thinkers or policy makers. This article first examines the lifecycle of an algorithm, and then demonstrates the likelihood that self-interested third parties will attempt to corrupt the development and operation of algorithms. The article then argues that existing mechanisms cannot protect the integrity of algorithms. The article concludes with a discussion of policies that could protect the integrity of algorithms: transparency in both the development of and the content of algorithms that affect general well-being and holding persons who corrupt the integrity of such algorithms accountable. Just as the Industrial Revolution eventually improved the quality of life for many, so too does the Big Data Revolution offer enhancement of general well-being. That promise, however, will only be realized if policy makers take action to protect the integrity of underlying algorithms now, at the beginning of the revolution.</p>","PeriodicalId":54186,"journal":{"name":"American Business Law Journal","volume":"56 4","pages":"771-814"},"PeriodicalIF":1.2,"publicationDate":"2019-11-21","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1111/ablj.12151","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"44894906","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 5
How Behavioral Science Ultimately Fails Retirement Savers: A Noble Experiment 行为科学最终如何让退休储蓄者失败:一个高尚的实验
IF 1.2 3区 社会学 Q3 BUSINESS Pub Date : 2019-11-21 DOI: 10.1111/ablj.12150
Dana M. Muir

Behavioral scientists boast that their insights have increased savings in 401(k) plans. Evidence shows that careful use of default decision settings and nudges can prevent decisional errors and encourage behavior that aligns with public policy while retaining individual power of choice. Indeed, even the Swedish National Academy of Sciences highlighted the effect of his behavioral science work on retirement savings when it awarded the 2017 Nobel Prize in economics to Professor Richard Thaler. This article shows, though, that, unlike the three plan default settings attributed to behavioral science insights, the default setting that I term automatic retention fails. That failure means too many savers take affirmative actions to move (rollover) assets from their 401(k) plans to individual retirement accounts (IRAs). Primarily because of rollovers, IRAs hold more than 11.5% of U.S. household financial assets. However, usually the decision to roll over is not an optimal choice for the saver. This last mile problem undermines the goal of the first three default settings to help employees build long-term retirement savings. This article examines research on what causes default settings to be slippery, as is the case for automatic retention, instead of sticky, as is the case for the other 401(k) default settings. It then evaluates three categories of potential interventions to mitigate the popularity of rollovers: aggressive regulation, expansion of fiduciary obligation, and use of incremental impeding altering rules. It concludes that adoption of incremental impeding altering rules would be both politically feasible and effective in increasing the stickiness of the automatic retention default setting.

行为科学家夸口说,他们的见解增加了401(k)计划的储蓄。有证据表明,谨慎使用默认决策设置和推动可以防止决策错误,并鼓励与公共政策一致的行为,同时保留个人的选择权。事实上,就连瑞典国家科学院(Swedish National Academy of Sciences)在将2017年诺贝尔经济学奖授予理查德·塞勒(Richard Thaler)教授时,也强调了他的行为科学研究对退休储蓄的影响。然而,本文表明,与归因于行为科学见解的三个计划默认设置不同,我称之为自动保留的默认设置失败了。这种失败意味着太多的储蓄者采取积极行动,将资产从401(k)计划转移到个人退休账户(ira)。ira持有超过11.5%的美国家庭金融资产,这主要是由于资产展期。然而,对于储蓄者来说,通常转款并不是最佳选择。最后一英里的问题破坏了前三个默认设置的目标,即帮助员工建立长期退休储蓄。本文考察了导致默认设置不稳定的原因,即自动保留的情况,而不是像其他401(k)默认设置那样具有粘性的情况。然后,它评估了三类潜在的干预措施,以减轻滚转的普及:积极监管,扩大信托义务,并使用增量阻碍改变规则。它的结论是,采用渐进式阻碍改变规则在政治上是可行的,并且在增加自动保留默认设置的粘性方面是有效的。
{"title":"How Behavioral Science Ultimately Fails Retirement Savers: A Noble Experiment","authors":"Dana M. Muir","doi":"10.1111/ablj.12150","DOIUrl":"10.1111/ablj.12150","url":null,"abstract":"<p>Behavioral scientists boast that their insights have increased savings in 401(k) plans. Evidence shows that careful use of default decision settings and nudges can prevent decisional errors and encourage behavior that aligns with public policy while retaining individual power of choice. Indeed, even the Swedish National Academy of Sciences highlighted the effect of his behavioral science work on retirement savings when it awarded the 2017 Nobel Prize in economics to Professor Richard Thaler. This article shows, though, that, unlike the three plan default settings attributed to behavioral science insights, the default setting that I term automatic retention fails. That failure means too many savers take affirmative actions to move (rollover) assets from their 401(k) plans to individual retirement accounts (IRAs). Primarily because of rollovers, IRAs hold more than 11.5% of U.S. household financial assets. However, usually the decision to roll over is not an optimal choice for the saver. This last mile problem undermines the goal of the first three default settings to help employees build long-term retirement savings. This article examines research on what causes default settings to be slippery, as is the case for automatic retention, instead of sticky, as is the case for the other 401(k) default settings. It then evaluates three categories of potential interventions to mitigate the popularity of rollovers: aggressive regulation, expansion of fiduciary obligation, and use of incremental impeding altering rules. It concludes that adoption of incremental impeding altering rules would be both politically feasible and effective in increasing the stickiness of the automatic retention default setting.</p>","PeriodicalId":54186,"journal":{"name":"American Business Law Journal","volume":"56 4","pages":"707-770"},"PeriodicalIF":1.2,"publicationDate":"2019-11-21","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1111/ablj.12150","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"43981920","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
期刊
American Business Law Journal
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1