首页 > 最新文献

Comparative labor law journal : a publication of the U.S. National Branch of the International Society for Labor Law and Social Security [and] the Wharton School, and the Law School of the University of Pennsylvania最新文献

英文 中文
Safety Transformation and the Structure of the Financial System 安全转型与金融体系结构
W. Diamond
This paper studies how a financial system that is organized to efficiently create safe assets responds to macroeconomic shocks. Financial intermediaries face a cost of bearing risk, so they choose the least risky portfolio that backs their issuance of riskless deposits: a diversified pool of nonfinancial firms' debt. Nonfinancial firms choose their capital structure to exploit the resulting segmentation between debt and equity markets. Increased safe asset demand yields larger and riskier intermediaries and more levered firms. Quantitative easing reduces the size and riskiness of intermediaries and can decrease firm leverage, despite reducing borrowing costs at the zero lower bound.
本文研究了一个旨在有效创造安全资产的金融体系如何应对宏观经济冲击。金融中介机构面临承担风险的成本,因此他们选择风险最低的投资组合来支持他们发行无风险存款:非金融公司债务的多元化池。非金融公司选择他们的资本结构来利用债务和股票市场之间的分割。安全资产需求的增加催生了规模更大、风险更高的中介机构和杠杆率更高的公司。量化宽松减少了中介机构的规模和风险,可以降低企业杠杆率,尽管将借贷成本降至零下限。
{"title":"Safety Transformation and the Structure of the Financial System","authors":"W. Diamond","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3219332","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3219332","url":null,"abstract":"This paper studies how a financial system that is organized to efficiently create safe assets responds to macroeconomic shocks. Financial intermediaries face a cost of bearing risk, so they choose the least risky portfolio that backs their issuance of riskless deposits: a diversified pool of nonfinancial firms' debt. Nonfinancial firms choose their capital structure to exploit the resulting segmentation between debt and equity markets. Increased safe asset demand yields larger and riskier intermediaries and more levered firms. Quantitative easing reduces the size and riskiness of intermediaries and can decrease firm leverage, despite reducing borrowing costs at the zero lower bound.","PeriodicalId":80976,"journal":{"name":"Comparative labor law journal : a publication of the U.S. National Branch of the International Society for Labor Law and Social Security [and] the Wharton School, and the Law School of the University of Pennsylvania","volume":"22 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2019-04-06","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"82789444","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 46
Keeping Options Open: What Motivates Entrepreneurs? 保持开放的选择:是什么激励着企业家?
S. Catherine
Using French administrative data on job-creating entrepreneurs, I estimate a life-cycle model in which risk-averse individuals can start businesses and return to paid employment. I estimate that the unobserved benefits of entrepreneurship represent 6,100 pre-tax euros per year (some 15% of profits), which adds up to 67,000 euros over the average entrepreneurial spell. For new entrepreneurs, the option of returning to paid employment is worth 82,000 euros. The main source of option value is not the unobserved heterogeneity in entrepreneurial abilities but rather the random-walk component of productivity. Together, unobserved benefits and this option value explain 42% of firm creations.
利用法国关于创造就业的企业家的行政数据,我估计了一个生命周期模型,在这个模型中,厌恶风险的个人可以创业并重返有偿就业。我估计,创业带来的未被观察到的收益相当于每年税前6100欧元(约占利润的15%),平均而言,创业期的收益总计为67000欧元。对于新企业家来说,重返带薪工作的选择价值8.2万欧元。期权价值的主要来源不是创业能力的未观察到的异质性,而是生产率的随机游走成分。未观察到的利益和期权价值共同解释了42%的公司创建。
{"title":"Keeping Options Open: What Motivates Entrepreneurs?","authors":"S. Catherine","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3274879","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3274879","url":null,"abstract":"Using French administrative data on job-creating entrepreneurs, I estimate a life-cycle model in which risk-averse individuals can start businesses and return to paid employment. I estimate that the unobserved benefits of entrepreneurship represent 6,100 pre-tax euros per year (some 15% of profits), which adds up to 67,000 euros over the average entrepreneurial spell. For new entrepreneurs, the option of returning to paid employment is worth 82,000 euros. The main source of option value is not the unobserved heterogeneity in entrepreneurial abilities but rather the random-walk component of productivity. Together, unobserved benefits and this option value explain 42% of firm creations.","PeriodicalId":80976,"journal":{"name":"Comparative labor law journal : a publication of the U.S. National Branch of the International Society for Labor Law and Social Security [and] the Wharton School, and the Law School of the University of Pennsylvania","volume":"16 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2019-02-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"86710841","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 14
Whatever Did Happen to the Antitrust Movement? 反垄断运动到底发生了什么?
Herbert Hovenkamp
Antitrust in the United States today is caught between its pursuit of technical rules designed to define and implement defensible economic goals, and increasing calls for a new antitrust “movement.” The goals of this movement have been variously defined as combating industrial concentration, limiting the economic or political power of large firms, correcting the maldistribution of wealth, control of high profits, increasing wages, or protection of small business. High output and low consumer prices are typically unmentioned. In the 1960s the great policy historian Richard Hofstadter lamented the passing of the antitrust “movement” as one of the “faded passions of American reform.” In its early history, he observed, antitrust had a powerful movement quality but very little success in the courts. Later, it ceased to be a movement just as it was attaining litigation success. As a movement, antitrust often succeeds at capturing political attention, but it fails at making effective – or even coherent – policy. The coherence problem shows up in goals that are both unmeasurable and fundamentally inconsistent, but with their contradictions rarely exposed. Among the most problematic contradictions is the one between small business protection and consumer welfare. Consumers benefit from low prices, high output and high quality and variety of products and services. But when a firm is able to offer these things it invariably injures rivals -- typically smaller firms or those dedicated to older technologies. Although movement antitrust rhetoric is often opaque about specifics, its general effect is invariably to encourage higher prices or reduced output or innovation, mainly for the protection of small business or firms dedicated to older technologies. Indeed, some spokespersons for movement antitrust write as if low prices are the evil that antitrust law should be combating. This piece sets out to do three things. First it describes so-called “movement” antitrust, focusing on recent writings disparaging consumer welfare in favor of alternatives that seek to protect small business welfare, redistribute wealth, or pursue other goals. Then it describes the fundamental contours of technical antitrust, whose stated goal is the protection of high output and low prices, and explains why this approach is much more consistent with concerns about economic rationality, due process, administrability, and federalism. Finally, it examines several areas where technical antitrust rules could be improved, focusing mainly on merger policy and one particularly problematic area, which is antitrust’s historical failure to deal adequately with monopsony power in labor markets.
今天,美国的反垄断陷入了两难境地,一方面是追求旨在定义和实施可辩护的经济目标的技术规则,另一方面是越来越多地呼吁开展新的反垄断“运动”。这一运动的目标被不同地定义为反对产业集中,限制大公司的经济或政治权力,纠正财富分配不均,控制高利润,增加工资或保护小企业。高产出和低消费价格通常没有被提及。20世纪60年代,伟大的政策历史学家理查德·霍夫施塔特(Richard Hofstadter)曾哀叹,反垄断“运动”的消逝是“美国改革中逐渐消退的激情”之一。他观察到,在反垄断的早期历史中,反垄断具有强大的运动性质,但在法庭上却很少取得成功。后来,就在它获得诉讼成功的时候,它不再是一场运动。作为一项运动,反垄断常常能成功地吸引政治关注,但却无法制定有效的——甚至是连贯的——政策。一致性问题出现在那些既无法衡量又根本不一致的目标中,但它们之间的矛盾很少暴露出来。其中最有问题的矛盾是小企业保护和消费者福利之间的矛盾。消费者受益于低价格、高产量、高质量和多样化的产品和服务。但是,当一家公司能够提供这些东西时,它总是会伤害竞争对手——通常是较小的公司或那些致力于老技术的公司。尽管反垄断运动的修辞往往不清楚具体细节,但其总体效果总是鼓励更高的价格或减少产出或创新,主要是为了保护小企业或致力于老技术的公司。事实上,反垄断运动的一些发言人写道,似乎低价是反垄断法应该打击的邪恶。这篇文章打算做三件事。首先,它描述了所谓的“运动”反垄断,重点关注最近的文章贬低消费者福利,支持寻求保护小企业福利,重新分配财富或追求其他目标的替代方案。然后,它描述了技术性反垄断的基本轮廓,其既定目标是保护高产量和低价格,并解释了为什么这种方法更符合对经济合理性、正当程序、可管理性和联邦制的关注。最后,它考察了技术反垄断规则可以改进的几个领域,主要集中在合并政策和一个特别有问题的领域,即反垄断在劳动力市场中充分处理垄断力量的历史失败。
{"title":"Whatever Did Happen to the Antitrust Movement?","authors":"Herbert Hovenkamp","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3097452","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3097452","url":null,"abstract":"Antitrust in the United States today is caught between its pursuit of technical rules designed to define and implement defensible economic goals, and increasing calls for a new antitrust “movement.” The goals of this movement have been variously defined as combating industrial concentration, limiting the economic or political power of large firms, correcting the maldistribution of wealth, control of high profits, increasing wages, or protection of small business. High output and low consumer prices are typically unmentioned. \u0000 \u0000In the 1960s the great policy historian Richard Hofstadter lamented the passing of the antitrust “movement” as one of the “faded passions of American reform.” In its early history, he observed, antitrust had a powerful movement quality but very little success in the courts. Later, it ceased to be a movement just as it was attaining litigation success. As a movement, antitrust often succeeds at capturing political attention, but it fails at making effective – or even coherent – policy. The coherence problem shows up in goals that are both unmeasurable and fundamentally inconsistent, but with their contradictions rarely exposed. Among the most problematic contradictions is the one between small business protection and consumer welfare. Consumers benefit from low prices, high output and high quality and variety of products and services. But when a firm is able to offer these things it invariably injures rivals -- typically smaller firms or those dedicated to older technologies. Although movement antitrust rhetoric is often opaque about specifics, its general effect is invariably to encourage higher prices or reduced output or innovation, mainly for the protection of small business or firms dedicated to older technologies. Indeed, some spokespersons for movement antitrust write as if low prices are the evil that antitrust law should be combating. \u0000 \u0000This piece sets out to do three things. First it describes so-called “movement” antitrust, focusing on recent writings disparaging consumer welfare in favor of alternatives that seek to protect small business welfare, redistribute wealth, or pursue other goals. Then it describes the fundamental contours of technical antitrust, whose stated goal is the protection of high output and low prices, and explains why this approach is much more consistent with concerns about economic rationality, due process, administrability, and federalism. Finally, it examines several areas where technical antitrust rules could be improved, focusing mainly on merger policy and one particularly problematic area, which is antitrust’s historical failure to deal adequately with monopsony power in labor markets.","PeriodicalId":80976,"journal":{"name":"Comparative labor law journal : a publication of the U.S. National Branch of the International Society for Labor Law and Social Security [and] the Wharton School, and the Law School of the University of Pennsylvania","volume":"4 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2018-12-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"75307531","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 23
The Impact of Behavioral and Economic Drivers on Gig Economy Workers 行为和经济驱动因素对零工经济工作者的影响
Gad Allon, Maxime C. Cohen, W. Sinchaisri
Problem definition: Gig economy companies benefit from labor flexibility by hiring independent workers in response to real-time demand. However, workers’ flexibility in their work schedule poses a great challenge in terms of planning and committing to a service capacity. Understanding what motivates gig economy workers is thus of great importance. In collaboration with a ride-hailing platform, we study how on-demand workers make labor decisions; specifically, whether to work and work duration. Our model revisits competing theories of labor supply regarding the impact of financial incentives and behavioral motives on labor decisions. We are interested in both improving how to predict the behavior of flexible workers and understanding how to design better incentives. Methodology/results: Using a large comprehensive data set, we develop an econometric model to analyze workers’ labor decisions and responses to incentives while accounting for sample selection and endogeneity. We find that financial incentives have a significant positive influence on the decision to work and on the work duration—confirming the positive income elasticity posited by the standard income effect. We also find support for a behavioral theory as workers exhibit income-targeting behavior (working less when reaching an income goal) and inertia (working more after working for a longer period). Managerial implications: We demonstrate via numerical experiments that incentive optimization based on our insights can increase service capacity by 22% without incurring additional cost, or maintain the same capacity at a 30% lower cost. Ignoring behavioral factors could lead to understaffing by 10%–17% below the optimal capacity level. Lastly, our insights inform the design of platform strategy to manage flexible workers amidst an intensified competition among gig platforms. Funding: This study was supported by The Jay H. Baker Retailing Center, The William and Phyllis Mack Institute for Innovation Management, The Wharton Risk Management and Decision Processes Center, and The Fishman-Davidson Center for Service and Operations Management. Supplemental Material: The online appendices are available at https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2023.1191 .
问题定义:零工经济公司通过雇佣独立员工来应对实时需求,从而受益于劳动力灵活性。然而,员工在工作时间表上的灵活性在规划和承诺服务能力方面构成了巨大的挑战。因此,了解零工经济工作者的动机非常重要。我们与一个叫车平台合作,研究按需员工如何做出劳动决策;具体来说就是是否工作和工作时长。我们的模型回顾了关于经济激励和行为动机对劳动力决策影响的劳动力供给竞争理论。我们感兴趣的是改进如何预测灵活员工的行为,以及了解如何设计更好的激励措施。方法/结果:使用大型综合数据集,我们开发了一个计量经济学模型来分析工人的劳动决策和对激励的反应,同时考虑样本选择和内生性。我们发现,财政激励对工作决策和工作持续时间有显著的正向影响——证实了标准收入效应所假设的正收入弹性。我们还发现了行为理论的支持,因为工人表现出收入目标行为(达到收入目标后工作更少)和惯性(工作更长时间后工作更多)。管理意义:我们通过数值实验证明,基于我们的见解的激励优化可以在不产生额外成本的情况下将服务容量增加22%,或者以降低30%的成本保持相同的容量。忽略行为因素可能导致比最佳能力水平低10%-17%的人员不足。最后,我们的见解为在零工平台之间激烈竞争中管理灵活员工的平台策略设计提供了信息。资助:本研究由杰伊·h·贝克零售中心、威廉和菲利斯·麦克创新管理研究所、沃顿风险管理和决策过程中心以及菲什曼-戴维森服务和运营管理中心支持。补充材料:在线附录可在https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2023.1191上获得。
{"title":"The Impact of Behavioral and Economic Drivers on Gig Economy Workers","authors":"Gad Allon, Maxime C. Cohen, W. Sinchaisri","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3274628","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3274628","url":null,"abstract":"Problem definition: Gig economy companies benefit from labor flexibility by hiring independent workers in response to real-time demand. However, workers’ flexibility in their work schedule poses a great challenge in terms of planning and committing to a service capacity. Understanding what motivates gig economy workers is thus of great importance. In collaboration with a ride-hailing platform, we study how on-demand workers make labor decisions; specifically, whether to work and work duration. Our model revisits competing theories of labor supply regarding the impact of financial incentives and behavioral motives on labor decisions. We are interested in both improving how to predict the behavior of flexible workers and understanding how to design better incentives. Methodology/results: Using a large comprehensive data set, we develop an econometric model to analyze workers’ labor decisions and responses to incentives while accounting for sample selection and endogeneity. We find that financial incentives have a significant positive influence on the decision to work and on the work duration—confirming the positive income elasticity posited by the standard income effect. We also find support for a behavioral theory as workers exhibit income-targeting behavior (working less when reaching an income goal) and inertia (working more after working for a longer period). Managerial implications: We demonstrate via numerical experiments that incentive optimization based on our insights can increase service capacity by 22% without incurring additional cost, or maintain the same capacity at a 30% lower cost. Ignoring behavioral factors could lead to understaffing by 10%–17% below the optimal capacity level. Lastly, our insights inform the design of platform strategy to manage flexible workers amidst an intensified competition among gig platforms. Funding: This study was supported by The Jay H. Baker Retailing Center, The William and Phyllis Mack Institute for Innovation Management, The Wharton Risk Management and Decision Processes Center, and The Fishman-Davidson Center for Service and Operations Management. Supplemental Material: The online appendices are available at https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2023.1191 .","PeriodicalId":80976,"journal":{"name":"Comparative labor law journal : a publication of the U.S. National Branch of the International Society for Labor Law and Social Security [and] the Wharton School, and the Law School of the University of Pennsylvania","volume":"31 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2018-10-29","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"86739464","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 47
Performance Evaluation with Latent Factors 基于潜在因素的绩效评价
Yang Song, Qingyuan Zhao
It is common to evaluate mutual fund (and in general, security) returns by linear factor models. However, performance measures from these models are misleading if there are some omitted factors that explain cross-sectional variation in returns. We propose to use a latent-factor approach, Confounder Adjusted Testing and Estimation (CATE), for performance evaluation. Under reasonable economic assumptions, we show that CATE can consistently separate "alpha" from the return components that are due to common factor exposures, without forcing any particular ex-ante specification of the factors. We demonstrate that CATE outperforms widely used factor models in identifying common variation in mutual fund returns and that CATE alpha positively predicts future fund performance. When ranked by the difference between CATE alpha and CAPM alpha, the most favorable measure used by mutual fund investors, we find that the top decile of funds outperforms the bottom decile by as large as 5% per year. We also find that mutual fund flows become less responsive to returns due to the size, value, and momentum factors over time, yet respond persistently to other factor-related variation.
通过线性因子模型来评估共同基金(以及一般的证券)的回报是很常见的。然而,如果有一些遗漏的因素来解释收益的横截面变化,这些模型的绩效衡量就会产生误导。我们建议使用潜在因素方法,混杂因素调整测试和估计(CATE),进行性能评估。在合理的经济假设下,我们表明CATE可以始终如一地将“alpha”从由于共同因素暴露的回报成分中分离出来,而无需强制对因素进行任何特定的事前说明。我们证明,在识别共同基金收益的共同变化方面,CATE优于广泛使用的因子模型,并且CATE alpha积极预测未来基金的表现。当根据CATE alpha和CAPM alpha(共同基金投资者使用的最有利的衡量标准)之间的差异进行排名时,我们发现,排名前十分之一的基金每年的表现比排名后十分之一的基金高出5%。我们还发现,随着时间的推移,由于规模、价值和动量因素的影响,共同基金流量对回报的反应越来越弱,但对其他因素相关的变化却持续做出反应。
{"title":"Performance Evaluation with Latent Factors","authors":"Yang Song, Qingyuan Zhao","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3216272","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3216272","url":null,"abstract":"It is common to evaluate mutual fund (and in general, security) returns by linear factor models. However, performance measures from these models are misleading if there are some omitted factors that explain cross-sectional variation in returns. We propose to use a latent-factor approach, Confounder Adjusted Testing and Estimation (CATE), for performance evaluation. Under reasonable economic assumptions, we show that CATE can consistently separate \"alpha\" from the return components that are due to common factor exposures, without forcing any particular ex-ante specification of the factors. We demonstrate that CATE outperforms widely used factor models in identifying common variation in mutual fund returns and that CATE alpha positively predicts future fund performance. When ranked by the difference between CATE alpha and CAPM alpha, the most favorable measure used by mutual fund investors, we find that the top decile of funds outperforms the bottom decile by as large as 5% per year. We also find that mutual fund flows become less responsive to returns due to the size, value, and momentum factors over time, yet respond persistently to other factor-related variation.","PeriodicalId":80976,"journal":{"name":"Comparative labor law journal : a publication of the U.S. National Branch of the International Society for Labor Law and Social Security [and] the Wharton School, and the Law School of the University of Pennsylvania","volume":"11 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2018-07-18","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"73277708","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 6
Financial Reporting Quality, Investment Horizon, and Institutional Investor Trading Strategies 财务报告质量、投资视野和机构投资者交易策略
Brian J. Bushee, Theodore H. Goodman, S. Sunder
This paper provides evidence that financial reporting quality (FRQ) influences the holding costs of trading strategies. While prior research has focused on the benefits of investment strategies based on poor FRQ (i.e., larger returns due to a greater amount of private information), we examine whether poor FRQ imposes greater holding costs on certain trading strategies. We show that poor FRQ motivates sophisticated investors with short-term horizons to tilt their portfolios away from value stocks, whose returns are contingent on investors revising their beliefs about firm fundamental value, and toward past winner stocks, whose future returns are realized more quickly. Poor FRQ also increases the length of time that institutions maintain large positions in value stocks. Our results imply that mis-valuations can be persistent when arbitrageurs perceive high holding costs from poor financial quality, even when they can see through the opaque financial disclosures.
本文提供了财务报告质量(FRQ)影响交易策略持有成本的证据。虽然之前的研究集中在基于低FRQ的投资策略的好处上(即,由于更多的私人信息而获得更大的回报),但我们研究了低FRQ是否会给某些交易策略带来更高的持有成本。我们的研究表明,糟糕的FRQ会促使短线眼光的老练投资者将投资组合从价值型股票中倾斜出来,价值型股票的回报取决于投资者对坚定基本价值的信念的修正,而过去的赢家股票,其未来回报实现得更快。糟糕的FRQ也增加了机构在价值型股票中持有大量头寸的时间长度。我们的研究结果表明,当套利者从糟糕的财务质量中感知到高持有成本时,即使他们能够看穿不透明的财务披露,错误估值也可能持续存在。
{"title":"Financial Reporting Quality, Investment Horizon, and Institutional Investor Trading Strategies","authors":"Brian J. Bushee, Theodore H. Goodman, S. Sunder","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3207369","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3207369","url":null,"abstract":"\u0000 This paper provides evidence that financial reporting quality (FRQ) influences the holding costs of trading strategies. While prior research has focused on the benefits of investment strategies based on poor FRQ (i.e., larger returns due to a greater amount of private information), we examine whether poor FRQ imposes greater holding costs on certain trading strategies. We show that poor FRQ motivates sophisticated investors with short-term horizons to tilt their portfolios away from value stocks, whose returns are contingent on investors revising their beliefs about firm fundamental value, and toward past winner stocks, whose future returns are realized more quickly. Poor FRQ also increases the length of time that institutions maintain large positions in value stocks. Our results imply that mis-valuations can be persistent when arbitrageurs perceive high holding costs from poor financial quality, even when they can see through the opaque financial disclosures.","PeriodicalId":80976,"journal":{"name":"Comparative labor law journal : a publication of the U.S. National Branch of the International Society for Labor Law and Social Security [and] the Wharton School, and the Law School of the University of Pennsylvania","volume":"42 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2018-07-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"90174784","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 14
Corporate Debt Choice and Bank Capital Regulation 企业债务选择与银行资本监管
Haotian Xiang
I investigate the impact of bank capital requirements in a business cycle model with corporate debt choice. Compared to non-bank investors, banks provide restructurable loans that reduce firm bankruptcy losses and enhance production efficiency. Raising capital requirements eliminates deposit insurance distortions but also deposit tax shields. As a result, firms cut back on both bank and non-bank borrowing while going bankrupt more frequently. Implementing an optimal capital ratio of 11 percent in the US produces limited marginal impacts on aggregate quantities and welfare.
我研究了银行资本要求在企业债务选择的商业周期模型中的影响。与非银行投资者相比,银行提供的可重组贷款减少了企业破产损失,提高了生产效率。提高资本金要求消除了存款保险的扭曲,但也消除了存款税屏障。结果,企业削减了银行和非银行贷款,同时更频繁地破产。在美国实施11%的最优资本比率对总量和福利产生有限的边际影响。
{"title":"Corporate Debt Choice and Bank Capital Regulation","authors":"Haotian Xiang","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.2882235","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2882235","url":null,"abstract":"I investigate the impact of bank capital requirements in a business cycle model with corporate debt choice. Compared to non-bank investors, banks provide restructurable loans that reduce firm bankruptcy losses and enhance production efficiency. Raising capital requirements eliminates deposit insurance distortions but also deposit tax shields. As a result, firms cut back on both bank and non-bank borrowing while going bankrupt more frequently. Implementing an optimal capital ratio of 11 percent in the US produces limited marginal impacts on aggregate quantities and welfare.","PeriodicalId":80976,"journal":{"name":"Comparative labor law journal : a publication of the U.S. National Branch of the International Society for Labor Law and Social Security [and] the Wharton School, and the Law School of the University of Pennsylvania","volume":"70 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2018-03-17","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"88310441","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 7
Making Bankruptcy Work: Living Wills & the Liquidity Challenge (Presentation Slides) 使破产有效:生前遗嘱和流动性挑战(演示幻灯片)
R. Herring
Presentation with emphasis on the challenges of designing bank resolution procedures that minimize contagion and have credibility with respect to large banks.
重点介绍设计银行清算程序的挑战,以最大限度地减少传染,并在大型银行中具有可信度。
{"title":"Making Bankruptcy Work: Living Wills & the Liquidity Challenge (Presentation Slides)","authors":"R. Herring","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3048513","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3048513","url":null,"abstract":"Presentation with emphasis on the challenges of designing bank resolution procedures that minimize contagion and have credibility with respect to large banks.","PeriodicalId":80976,"journal":{"name":"Comparative labor law journal : a publication of the U.S. National Branch of the International Society for Labor Law and Social Security [and] the Wharton School, and the Law School of the University of Pennsylvania","volume":"18 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2017-05-12","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"86974261","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
The Mortgage Interest Tax Deduction and the Great Recession 按揭利息税减免与经济大衰退
Jonathan S. Hartley, J. Dorf
This paper revisits the mortgage interest deduction (MID) in the U.S. and its distribution across households using ZIP-code level data from the IRS Statistics of Income. Since the Great Recession, the total and average amount of mortgage interest deducted has fallen significantly along with the number of deduction claimants as the home-ownership rate has declined dramatically since the peak of the mid-2000’s housing boom. We also use housing supply as an instrumental variable to better understand how geographic dispersion in housing prices can account for variation in ZIP-code average MID claims. While housing tax benefits are concentrated in high-income areas and regions with inelastic supply, the dollar share of the MID has fallen among the wealthy since the housing bust. We further discuss the implications for policy changes such as the prospects of capping or eliminating the MID or relaxing zoning laws.
本文重新审视了美国的抵押贷款利息扣除(MID)及其在家庭中的分布,使用了来自美国国税局收入统计的邮政编码级数据。自经济大衰退以来,抵押贷款利息扣除的总额和平均金额随着申请扣除的人数大幅下降,因为自2000年中期房地产繁荣达到顶峰以来,住房拥有率大幅下降。我们还使用住房供应作为工具变量,以更好地理解房价的地理分布如何解释邮政编码平均MID索赔的变化。虽然住房税收优惠集中在高收入地区和供应缺乏弹性的地区,但自房地产泡沫破裂以来,中产阶级在富人中的美元份额有所下降。我们进一步讨论对政策变化的影响,例如限制或取消MID或放宽分区法的前景。
{"title":"The Mortgage Interest Tax Deduction and the Great Recession","authors":"Jonathan S. Hartley, J. Dorf","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3134107","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3134107","url":null,"abstract":"This paper revisits the mortgage interest deduction (MID) in the U.S. and its distribution across households using ZIP-code level data from the IRS Statistics of Income. Since the Great Recession, the total and average amount of mortgage interest deducted has fallen significantly along with the number of deduction claimants as the home-ownership rate has declined dramatically since the peak of the mid-2000’s housing boom. We also use housing supply as an instrumental variable to better understand how geographic dispersion in housing prices can account for variation in ZIP-code average MID claims. While housing tax benefits are concentrated in high-income areas and regions with inelastic supply, the dollar share of the MID has fallen among the wealthy since the housing bust. We further discuss the implications for policy changes such as the prospects of capping or eliminating the MID or relaxing zoning laws.","PeriodicalId":80976,"journal":{"name":"Comparative labor law journal : a publication of the U.S. National Branch of the International Society for Labor Law and Social Security [and] the Wharton School, and the Law School of the University of Pennsylvania","volume":"1 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2017-04-28","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"83694229","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Regulating Mortgage Leverage: Fire Sales, Foreclosure Spirals and Pecuniary Externalities 监管抵押贷款杠杆:甩卖、止赎螺旋和金融外部性
A. Zevelev
The US housing boom was accompanied by a rise in mortgage leverage. The subsequent bust was accompanied by a rise in foreclosure. This paper introduces a dynamic general equilibrium model to study how leverage and foreclosure affect house prices. The model shows how foreclosure sales, through their effect on housing supply, amplify and propagate house price drops. A calibration to match the bust shows consumption and housing need to be sufficiently complementary to fit the data. Since leverage plays a key role in foreclosure, a regulator can reduce systemic risk by placing a cap on leverage. Counterfactual experiments show that in a world with less leverage, the same economic shock leads to less foreclosure and less severe, shorter busts in house prices. A 90% cap on loan-to-value ratios in 2006 predicts house prices would have fallen 12% rather than 18% as in the data. The regulator faces a trade-off in that less leverage means less housing for constrained households, but also fewer foreclosures and less severe busts in house prices. A regulator with reasonable preference parameters would choose a cap of 95%.
美国房地产市场的繁荣伴随着抵押贷款杠杆的上升。随后的泡沫破裂伴随着止赎率的上升。本文引入一个动态一般均衡模型来研究杠杆和止赎对房价的影响。该模型显示了丧失抵押品赎回权的销售是如何通过对住房供应的影响放大和传播房价下跌的。一项与泡沫破灭相符的校准显示,消费和住房需要充分互补,才能符合数据。由于杠杆在止赎中起着关键作用,监管机构可以通过限制杠杆来降低系统性风险。反事实的实验表明,在一个杠杆率较低的世界里,同样的经济冲击会导致更少的止赎,以及不那么严重、更短时间的房价崩盘。如果2006年贷款与价值比率(loan-to-value ratio)上限为90%,预计房价将下跌12%,而不是数据显示的18%。监管机构面临着一种权衡,杠杆率降低意味着受约束家庭的住房减少,但也意味着止赎减少,房价破裂程度降低。具有合理偏好参数的监管机构会选择95%的上限。
{"title":"Regulating Mortgage Leverage: Fire Sales, Foreclosure Spirals and Pecuniary Externalities","authors":"A. Zevelev","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.2524764","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2524764","url":null,"abstract":"The US housing boom was accompanied by a rise in mortgage leverage. The subsequent bust was accompanied by a rise in foreclosure. This paper introduces a dynamic general equilibrium model to study how leverage and foreclosure affect house prices. The model shows how foreclosure sales, through their effect on housing supply, amplify and propagate house price drops. A calibration to match the bust shows consumption and housing need to be sufficiently complementary to fit the data. Since leverage plays a key role in foreclosure, a regulator can reduce systemic risk by placing a cap on leverage. Counterfactual experiments show that in a world with less leverage, the same economic shock leads to less foreclosure and less severe, shorter busts in house prices. A 90% cap on loan-to-value ratios in 2006 predicts house prices would have fallen 12% rather than 18% as in the data. The regulator faces a trade-off in that less leverage means less housing for constrained households, but also fewer foreclosures and less severe busts in house prices. A regulator with reasonable preference parameters would choose a cap of 95%.","PeriodicalId":80976,"journal":{"name":"Comparative labor law journal : a publication of the U.S. National Branch of the International Society for Labor Law and Social Security [and] the Wharton School, and the Law School of the University of Pennsylvania","volume":"57 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2017-03-24","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"76926005","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
期刊
Comparative labor law journal : a publication of the U.S. National Branch of the International Society for Labor Law and Social Security [and] the Wharton School, and the Law School of the University of Pennsylvania
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1