首页 > 最新文献

International Trade最新文献

英文 中文
Market Globalization by Firms from Emerging Markets and Small Countries: An Application of the Neoclassical Trade Model 新兴市场和小国企业的市场全球化:新古典贸易模型的应用
Pub Date : 2009-07-15 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.1489623
T. Agmon
The changes in globalization and in the world of international business make it necessary to rethink the basic model of the economics of international business. For most of the 2nd half of the 20th centuryinternational business was about how large companies in the developed countries increase their valuevia international business activities. Not surprisingly the research in the economics of international business from Caves, Kindleberger, and Hymer to Buckley and Casson, Dunning, and many others was based on models of industrial organization. The world has changed and international business has become a two-way street where firms and governments from emerging markets and small countries are as active as the developed countries MNEs and their governments. In this paper the basic international trade model is used to gain insights of the new world of international business. In particular, a dynamic model of changing factor intensity and of creating local specific competitive and comparative advantages for firms and governments from emerging markets is presented and discussed.
全球化和国际商业世界的变化使我们有必要重新思考国际商业经济学的基本模型。在20世纪下半叶的大部分时间里,国际商业是关于发达国家的大公司如何通过国际商业活动来增加他们的价值。毫不奇怪,从凯夫斯、金德尔伯格、海默到巴克利、卡森、邓宁等人的国际商业经济学研究都是基于产业组织模型。世界已经发生了变化,国际商业已经成为一条双向街道,来自新兴市场和小国的公司和政府与发达国家的跨国公司及其政府一样活跃。在本文中,基本的国际贸易模型是用来获得洞察国际商务的新世界。特别是,提出并讨论了一个动态模型,该模型改变了要素强度,并为新兴市场的公司和政府创造了当地特定的竞争和比较优势。
{"title":"Market Globalization by Firms from Emerging Markets and Small Countries: An Application of the Neoclassical Trade Model","authors":"T. Agmon","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.1489623","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1489623","url":null,"abstract":"The changes in globalization and in the world of international business make it necessary to rethink the basic model of the economics of international business. For most of the 2nd half of the 20th centuryinternational business was about how large companies in the developed countries increase their valuevia international business activities. Not surprisingly the research in the economics of international business from Caves, Kindleberger, and Hymer to Buckley and Casson, Dunning, and many others was based on models of industrial organization. The world has changed and international business has become a two-way street where firms and governments from emerging markets and small countries are as active as the developed countries MNEs and their governments. In this paper the basic international trade model is used to gain insights of the new world of international business. In particular, a dynamic model of changing factor intensity and of creating local specific competitive and comparative advantages for firms and governments from emerging markets is presented and discussed.","PeriodicalId":14396,"journal":{"name":"International Trade","volume":"18 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2009-07-15","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"85196687","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 3
Open Borders, Intellectual Property Policy, and Federal Criminal Trade Secret Law 开放边界,知识产权政策和联邦刑事商业秘密法
Pub Date : 2009-07-14 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.1434135
Shubha Ghosh
The mobility of skilled labor across firms has been identified as an important source of regional advantage. Scholars have shown how cultural, economic, and legal conditions (such as the nonenforceability of covenants not to compete) affect the development of high tech sectors that are geographically concentrated. This paper explores to what extent these theories are applicable to the movement of skilled labor across national borders. This inquiry is relevant because the United States enacted the Economic Espionage Act in 1996, and this Act has been used to prosecute non-US skilled workers for theft of trade secret. The Act has application to mobility within the United States as well. To what extent are justifications for the Economic Espionage Act of 1996 mitigated by its effects on labor mobility and the accompanying transfer of knowledge and technology? This paper addresses this question through a theoretical discussion of international trade and mobility of labor and knowledge across borders and an assessment of the case law under the Economic Espionage Act. The author criticizes the Act because of its effect on the transfer of knowledge and makes the case for open borders to promote the mobility of knowledge. Several policy implications are drawn for limits on the Economic Espionage Act, including extraterritorial application of state trade secret law and federal patent law.
技术劳动力在企业之间的流动已被确定为区域优势的重要来源。学者们已经展示了文化、经济和法律条件(如不竞争契约的不可执行性)如何影响地理上集中的高科技部门的发展。本文探讨了这些理论在多大程度上适用于技术劳动力的跨国流动。这项调查具有相关性,因为美国于1996年颁布了《经济间谍法》,该法案已被用于起诉非美国技术工人盗窃商业秘密。该法案也适用于美国境内的流动性。1996年《经济间谍法》对劳动力流动以及随之而来的知识和技术转移的影响,在多大程度上减轻了其正当性?本文通过对国际贸易和跨境劳动力和知识流动的理论讨论以及对《经济间谍法》下的判例法的评估来解决这个问题。作者批评了该法案,因为它对知识转移的影响,并提出了开放边界以促进知识流动的理由。对《经济间谍法》的限制提出了若干政策含义,包括州商业秘密法和联邦专利法的域外适用。
{"title":"Open Borders, Intellectual Property Policy, and Federal Criminal Trade Secret Law","authors":"Shubha Ghosh","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.1434135","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.1434135","url":null,"abstract":"The mobility of skilled labor across firms has been identified as an important source of regional advantage. Scholars have shown how cultural, economic, and legal conditions (such as the nonenforceability of covenants not to compete) affect the development of high tech sectors that are geographically concentrated. This paper explores to what extent these theories are applicable to the movement of skilled labor across national borders. This inquiry is relevant because the United States enacted the Economic Espionage Act in 1996, and this Act has been used to prosecute non-US skilled workers for theft of trade secret. The Act has application to mobility within the United States as well. To what extent are justifications for the Economic Espionage Act of 1996 mitigated by its effects on labor mobility and the accompanying transfer of knowledge and technology? This paper addresses this question through a theoretical discussion of international trade and mobility of labor and knowledge across borders and an assessment of the case law under the Economic Espionage Act. The author criticizes the Act because of its effect on the transfer of knowledge and makes the case for open borders to promote the mobility of knowledge. Several policy implications are drawn for limits on the Economic Espionage Act, including extraterritorial application of state trade secret law and federal patent law.","PeriodicalId":14396,"journal":{"name":"International Trade","volume":"65 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2009-07-14","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"79742984","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
An Economic Analysis of Trade-Secret Protection in Buyer-Seller Relationships 买卖关系中商业秘密保护的经济学分析
Pub Date : 2009-07-01 DOI: 10.1093/JLEO/EWP020
S. Bechtold, Felix Höffler
The economic analysis of trade-secret protection has traditionally focused on the interests of companies to conceal information from competitors in order to gain a competitive advantage through trade-secret law. This has neglected cases in which the interest is not in concealing information from competitors, but from trading partners. We investigate the social efficiency effects of trade-secret protection in such cases. Many results from economic theory state that asymmetric information (and therefore also its legal protection) is socially undesirable since it leads to inefficient trade. At the same time, protecting private information might create incentives for socially desirable investments. We model this trade-off in a simple buyer-seller model and find that, indeed, trade-secret protection has ambiguous welfare effects. However, a simple, informationally undemanding rule, conditioning the applicability of legal protection on a minimum investment by the informed party to conceal the information, helps to apply trade-secret protection only when it increases welfare. This rationalizes important features of current legal practice.
传统上对商业秘密保护的经济分析主要集中在公司通过商业秘密法向竞争对手隐瞒信息以获得竞争优势的利益上。这忽略了一些情况,其中的利益不是向竞争对手隐瞒信息,而是向贸易伙伴隐瞒信息。在这种情况下,我们研究了商业秘密保护的社会效率效应。经济理论的许多结果表明,信息不对称(以及它的法律保护)在社会上是不受欢迎的,因为它会导致贸易效率低下。与此同时,保护私人信息可能会为社会期望的投资创造激励。我们用一个简单的买卖模型来模拟这种权衡,并发现商业秘密保护确实具有模糊的福利效应。然而,一个简单的、信息要求不高的规则,将法律保护的适用性限制在被告知方隐瞒信息的最小投资上,只有当它增加福利时,才有助于应用商业秘密保护。这使当前法律实践的重要特征合理化。
{"title":"An Economic Analysis of Trade-Secret Protection in Buyer-Seller Relationships","authors":"S. Bechtold, Felix Höffler","doi":"10.1093/JLEO/EWP020","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1093/JLEO/EWP020","url":null,"abstract":"The economic analysis of trade-secret protection has traditionally focused on the interests of companies to conceal information from competitors in order to gain a competitive advantage through trade-secret law. This has neglected cases in which the interest is not in concealing information from competitors, but from trading partners. We investigate the social efficiency effects of trade-secret protection in such cases. Many results from economic theory state that asymmetric information (and therefore also its legal protection) is socially undesirable since it leads to inefficient trade. At the same time, protecting private information might create incentives for socially desirable investments. We model this trade-off in a simple buyer-seller model and find that, indeed, trade-secret protection has ambiguous welfare effects. However, a simple, informationally undemanding rule, conditioning the applicability of legal protection on a minimum investment by the informed party to conceal the information, helps to apply trade-secret protection only when it increases welfare. This rationalizes important features of current legal practice.","PeriodicalId":14396,"journal":{"name":"International Trade","volume":"16 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2009-07-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"73974852","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 6
Global Competitiveness of Powder Metallurgy Part Manufacturing in North Central Pennsylvania 宾夕法尼亚州中北部粉末冶金零件制造业的全球竞争力
Pub Date : 2009-07-01 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.1426266
R. Baker, D. Passmore
Provided in this report is information summarizing the global competitive dynamics and pressures on the PM part manufacturing industry in north central Pennsylvania. Information is provided about the geographic/economic region in which the industry operates. A brief description of PM manufacturing materials and processes is presented. Then, an analysis is reported of the economic and workforce structure of PM part manufacturing industry in north central Pennsylvania. Last, evidence of competitive forces affecting the industry is drawn from structured face-to-face and telephone meetings, gleaned during plant tours and over informal lunches, linked by following trends and themes in documents, and captured in confidences revealed in unstructured personal conversations. These competitive forces are summarized around five themes: the threat of entry of new competitors; bargaining power of customers; bargaining power of suppliers; the threat (and opportunity) posed by substitute products; and the nature of competitive rivalry within the PM part manufacturing industry. The kernel of competition in the PM part manufacturing industry is summarized in the following simple statements:• The north central region of Pennsylvania is an economic region that is the locus of PM part manufacturing industry activity in the United States. It generates much economic good in the region for individuals and institutions. The industry is both a jewel and a bellwether for the Pennsylvania economy. The competitiveness of the PM part industry is a lynchpin economic driver in Pennsylvania, in general, and the north central region, in particular.• The PM part manufacturing industry brings unique and specialized manufacturing know–how from Pennsylvania to the world through its economic and technological contribution and potential.• New competitors can enter the industry at the low end with modest capital and knowledge of PM parts manufacturing. However, to play at the high end, new market entrants require deeper pockets. • Foreign involvement and ownership are diffusing around the world the specialized knowledge and human capital that formerly was localized to north central Pennsylvania. Competition is not local any more. It is global.• PM part manufacturers compete aggressively and almost solely on the basis of price.• Poor understanding and inaccurate perceptions held by customers about the materials, processes, and end-products of PM part manufacturing affect the competitive position of the industry.• The PM industry deals with a small number of large suppliers and customers who have the power to dictate the ability of PM part manufacturing firms to cover their costs and make a profit. • The PM part manufacturing industry is small relative to the entire manufacturing sector and, in particular, within the fabricated metal product manufacturing subsector. Just on these scale factors alone, opportunities probably are large for capturing metal fabrication opportunities from othe
本报告提供的信息总结了宾夕法尼亚州中北部PM零件制造业的全球竞争动态和压力。提供有关该行业经营所在地理/经济区域的信息。简要介绍了粉末冶金的制造材料和工艺。然后,对宾夕法尼亚州中北部粉末冶金零件制造业的经济和劳动力结构进行了分析。最后,影响行业的竞争力量的证据来自结构化的面对面和电话会议,在工厂参观和非正式午餐期间收集,与文件中的趋势和主题联系在一起,并在非结构化的个人谈话中透露的机密中获得。这些竞争力量围绕五个主题进行总结:新竞争者进入的威胁;客户议价能力;供应商议价能力;替代产品带来的威胁(和机会);以及PM零件制造行业内竞争的本质。在PM零件制造业竞争的核心是以下简单的陈述总结:•宾夕法尼亚州的中北部地区是一个经济区域,是美国PM零件制造业活动的所在地。它为该地区的个人和机构带来了巨大的经济效益。该行业既是宾夕法尼亚州经济的宝石,也是宾夕法尼亚州经济的风向标。一般来说,PM零件行业的竞争力是宾夕法尼亚州,特别是中北部地区的关键经济驱动力。•PM零件制造业通过其经济和技术贡献和潜力,将宾夕法尼亚州独特的专业制造技术带到世界各地。•新的竞争对手可以在低端进入该行业,拥有适度的资本和PM零件制造知识。然而,要进入高端市场,新进入者需要更雄厚的财力。•外资的参与和所有权正在将以前局限于宾夕法尼亚州中北部的专业知识和人力资本扩散到世界各地。竞争不再局限于本地。它是全球性的。•PM零件制造商竞争激烈,几乎完全基于价格。•客户对PM零件制造的材料、工艺和最终产品的理解不足和不准确的认知影响了行业的竞争地位。•PM行业与少数大型供应商和客户打交道,这些供应商和客户有权决定PM零件制造公司支付成本和盈利的能力。•PM零件制造行业相对于整个制造业来说规模较小,特别是在金属制品制造子行业中。仅就这些规模因素而言,从其他行业获取金属制造机会或寻找与其他金属制造行业创造互补产品的方法的机会可能很大。•在制造金属制品行业的公司之间的竞争是激烈的PM零件市场。粉末冶金零件制造业与锻钢行业之间的连杆市场争夺就是一个很好的例子。•汽车市场是PM零件制造行业的主导力量。汽车行业遵循的供应商纪律文化保证了PM零件制造的成本节约,价格竞争环境。•金属商品价格波动和上涨,增加了风险,不确定性,并增加了金属粉末投入到PM零件制造的成本。•过去错误地指定PM不适合PM的零件所犯的错误导致了信誉问题,这仍然影响着行业的竞争地位。•PM零件制造行业很难招聘到具有适应该行业技能的工人。这个问题的部分原因在于技能创造渠道的不足;造成这一问题的部分原因在于,该行业位于宾夕法尼亚州中北部,地理位置相对孤立。•PM零件制造公司之间的竞争激烈,几乎完全基于价格,但很少与其他工艺竞争。
{"title":"Global Competitiveness of Powder Metallurgy Part Manufacturing in North Central Pennsylvania","authors":"R. Baker, D. Passmore","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.1426266","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1426266","url":null,"abstract":"Provided in this report is information summarizing the global competitive dynamics and pressures on the PM part manufacturing industry in north central Pennsylvania. Information is provided about the geographic/economic region in which the industry operates. A brief description of PM manufacturing materials and processes is presented. Then, an analysis is reported of the economic and workforce structure of PM part manufacturing industry in north central Pennsylvania. Last, evidence of competitive forces affecting the industry is drawn from structured face-to-face and telephone meetings, gleaned during plant tours and over informal lunches, linked by following trends and themes in documents, and captured in confidences revealed in unstructured personal conversations. These competitive forces are summarized around five themes: the threat of entry of new competitors; bargaining power of customers; bargaining power of suppliers; the threat (and opportunity) posed by substitute products; and the nature of competitive rivalry within the PM part manufacturing industry. The kernel of competition in the PM part manufacturing industry is summarized in the following simple statements:• The north central region of Pennsylvania is an economic region that is the locus of PM part manufacturing industry activity in the United States. It generates much economic good in the region for individuals and institutions. The industry is both a jewel and a bellwether for the Pennsylvania economy. The competitiveness of the PM part industry is a lynchpin economic driver in Pennsylvania, in general, and the north central region, in particular.• The PM part manufacturing industry brings unique and specialized manufacturing know–how from Pennsylvania to the world through its economic and technological contribution and potential.• New competitors can enter the industry at the low end with modest capital and knowledge of PM parts manufacturing. However, to play at the high end, new market entrants require deeper pockets. • Foreign involvement and ownership are diffusing around the world the specialized knowledge and human capital that formerly was localized to north central Pennsylvania. Competition is not local any more. It is global.• PM part manufacturers compete aggressively and almost solely on the basis of price.• Poor understanding and inaccurate perceptions held by customers about the materials, processes, and end-products of PM part manufacturing affect the competitive position of the industry.• The PM industry deals with a small number of large suppliers and customers who have the power to dictate the ability of PM part manufacturing firms to cover their costs and make a profit. • The PM part manufacturing industry is small relative to the entire manufacturing sector and, in particular, within the fabricated metal product manufacturing subsector. Just on these scale factors alone, opportunities probably are large for capturing metal fabrication opportunities from othe","PeriodicalId":14396,"journal":{"name":"International Trade","volume":"61 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2009-07-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"90860536","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Initiatives Should Be Taken to Facilitate South Asian Economic Integration 应采取措施促进南亚经济一体化
Pub Date : 2009-06-27 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.1426442
M. Abdin
Last month I was in Singapore to join an international seminar on 'Pan Asian Integration' but before that we must be integrated in South Asia to facilitate integration with East Asia. The South Asian Association for Regional Cooperation (SAARC) is mandated for poverty alleviation through trade and economic cooperation in the region. It did not gain momentum up to the desired level. Intra-SAARC trade remained lower than 5% even after 23 years of SAARC's inception. The foreign direct investment (FDI) among the SAARC region is very negligible. Intra-regional investment depends on the capability to pursue deep integration and economic connectivity. Our previous efforts to boost intra-regional trade through South Asian Preferential Trade Arrangement (SAPTA) did not meet with success because of some factors like intercountry barriers to trade, rampant informal trade, high tariff, non-tariff barriers, absence of harmonisation of standards, non-simplification of customs clearance procedures, non-simplification of banking procedures, barriers to intra-SAARC investment and inadequate transport infrastructure. Effective trade facilitation measures should be implemented as an obligation to ensure enabling trade policy and governance for smooth and speedy movement of goods across the borders.
上个月,我在新加坡参加了一个关于“泛亚一体化”的国际研讨会,但在此之前,我们必须在南亚实现一体化,以促进与东亚的一体化。南亚区域合作联盟(南盟)的任务是通过该区域的贸易和经济合作来减轻贫困。它没有获得达到预期水平的动力。即使在南盟成立23年后,南盟内部的贸易仍低于5%。南盟地区的外国直接投资(FDI)非常微不足道。区域内投资取决于实现深度一体化和经济互联互通的能力。我们以前通过南亚优惠贸易安排(SAPTA)促进区域内贸易的努力没有取得成功,原因包括一些因素,如国家间贸易壁垒、猖獗的非正式贸易、高关税、非关税壁垒、缺乏统一的标准、未简化的通关程序、未简化的银行程序、南盟内部投资壁垒和运输基础设施不足。应将有效的贸易便利化措施作为一项义务加以实施,确保有利的贸易政策和治理,促进货物顺利、快速地跨境流动。
{"title":"Initiatives Should Be Taken to Facilitate South Asian Economic Integration","authors":"M. Abdin","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.1426442","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1426442","url":null,"abstract":"Last month I was in Singapore to join an international seminar on 'Pan Asian Integration' but before that we must be integrated in South Asia to facilitate integration with East Asia. The South Asian Association for Regional Cooperation (SAARC) is mandated for poverty alleviation through trade and economic cooperation in the region. It did not gain momentum up to the desired level. Intra-SAARC trade remained lower than 5% even after 23 years of SAARC's inception. The foreign direct investment (FDI) among the SAARC region is very negligible. Intra-regional investment depends on the capability to pursue deep integration and economic connectivity. Our previous efforts to boost intra-regional trade through South Asian Preferential Trade Arrangement (SAPTA) did not meet with success because of some factors like intercountry barriers to trade, rampant informal trade, high tariff, non-tariff barriers, absence of harmonisation of standards, non-simplification of customs clearance procedures, non-simplification of banking procedures, barriers to intra-SAARC investment and inadequate transport infrastructure. Effective trade facilitation measures should be implemented as an obligation to ensure enabling trade policy and governance for smooth and speedy movement of goods across the borders.","PeriodicalId":14396,"journal":{"name":"International Trade","volume":"1 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2009-06-27","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"89571928","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Retaliatory Disagreement Point with Asymmetric Countries: Evidence from European Wine Sector During Enlargement 不对称国家的报复性分歧点:来自欧洲葡萄酒行业扩张的证据
Pub Date : 2009-06-15 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.1435993
Genoveva Elena Perju
The vector space model facilitates a very useful representation of the strategic interaction in trade because it is possible to incorporate both symmetric and asymmetric features of the players. This paper characterizes the Nash solution of the non-cooperative international trade game in the orthogonal vector space. We have used the standard properties of the Nash solution to determine if the non-cooperative action-reaction trade policy space should be written in terms of 'import-import' or 'import-export' quotas as strongest punishment. The trade policy space defined by import-export' quotas is not a Nash solution of the non-cooperative game but an improvement in the disagreement set. We show the positive correlation between import and export quotas using data on trade relations between EU-15, Romania, Hungary and Bulgaria for wine sector during 1995-2005. In our model the outcome of the non-cooperative trade is autarky. Retaliation is played when countries restrict their imports to one third of the national optimum.
向量空间模型有助于非常有用地表示贸易中的战略互动,因为它可以结合参与者的对称和不对称特征。本文在正交向量空间中刻画了非合作国际贸易博弈的纳什解。我们使用纳什解的标准属性来确定非合作行动-反应贸易政策空间是否应该以“进口-进口”或“进口-出口”配额作为最严厉的惩罚。由进出口配额定义的贸易政策空间不是非合作博弈的纳什解,而是对分歧集的改进。我们使用欧盟15国、罗马尼亚、匈牙利和保加利亚1995-2005年间葡萄酒行业贸易关系的数据显示了进出口配额之间的正相关关系。在我们的模型中,非合作贸易的结果是自给自足的。当一国将进口限制在本国最优水平的三分之一时,就会进行报复。
{"title":"Retaliatory Disagreement Point with Asymmetric Countries: Evidence from European Wine Sector During Enlargement","authors":"Genoveva Elena Perju","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.1435993","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1435993","url":null,"abstract":"The vector space model facilitates a very useful representation of the strategic interaction in trade because it is possible to incorporate both symmetric and asymmetric features of the players. This paper characterizes the Nash solution of the non-cooperative international trade game in the orthogonal vector space. We have used the standard properties of the Nash solution to determine if the non-cooperative action-reaction trade policy space should be written in terms of 'import-import' or 'import-export' quotas as strongest punishment. The trade policy space defined by import-export' quotas is not a Nash solution of the non-cooperative game but an improvement in the disagreement set. We show the positive correlation between import and export quotas using data on trade relations between EU-15, Romania, Hungary and Bulgaria for wine sector during 1995-2005. In our model the outcome of the non-cooperative trade is autarky. Retaliation is played when countries restrict their imports to one third of the national optimum.","PeriodicalId":14396,"journal":{"name":"International Trade","volume":"2 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2009-06-15","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"87165018","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
The ASEAN Free Trade Agreement: Impact on Trade Flows and External Trade Barriers 东盟自由贸易协定:对贸易流动和外部贸易壁垒的影响
Pub Date : 2009-06-01 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.2483814
Hector F. Calvo Pardo, C. Freund, E. Ornelas
Using detailed data on trade and tariffs from 1992-2007, the authors examine how the ASEAN Free Trade Agreement has affected trade with nonmembers and external tariffs facing nonmembers. First, the paper examines the effect of preferential and external tariff reduction on import growth from ASEAN insiders and outsiders across HS 6-digit industries. The analysis finds no evidence that preferential liberalization has led to lower import growth from nonmembers. Second, it examines the relationship between preferential tariff reduction and MFN tariff reduction. The analysis finds that preferential liberalization tends to precede external tariff liberalization. To examine whether this tariff complementarity is a result of simultaneous decision making, the authors use the scheduled future preferential tariff reductions (agreed to in 1992) as instruments for actual preferential tariff changes after the Asia crisis. The results remain unchanged, suggesting that there is a causal relationship between preferential and MFN tariff reduction. The findings also indicate that external liberalization was relatively sharper in the products where preferences are likely to be most damaging, proving further support for a causal effect. Overall, the results imply that the ASEAN agreement has been a force for broader liberalization.
利用1992年至2007年的贸易和关税的详细数据,作者研究了东盟自由贸易协定如何影响与非成员国的贸易以及非成员国面临的外部关税。首先,本文考察了优惠和外部关税削减对东盟内部和外部HS 6位数行业进口增长的影响。分析发现,没有证据表明优惠的自由化导致来自非成员国的进口增长下降。其次,考察特惠关税减让与最惠国关税减让的关系。分析发现,优惠关税自由化倾向于先于外部关税自由化。为了检验这种关税互补性是否是同时决策的结果,作者使用计划中的未来优惠关税削减(1992年商定)作为亚洲危机后实际优惠关税变化的工具。结果保持不变,表明特惠关税和最惠国关税削减之间存在因果关系。研究结果还表明,在偏好可能最具破坏性的产品中,外部自由化相对更为明显,进一步证明了因果效应的支持。总体而言,调查结果表明,东盟协议一直是推动更广泛自由化的力量。
{"title":"The ASEAN Free Trade Agreement: Impact on Trade Flows and External Trade Barriers","authors":"Hector F. Calvo Pardo, C. Freund, E. Ornelas","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.2483814","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2483814","url":null,"abstract":"Using detailed data on trade and tariffs from 1992-2007, the authors examine how the ASEAN Free Trade Agreement has affected trade with nonmembers and external tariffs facing nonmembers. First, the paper examines the effect of preferential and external tariff reduction on import growth from ASEAN insiders and outsiders across HS 6-digit industries. The analysis finds no evidence that preferential liberalization has led to lower import growth from nonmembers. Second, it examines the relationship between preferential tariff reduction and MFN tariff reduction. The analysis finds that preferential liberalization tends to precede external tariff liberalization. To examine whether this tariff complementarity is a result of simultaneous decision making, the authors use the scheduled future preferential tariff reductions (agreed to in 1992) as instruments for actual preferential tariff changes after the Asia crisis. The results remain unchanged, suggesting that there is a causal relationship between preferential and MFN tariff reduction. The findings also indicate that external liberalization was relatively sharper in the products where preferences are likely to be most damaging, proving further support for a causal effect. Overall, the results imply that the ASEAN agreement has been a force for broader liberalization.","PeriodicalId":14396,"journal":{"name":"International Trade","volume":"81 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2009-06-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"74507506","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 101
Global Economic and Financial Crisis: India's Trade Potential and Future Prospects 全球经济和金融危机:印度的贸易潜力和未来前景
Pub Date : 2009-06-01 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.1412592
P. De
This paper estimates the trade potential for India using the augmented gravity model and then attempts to determine the importance of trade remedies. Based on panel data, this gravity model is the first-ever attempt to estimate India’s trade potential in the pre- and post- global economic and financial crisis period. The estimates of India’s global trade potential reveal that the magnitude of India’s trade potential is at its maximum in the Asia-Pacific region, followed by Africa and Latin America. Potential for expansion of trade in the post-crisis period is highest for countries such as China. However, in a large part of the world, India’s trade has remained unrealized, which provides further opportunities to expand despite the slowdown in global demand. There is a strong complementary role, as the findings of this paper indicate; i.e., tariff liberalization and trade facilitation, which taken together can help build export momentum in the crisis period.
本文利用增强重力模型估计了印度的贸易潜力,然后试图确定贸易救济的重要性。基于面板数据,这个重力模型是首次尝试估计印度在全球经济和金融危机前后的贸易潜力。对印度全球贸易潜力的估计显示,印度在亚太地区的贸易潜力最大,其次是非洲和拉丁美洲。在后危机时期,中国等国的贸易扩张潜力最大。然而,在世界很大一部分地区,印度的贸易仍未实现,这为在全球需求放缓的情况下扩大提供了进一步的机会。正如本文的研究结果所表明的那样,存在很强的互补作用;即关税自由化和贸易便利化,两者结合起来有助于在危机时期建立出口动力。
{"title":"Global Economic and Financial Crisis: India's Trade Potential and Future Prospects","authors":"P. De","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.1412592","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1412592","url":null,"abstract":"This paper estimates the trade potential for India using the augmented gravity model and then attempts to determine the importance of trade remedies. Based on panel data, this gravity model is the first-ever attempt to estimate India’s trade potential in the pre- and post- global economic and financial crisis period. The estimates of India’s global trade potential reveal that the magnitude of India’s trade potential is at its maximum in the Asia-Pacific region, followed by Africa and Latin America. Potential for expansion of trade in the post-crisis period is highest for countries such as China. However, in a large part of the world, India’s trade has remained unrealized, which provides further opportunities to expand despite the slowdown in global demand. There is a strong complementary role, as the findings of this paper indicate; i.e., tariff liberalization and trade facilitation, which taken together can help build export momentum in the crisis period.","PeriodicalId":14396,"journal":{"name":"International Trade","volume":"88 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2009-06-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"73395190","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 22
On the Specification of the Gravity Model of Trade: Zeros, Excess Zeros and Zero-Inflated Estimation 贸易重力模型的规范:零、超额零与零膨胀估计
Pub Date : 2009-06-01 DOI: 10.1080/17421770902834327
M. Burger, F. V. van Oort, G. Linders
Conventional studies of bilateral trade patterns specify a log-normal gravity equation for empirical estimation. However, the log-normal gravity equation suffers from three problems: the bias created by the logarithmic transformation, the failure of the homoscedasticity assumption, and the way zero values are treated. These problems normally result in biased and inefficient estimates. Recently, the Poisson specification of the trade gravity model has received attention as an alternative to the log-normality assumption (Santos Silva and Tenreyro, 2006). However, the standard Poisson model is vulnerable for problems of overdispersion and excess zero flows. To overcome these problems, this paper considers modified Poisson fixed-effects estimations (negative binomial, zero-inflated). Extending the empirical model put forward by Santos Silva and Tenreyro (2006), we show how these techniques may provide viable alternatives to both the log-normal and standard Poisson specification of the gravity model of trade.
双边贸易模式的传统研究指定了一个对数正态重力方程用于经验估计。然而,对数正态重力方程存在三个问题:对数变换产生的偏差,均方差假设的失败,以及处理零值的方式。这些问题通常会导致有偏差和低效的估计。最近,贸易重力模型的泊松规范作为对数正态性假设的替代方案受到了关注(Santos Silva和Tenreyro, 2006)。然而,标准泊松模型容易出现过分散和超零流问题。为了克服这些问题,本文考虑了修正泊松固定效应估计(负二项、零膨胀)。扩展Santos Silva和Tenreyro(2006)提出的经验模型,我们展示了这些技术如何为贸易重力模型的对数正态和标准泊松规范提供可行的替代方案。
{"title":"On the Specification of the Gravity Model of Trade: Zeros, Excess Zeros and Zero-Inflated Estimation","authors":"M. Burger, F. V. van Oort, G. Linders","doi":"10.1080/17421770902834327","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1080/17421770902834327","url":null,"abstract":"Conventional studies of bilateral trade patterns specify a log-normal gravity equation for empirical estimation. However, the log-normal gravity equation suffers from three problems: the bias created by the logarithmic transformation, the failure of the homoscedasticity assumption, and the way zero values are treated. These problems normally result in biased and inefficient estimates. Recently, the Poisson specification of the trade gravity model has received attention as an alternative to the log-normality assumption (Santos Silva and Tenreyro, 2006). However, the standard Poisson model is vulnerable for problems of overdispersion and excess zero flows. To overcome these problems, this paper considers modified Poisson fixed-effects estimations (negative binomial, zero-inflated). Extending the empirical model put forward by Santos Silva and Tenreyro (2006), we show how these techniques may provide viable alternatives to both the log-normal and standard Poisson specification of the gravity model of trade.","PeriodicalId":14396,"journal":{"name":"International Trade","volume":"92 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2009-06-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"83748911","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 570
Vertical and Horizontal Intra-Industry Trade Between the U.S. And NAFTA Partners 美国与北美自由贸易协定伙伴之间的纵向和横向产业内贸易
Pub Date : 2009-06-01 DOI: 10.4067/S0718-88702009000100002
E. M. Ekayanake, Bala Veeramacheneni, Carlos Moslares
The main objectives of this paper are to (a) explain the extent of vertical and horizontal intra-industry trade in the United State’s foreign trade with the North American Free Trade Area (NAFTA), and (b) identify the industry-specific determinants of vertical and horizontal intra-industry trade. One of the main findings is that the observed increase in intra-industry trade between the United States and NAFTA is almost entirely due to two-way trade in vertical differentiation. Another important finding is that the share of horizontal intra-industry trade has increased significantly during this period, although vertical intra-industry trade continued to be dominant in the U.S.-NAFTA IIT Trade. Among the industry-specific variables, product differentiation, vertical product differentiation, and product quality differences are found to have a positive effect on all three types of IIT shares. Industry concentration and industry size are found to have a negative and statistically significant effect on all three types of IIT share.
本文的主要目标是(a)解释垂直和水平产业内贸易在美国与北美自由贸易区(NAFTA)的对外贸易中的程度,以及(b)确定垂直和水平产业内贸易的行业特定决定因素。其中一个主要发现是,观察到的美国和北美自由贸易协定之间产业内贸易的增长几乎完全是由于垂直差异化的双向贸易。另一个重要的发现是,在此期间,横向产业内贸易的份额显著增加,尽管垂直产业内贸易继续在美国-北美自由贸易协定的IIT贸易中占主导地位。在特定行业变量中,产品差异化、垂直产品差异化和产品质量差异对三种类型的IIT股票均有正向影响。研究发现,行业集中度和行业规模对三种类型的IIT份额均有显著的负向影响。
{"title":"Vertical and Horizontal Intra-Industry Trade Between the U.S. And NAFTA Partners","authors":"E. M. Ekayanake, Bala Veeramacheneni, Carlos Moslares","doi":"10.4067/S0718-88702009000100002","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.4067/S0718-88702009000100002","url":null,"abstract":"The main objectives of this paper are to (a) explain the extent of vertical and horizontal intra-industry trade in the United State’s foreign trade with the North American Free Trade Area (NAFTA), and (b) identify the industry-specific determinants of vertical and horizontal intra-industry trade. One of the main findings is that the observed increase in intra-industry trade between the United States and NAFTA is almost entirely due to two-way trade in vertical differentiation. Another important finding is that the share of horizontal intra-industry trade has increased significantly during this period, although vertical intra-industry trade continued to be dominant in the U.S.-NAFTA IIT Trade. Among the industry-specific variables, product differentiation, vertical product differentiation, and product quality differences are found to have a positive effect on all three types of IIT shares. Industry concentration and industry size are found to have a negative and statistically significant effect on all three types of IIT share.","PeriodicalId":14396,"journal":{"name":"International Trade","volume":"78 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2009-06-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"81270616","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 30
期刊
International Trade
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1