首页 > 最新文献

Macroeconomics: National Income & Product Accounts eJournal最新文献

英文 中文
Getting Rental Prices Right for Computers: Reconciling Different Perspectives on Depreciation 让电脑租金价格合理:调和折旧的不同观点
Pub Date : 2017-02-01 DOI: 10.1111/roiw.12249
Erwin Diewert, Hui Wei
National statistical agencies frequently assume high geometric depreciation rates for computers. However, typically the service flow that a computer generates over its useful life is roughly constant, which contradicts the geometric model of depreciation. A one hoss shay model of depreciation seems to be more appropriate for computers. The paper uses Australian data on computer investment over the past 25 years to construct one hoss shay estimates of computer capital stocks and flows and considers how best to approximate these more realistic models of depreciation with a geometric model. The paper shows that under certain assumptions, a geometric model can provide an exact approximation to an underlying one hoss shay model. This exactness result is extended to a more general model of depreciation, the Constant Efficiency Profile model. Finally, the paper shows how well the geometric approximation fits a one hoss shay model when the assumptions are not satisfied.
国家统计机构经常假定计算机的几何折旧率很高。然而,通常一台计算机在其使用寿命内产生的服务流大致是恒定的,这与折旧的几何模型相矛盾。单主机shay折旧模型似乎更适合于计算机。本文利用澳大利亚过去25年的计算机投资数据,构建了计算机资本存量和流动的粗略估计,并考虑了如何用几何模型最好地近似这些更现实的折旧模型。本文表明,在一定的假设条件下,几何模型可以提供一个精确的近似底层单host shay模型。这个精确的结果可以推广到更一般的折旧模型,即恒定效率剖面模型。最后,给出了在假设不满足的情况下,几何近似对单host shay模型的拟合效果。
{"title":"Getting Rental Prices Right for Computers: Reconciling Different Perspectives on Depreciation","authors":"Erwin Diewert, Hui Wei","doi":"10.1111/roiw.12249","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1111/roiw.12249","url":null,"abstract":"National statistical agencies frequently assume high geometric depreciation rates for computers. However, typically the service flow that a computer generates over its useful life is roughly constant, which contradicts the geometric model of depreciation. A one hoss shay model of depreciation seems to be more appropriate for computers. The paper uses Australian data on computer investment over the past 25 years to construct one hoss shay estimates of computer capital stocks and flows and considers how best to approximate these more realistic models of depreciation with a geometric model. The paper shows that under certain assumptions, a geometric model can provide an exact approximation to an underlying one hoss shay model. This exactness result is extended to a more general model of depreciation, the Constant Efficiency Profile model. Finally, the paper shows how well the geometric approximation fits a one hoss shay model when the assumptions are not satisfied.","PeriodicalId":18164,"journal":{"name":"Macroeconomics: National Income & Product Accounts eJournal","volume":"28 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2017-02-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"87013739","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 3
What Do the Different Measures of GDP Tell Us? 不同的GDP指标告诉我们什么?
Pub Date : 2016-12-08 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.2888931
Philip Cross
GDP is key to macroeconomics, yet different ways of defining and measuring GDP have particular purposes. This paper examines how total GDP can be conceptualized, dissected and studied and how these improve our analysis and understanding of the sources of economic growth. While each approach is useful, macroeconomic analysis is shifting from a short-term, recession-driven focus on managing aggregate demand to a long-term, supply-side perspective on the determinants of economic growth. This shift is likely to accelerate in the current environment of concerns about a “new normal” of slow growth, with the debate framed by supply determinants such as an aging labour force and whether technological innovations have been mostly exhausted. How one views GDP has important implications for policymaking. If today’s chronic slow growth is due to deficiency of demand, stimulative fiscal policies might be the proper response, depending on a country’s fiscal capacity to take on more debt. However, if the shortfall in growth is due to a lack of productivity growth, different policies might be appropriate that increase the efficiency of resource use or the rate of innovation. The point is that a more detailed understanding of each measure of GDP leads to better comprehension of why it behaves in a particular way in response to different economic circumstances. This knowledge will allow policymakers to make more informed decisions. The author reviews each of the different ways of looking at GDP and how they evolved in response to the needs of analysts. He summarizes the strengths and weaknesses of each and what can be learned by contrasting and combining them in analysis. In order the six are: • GDP by industry; • GDP by expenditure; • GDP by income; • The quantity equation; • GDP by input/output; and • GDP by factor input. For economists, the different optics for viewing economic activity lead to a more profound understanding of the process of economic growth. Good analysis and policy prescription often depend on finding the right optic to understand a particular problem.
GDP是宏观经济学的关键,然而不同的定义和衡量GDP的方法有不同的目的。本文探讨了如何对GDP总量进行概念化、剖析和研究,以及这些如何提高我们对经济增长来源的分析和理解。虽然每种方法都很有用,但宏观经济分析正在从短期的、由衰退驱动的、聚焦于管理总需求的方式,转向长期的、着眼于经济增长决定因素的供给侧视角。在当前人们对低增长的“新常态”感到担忧的环境下,这种转变可能会加速,围绕供应决定因素(如劳动力老龄化,以及技术创新是否已基本枯竭)展开的辩论。如何看待GDP对政策制定具有重要意义。如果今天的长期缓慢增长是由于需求不足,刺激性财政政策可能是适当的应对措施,这取决于一个国家承担更多债务的财政能力。然而,如果增长的不足是由于缺乏生产率增长,那么提高资源使用效率或创新速度的不同政策可能是适当的。关键在于,更详细地了解GDP的每一项指标,就能更好地理解为什么它在不同的经济环境下会以特定的方式表现出来。这些知识将使决策者能够做出更明智的决策。作者回顾了看待GDP的每一种不同方式,以及它们是如何根据分析师的需求而演变的。他总结了每种方法的优点和缺点,以及通过对比和结合分析可以学到什么。这六项依次为:•按行业划分的GDP;•按支出计算的国内生产总值;•按收入计算的GDP;•数量方程;•按投入/产出计算的GDP;按要素投入计算的GDP。对于经济学家来说,观察经济活动的不同视角导致对经济增长过程的更深刻理解。好的分析和政策处方往往取决于找到正确的视角来理解一个特定的问题。
{"title":"What Do the Different Measures of GDP Tell Us?","authors":"Philip Cross","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.2888931","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2888931","url":null,"abstract":"GDP is key to macroeconomics, yet different ways of defining and measuring GDP have particular purposes. This paper examines how total GDP can be conceptualized, dissected and studied and how these improve our analysis and understanding of the sources of economic growth. While each approach is useful, macroeconomic analysis is shifting from a short-term, recession-driven focus on managing aggregate demand to a long-term, supply-side perspective on the determinants of economic growth. This shift is likely to accelerate in the current environment of concerns about a “new normal” of slow growth, with the debate framed by supply determinants such as an aging labour force and whether technological innovations have been mostly exhausted. How one views GDP has important implications for policymaking. If today’s chronic slow growth is due to deficiency of demand, stimulative fiscal policies might be the proper response, depending on a country’s fiscal capacity to take on more debt. However, if the shortfall in growth is due to a lack of productivity growth, different policies might be appropriate that increase the efficiency of resource use or the rate of innovation. The point is that a more detailed understanding of each measure of GDP leads to better comprehension of why it behaves in a particular way in response to different economic circumstances. This knowledge will allow policymakers to make more informed decisions. The author reviews each of the different ways of looking at GDP and how they evolved in response to the needs of analysts. He summarizes the strengths and weaknesses of each and what can be learned by contrasting and combining them in analysis. In order the six are: \u0000• GDP by industry; • GDP by expenditure; • GDP by income; • The quantity equation; • GDP by input/output; and • GDP by factor input. \u0000For economists, the different optics for viewing economic activity lead to a more profound understanding of the process of economic growth. Good analysis and policy prescription often depend on finding the right optic to understand a particular problem.","PeriodicalId":18164,"journal":{"name":"Macroeconomics: National Income & Product Accounts eJournal","volume":"70 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2016-12-08","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"76212729","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 7
Credit Markets and Housing Choices 信贷市场和住房选择
Pub Date : 2016-12-01 DOI: 10.1111/boer.12063
Serena Trucchi
This paper analyses how individual characteristics and credit market conditions interact and determine homeownership. The impact of the lifetime profile of resources on homeownership is larger when credit market imperfections are more severe. We combine data from the Bank of Italy's Survey on Household Income and Wealth with information on regional differences in interest rate spreads. We find that an increase in current resources by 10,000 euros increases the probability of homeownership by five (two) percentage points under the least (most) favourable credit market conditions.
本文分析了个人特征和信贷市场条件如何相互作用并决定房屋所有权。当信贷市场缺陷更严重时,资源的终身概况对房屋所有权的影响更大。我们将意大利银行家庭收入和财富调查的数据与利差的地区差异信息结合起来。我们发现,在最不(最)有利的信贷市场条件下,当前资源每增加10,000欧元,房屋所有权的可能性就会增加5(2)个百分点。
{"title":"Credit Markets and Housing Choices","authors":"Serena Trucchi","doi":"10.1111/boer.12063","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1111/boer.12063","url":null,"abstract":"This paper analyses how individual characteristics and credit market conditions interact and determine homeownership. The impact of the lifetime profile of resources on homeownership is larger when credit market imperfections are more severe. We combine data from the Bank of Italy's Survey on Household Income and Wealth with information on regional differences in interest rate spreads. We find that an increase in current resources by 10,000 euros increases the probability of homeownership by five (two) percentage points under the least (most) favourable credit market conditions.","PeriodicalId":18164,"journal":{"name":"Macroeconomics: National Income & Product Accounts eJournal","volume":"50 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2016-12-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"77516042","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2
Russian Industry in H1 2016: Zero Dynamics 2016年上半年俄罗斯工业:零动态
Pub Date : 2016-09-22 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.2842173
A. Kaukin, G. Idrisov
The trend that first became visible in early 2016 – decline giving way to zero rates of growth – towards the end of H1 had spread across a majority of segments of the economy’s real sector. The lack of a noticeable domestic demand and dependence upon foreign equipment supplies coupled with the persistently low relative income generated by exports of raw materials make it impossible to expect any significant domestic production growth in the nearest future.
2016年初首次显现出来的趋势——经济下滑让位于零增长——在上半年末已经蔓延到实体经济的大部分领域。由于缺乏明显的国内需求和对外国设备供应的依赖,再加上原材料出口所产生的相对收入持续较低,因此不可能期望在最近的将来国内生产有任何显著的增长。
{"title":"Russian Industry in H1 2016: Zero Dynamics","authors":"A. Kaukin, G. Idrisov","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.2842173","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2842173","url":null,"abstract":"The trend that first became visible in early 2016 – decline giving way to zero rates of growth – towards the end of H1 had spread across a majority of segments of the economy’s real sector. The lack of a noticeable domestic demand and dependence upon foreign equipment supplies coupled with the persistently low relative income generated by exports of raw materials make it impossible to expect any significant domestic production growth in the nearest future.","PeriodicalId":18164,"journal":{"name":"Macroeconomics: National Income & Product Accounts eJournal","volume":"43 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2016-09-22","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"73999279","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Valuing 'Free' Media in GDP: An Experimental Approach 在GDP中评估“自由”媒体:一种实验性方法
Pub Date : 2016-08-05 DOI: 10.21799/FRBP.WP.2016.24
L. Nakamura, Jon D. Samuels, Rachel H. Soloveichik
“Free” consumer entertainment and information from the Internet, largely supported by advertising revenues, has had a major impact on consumer behavior. Some economists believe that measured gross domestic product (GDP) growth is badly underestimated because GDP excludes online entertainment (Brynjolfsson and Oh 2012; Ito 2013; Aeppel 2015). This paper introduces an experimental GDP methodology that includes advertising-supported media in both final output and business inputs. For example, Google Maps would be counted as final output when it is used by a consumer to plan vacation driving routes. On the other hand, the same website would be counted as a business input when it is used by a pizza restaurant to plan delivery routes. Contrary to critics of the U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA), the process of including “free” media in the input-output accounts has little impact on either GDP or total factor productivity (TFP). Between 1998 and 2012, measured nominal GDP growth falls 0.005% per year, real GDP growth rises 0.009% per year and TFP growth rises 0.016% per year. Between 1929 and 1998, measured nominal GDP growth rises 0.002% per year, real GDP growth falls 0.002% per year, and TFP growth rises 0.004% per year. These changes are not nearly enough to reverse the recent slowdown in growth. Our method for accounting for free media is production oriented in the sense that it is a measure of the resource input into the entertainment (or other content) of the medium rather than a measure of the consumer surplus arising from the content. The BEA uses a similar production-oriented approach when measuring GDP. In contrast, other researchers use broader approaches to measure value. Brynjolfsson and Oh (2012) attempt to capture some consumer surplus by measuring the time expended on the Internet. Varian (2009) argues that much of the value of the Internet is in time saving, an additional metric for capturing consumer surplus. The McKinsey Institute (Bughin et al. 2011) attempts to measure the productivity gain from search directly. In particular, this production-oriented accounting has no method to account for instances in which the good or service precedes the revenue that it eventually generates. Over the past two decades, many Silicon Valley firms have followed the disruptive business model described as URL: ubiquity now, revenue later. Some firms have been creating proprietary software or research, which is already captured in the national accounts as investment. Other firms have been creating intangible investments in open source software, customer networks and other organizational capital. Despite their long-run value, none of these intangible assets are currently captured in the national accounts as investment. If we treat these asset categories as capital, then the productivity boom from 1995 to 2000 becomes even stronger and the weak productivity growth of the past decade may be ameliorated somewhat.
来自互联网的“免费”消费者娱乐和信息,在很大程度上由广告收入支持,对消费者行为产生了重大影响。一些经济学家认为,衡量的国内生产总值(GDP)增长被严重低估了,因为GDP不包括在线娱乐(Brynjolfsson and Oh 2012;伊藤2013;Aeppel 2015)。本文介绍了一种实验性GDP方法,该方法将广告支持的媒体包括在最终产出和商业投入中。例如,当消费者使用谷歌地图来规划度假驾驶路线时,它将被视为最终输出。另一方面,同样的网站被比萨餐厅用来规划送货路线时,将被视为一项业务投入。与美国经济分析局(BEA)的批评者相反,将“自由”媒体纳入投入产出账户的过程对GDP或全要素生产率(TFP)几乎没有影响。1998年至2012年间,名义GDP增长率每年下降0.005%,实际GDP增长率每年上升0.009%,TFP增长率每年上升0.016%。1929年至1998年间,名义GDP增长率每年上升0.002%,实际GDP增长率每年下降0.002%,TFP增长率每年上升0.004%。这些变化远远不足以扭转最近的增长放缓。我们计算免费媒体的方法是以生产为导向的,因为它是对媒体娱乐(或其他内容)资源投入的衡量,而不是对内容产生的消费者剩余的衡量。经济分析局在衡量GDP时也采用了类似的以生产为导向的方法。相比之下,其他研究人员使用更广泛的方法来衡量价值。Brynjolfsson和Oh(2012)试图通过测量在互联网上花费的时间来捕获一些消费者剩余。瓦里安(2009)认为,互联网的大部分价值在于节省时间,这是捕获消费者剩余的额外指标。麦肯锡研究所(Bughin et al. 2011)试图直接衡量搜索带来的生产力收益。特别是,这种以生产为导向的会计没有办法说明商品或服务先于其最终产生的收入的情况。在过去的二十年里,许多硅谷公司都遵循着一种被称为URL的颠覆性商业模式:先普及,后创收。一些公司一直在开发专有软件或研究,这些已经作为投资计入国民账户。其他公司一直在对开源软件、客户网络和其他组织资本进行无形投资。尽管这些无形资产具有长期价值,但它们目前都没有作为投资计入国民账户。如果我们将这些资产类别视为资本,那么1995年至2000年的生产率繁荣将变得更加强劲,过去十年的生产率增长疲软可能会有所改善。
{"title":"Valuing 'Free' Media in GDP: An Experimental Approach","authors":"L. Nakamura, Jon D. Samuels, Rachel H. Soloveichik","doi":"10.21799/FRBP.WP.2016.24","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.21799/FRBP.WP.2016.24","url":null,"abstract":"“Free” consumer entertainment and information from the Internet, largely supported by advertising revenues, has had a major impact on consumer behavior. Some economists believe that measured gross domestic product (GDP) growth is badly underestimated because GDP excludes online entertainment (Brynjolfsson and Oh 2012; Ito 2013; Aeppel 2015). This paper introduces an experimental GDP methodology that includes advertising-supported media in both final output and business inputs. For example, Google Maps would be counted as final output when it is used by a consumer to plan vacation driving routes. On the other hand, the same website would be counted as a business input when it is used by a pizza restaurant to plan delivery routes. Contrary to critics of the U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA), the process of including “free” media in the input-output accounts has little impact on either GDP or total factor productivity (TFP). Between 1998 and 2012, measured nominal GDP growth falls 0.005% per year, real GDP growth rises 0.009% per year and TFP growth rises 0.016% per year. Between 1929 and 1998, measured nominal GDP growth rises 0.002% per year, real GDP growth falls 0.002% per year, and TFP growth rises 0.004% per year. These changes are not nearly enough to reverse the recent slowdown in growth. Our method for accounting for free media is production oriented in the sense that it is a measure of the resource input into the entertainment (or other content) of the medium rather than a measure of the consumer surplus arising from the content. The BEA uses a similar production-oriented approach when measuring GDP. In contrast, other researchers use broader approaches to measure value. Brynjolfsson and Oh (2012) attempt to capture some consumer surplus by measuring the time expended on the Internet. Varian (2009) argues that much of the value of the Internet is in time saving, an additional metric for capturing consumer surplus. The McKinsey Institute (Bughin et al. 2011) attempts to measure the productivity gain from search directly. In particular, this production-oriented accounting has no method to account for instances in which the good or service precedes the revenue that it eventually generates. Over the past two decades, many Silicon Valley firms have followed the disruptive business model described as URL: ubiquity now, revenue later. Some firms have been creating proprietary software or research, which is already captured in the national accounts as investment. Other firms have been creating intangible investments in open source software, customer networks and other organizational capital. Despite their long-run value, none of these intangible assets are currently captured in the national accounts as investment. If we treat these asset categories as capital, then the productivity boom from 1995 to 2000 becomes even stronger and the weak productivity growth of the past decade may be ameliorated somewhat.","PeriodicalId":18164,"journal":{"name":"Macroeconomics: National Income & Product Accounts eJournal","volume":"16 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2016-08-05","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"87030142","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 17
Adjusting the External Adjustment: Cyclical Factors and the Italian Current Account 调整外部调整:周期性因素与意大利经常账户
Pub Date : 2016-07-21 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.2863912
S. Fabiani, Stefano Federico, Alberto Felettigh
We investigate the role of cyclical factors in the adjustment of Italy’s external balance from 2010, developing a model that infers the potential levels of domestic demand and of imports and exports from an exogenous measure of potential output, in an internally coherent fashion and also taking composition effects into account. According to our results, in 2015 Italy’s cyclically-adjusted current account surplus came to about 0.5 percentage points of GDP; the overall external rebalancing of the Italian economy has largely been of a non-cyclical nature, with a positive contribution from the decline in the prices of energy commodities. By applying our methodology to the other major euro-area countries, we find that current account imbalances over the recent period are amplified when assessed in cyclically-adjusted terms.
我们研究了2010年以来周期性因素在意大利外部平衡调整中的作用,开发了一个模型,该模型以内部一致的方式,从潜在产出的外生度量中推断出国内需求和进出口的潜在水平,并考虑了构成效应。根据我们的研究结果,2015年,意大利经周期调整的经常账户盈余约占GDP的0.5个百分点;意大利经济的整体外部再平衡在很大程度上是非周期性的,能源大宗商品价格的下跌起到了积极的作用。通过将我们的方法应用于其他主要欧元区国家,我们发现,在经周期调整的条件下,最近一段时间的经常账户失衡被放大了。
{"title":"Adjusting the External Adjustment: Cyclical Factors and the Italian Current Account","authors":"S. Fabiani, Stefano Federico, Alberto Felettigh","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.2863912","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2863912","url":null,"abstract":"We investigate the role of cyclical factors in the adjustment of Italy’s external balance from 2010, developing a model that infers the potential levels of domestic demand and of imports and exports from an exogenous measure of potential output, in an internally coherent fashion and also taking composition effects into account. According to our results, in 2015 Italy’s cyclically-adjusted current account surplus came to about 0.5 percentage points of GDP; the overall external rebalancing of the Italian economy has largely been of a non-cyclical nature, with a positive contribution from the decline in the prices of energy commodities. By applying our methodology to the other major euro-area countries, we find that current account imbalances over the recent period are amplified when assessed in cyclically-adjusted terms.","PeriodicalId":18164,"journal":{"name":"Macroeconomics: National Income & Product Accounts eJournal","volume":"43 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2016-07-21","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"75469897","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 7
Herausforderungen Bei Der Messung von Wohlfahrt (Challenges of Welfare Measurement) 制定福利措施
Pub Date : 2016-07-01 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.2812020
Beate R. Jochimsen, Christian Raffer
German Abstract: Initiiert von einer lebhaften oeffentlichen und wissenschaftlichen Debatte um die Eignung des Bruttoinlandsprodukts als Indikator fur materiellen Wohlstand sind zahlreiche alternative Masse zur Wohlstands- und Wohlfahrtsmessung entwickelt worden. Faellt dabei die Wahl auf einen Indikatorensatz, ist die Bestimmung der optimalen Anzahl der Indikatoren eine zentrale Herausforderung. Je mehr Indikatoren ausgewaehlt werden, desto besser koennen zwar die Bestandteile der Wohlfahrt abgebildet werden, desto schlechter ist aber die Kommunizierbarkeit. Beate Jochimsen und Christian Raffer analysieren mit Hilfe mehrerer statistischer Methoden die Verbindungen der 10 W³-Leitindikatoren des Deutschen Bundestages untereinander. Es zeigt sich, dass – je nach Messverfahren – drei bis sechs dieser Indikatoren ohne grossen Informationsverlust weggelassen werden koennen, da sie mit den verbleibenden eng korreliert sind. Ein kleiner W³-Indikatorensatz koennte wesentlich leichter erklaert und kommuniziert werden. Im Ergebnis bedeutet dies, dass der Umfang aller nationaler und internationaler Indikatorensaetze zur Wohlfahrtsmessung kritisch zu wuerdigen ist.English Abstract: Triggered by the lively public and academic debate on the gross domestic product as welfare indicator numerous alternative welfare measurements emerged. If a set of indicators as welfare measurement is chosen the identification of an optimal number of indicators is a challenging question. The more indicators are included in the set the more comprehensive welfare can be mapped, thus, the more complicated is the communication of results. Based on several statistical methods Beate Jochimsen and Christian Raffer analyze the linkage of the ten W³-Indicators which the German Bundestag developed. They find that – depending on the statistical method – between three and six of those ten indicators could be easily excluded as they are closely correlated with the remaining ones. A smaller set of W³-Indicators could be explained far easier to the public. This result suggests to critically evaluate the number of indicators in various welfare measures onnational and international level.
戴曼抽象:针对国内生产总值作为物质繁荣指标的戏剧性的开启和科学辩论已经发展出针对繁荣和福利测量的大量替代性物质。这套指标很有用,即确定最佳指标数目是关键挑战。提到的指标越多,虽然可以越好了解福利的构成部分,但资讯的可见度却越低。贝亚特Jochimsen克里斯汀Raffer利用多个分析统计方法联系10 W³互相联邦议院的-Leitindikatoren .根据测量方法,3到6个这些指标可以消除,而信息也可以减少,因为它们与剩下的指标密切相关。小W³-Indikatorensatz可以大大简化erklaert和沟通将.结果,这意味着这套国家指标和这套国际指标的范围已逼无措,这套指标可用来测量福利。lively民意和当地知识小组决定实施重新编制了《生境指标》,对生境最佳数的列报也相应列报。越来越多的生境者被列入了越来越完整的世界记录,他们收到了越来越复杂的效益。根据on several statistical methods贝亚特Jochimsen and Christian Raffer analyze the linkage《W 10³-Indicators基本写照德国议院developed .他们查明了他们对生境办法的统计办法得出的结论是他们列显着对他们的沉默。A smaller拍摄《W³-Indicators能所explained远方easier to the公共.他们列报了《生境效益指标评价》在汇报和国际一级的需要
{"title":"Herausforderungen Bei Der Messung von Wohlfahrt (Challenges of Welfare Measurement)","authors":"Beate R. Jochimsen, Christian Raffer","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.2812020","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.2812020","url":null,"abstract":"German Abstract: Initiiert von einer lebhaften oeffentlichen und wissenschaftlichen Debatte um die Eignung des Bruttoinlandsprodukts als Indikator fur materiellen Wohlstand sind zahlreiche alternative Masse zur Wohlstands- und Wohlfahrtsmessung entwickelt worden. Faellt dabei die Wahl auf einen Indikatorensatz, ist die Bestimmung der optimalen Anzahl der Indikatoren eine zentrale Herausforderung. Je mehr Indikatoren ausgewaehlt werden, desto besser koennen zwar die Bestandteile der Wohlfahrt abgebildet werden, desto schlechter ist aber die Kommunizierbarkeit. Beate Jochimsen und Christian Raffer analysieren mit Hilfe mehrerer statistischer Methoden die Verbindungen der 10 W³-Leitindikatoren des Deutschen Bundestages untereinander. Es zeigt sich, dass – je nach Messverfahren – drei bis sechs dieser Indikatoren ohne grossen Informationsverlust weggelassen werden koennen, da sie mit den verbleibenden eng korreliert sind. Ein kleiner W³-Indikatorensatz koennte wesentlich leichter erklaert und kommuniziert werden. Im Ergebnis bedeutet dies, dass der Umfang aller nationaler und internationaler Indikatorensaetze zur Wohlfahrtsmessung kritisch zu wuerdigen ist.English Abstract: Triggered by the lively public and academic debate on the gross domestic product as welfare indicator numerous alternative welfare measurements emerged. If a set of indicators as welfare measurement is chosen the identification of an optimal number of indicators is a challenging question. The more indicators are included in the set the more comprehensive welfare can be mapped, thus, the more complicated is the communication of results. Based on several statistical methods Beate Jochimsen and Christian Raffer analyze the linkage of the ten W³-Indicators which the German Bundestag developed. They find that – depending on the statistical method – between three and six of those ten indicators could be easily excluded as they are closely correlated with the remaining ones. A smaller set of W³-Indicators could be explained far easier to the public. This result suggests to critically evaluate the number of indicators in various welfare measures onnational and international level.","PeriodicalId":18164,"journal":{"name":"Macroeconomics: National Income & Product Accounts eJournal","volume":"273 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2016-07-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"76814150","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Hirschman's Tunnel Effect Goes Abroad: International Dimensions of Social Comparison and Subjective Well-Being 赫希曼的隧道效应走向国外:社会比较与主观幸福感的国际维度
Pub Date : 2016-06-01 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3131660
Aart Gerritsen, Harald Lang
We i¬ nd evidence that individuals’ subjective well-being depends on the macroeconomic performance of other countries as well as that of their home country. Given the home country’s economic growth, an individual’s life satisfaction is positively associated with the economic growth of important trade partners. It is negatively associated with the economic growth of neighboring countries that engage in relatively little trade with the home country. Our i¬ ndings are consistent with individuals who care about their economic situation relative to that of people in other countries, but who at the same time anticipate positive spillovers from the economic performance of countries that share an important economic tie with their home country.
我们发现证据表明,个人的主观幸福感取决于其他国家以及他们本国的宏观经济表现。考虑到母国的经济增长,个人的生活满意度与重要贸易伙伴的经济增长呈正相关。它与邻国的经济增长呈负相关,这些国家与母国的贸易相对较少。我们的研究结果与一些人的看法一致,他们关心自己的经济状况,而不是其他国家的经济状况,但与此同时,他们也预期与本国有着重要经济联系的国家的经济表现会产生积极的溢出效应。
{"title":"Hirschman's Tunnel Effect Goes Abroad: International Dimensions of Social Comparison and Subjective Well-Being","authors":"Aart Gerritsen, Harald Lang","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3131660","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3131660","url":null,"abstract":"We i¬ nd evidence that individuals’ subjective well-being depends on the macroeconomic performance of other countries as well as that of their home country. Given the home country’s economic growth, an individual’s life satisfaction is positively associated with the economic growth of important trade partners. It is negatively associated with the economic growth of neighboring countries that engage in relatively little trade with the home country. Our i¬ ndings are consistent with individuals who care about their economic situation relative to that of people in other countries, but who at the same time anticipate positive spillovers from the economic performance of countries that share an important economic tie with their home country.","PeriodicalId":18164,"journal":{"name":"Macroeconomics: National Income & Product Accounts eJournal","volume":"39 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2016-06-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"86338663","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Prosperity, Sustainability and the Measurement of Wealth 繁荣,可持续性和财富的衡量
Pub Date : 2016-05-01 DOI: 10.1002/app5.132
K. Mumford
Gross domestic product (GDP) and household income measures provide invaluable metrics of economic activity in an economy, but they tell us little about the sustainability of the economic trends. National wealth accounting can be utilised to determine the size of the underlying productive base, which provides insight into the sustainability of economic activities and indicates the potential for intergenerational well-being. An empirical methodology was developed to measure wealth and then used to analyse multiple Asian countries. A common theme found across the Asian countries was the depletion of natural capital (forests, minerals and energy) and the development of human and produced capital. A strong correlation between growth in GDP per capita and wealth per capita was also found, but there are instances of GDP growth and wealth growth having different signs.
国内生产总值(GDP)和家庭收入指标为一个经济体的经济活动提供了宝贵的衡量标准,但它们对经济趋势的可持续性知之甚少。国民财富核算可以用来确定潜在生产基础的规模,这可以深入了解经济活动的可持续性,并表明代际福利的潜力。研究人员开发了一种实证方法来衡量财富,然后将其用于分析多个亚洲国家。亚洲各国的共同主题是自然资本(森林、矿产和能源)的枯竭以及人力和生产资本的发展。人均GDP增长和人均财富增长之间也存在很强的相关性,但也有GDP增长和财富增长具有不同迹象的例子。
{"title":"Prosperity, Sustainability and the Measurement of Wealth","authors":"K. Mumford","doi":"10.1002/app5.132","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1002/app5.132","url":null,"abstract":"Gross domestic product (GDP) and household income measures provide invaluable metrics of economic activity in an economy, but they tell us little about the sustainability of the economic trends. National wealth accounting can be utilised to determine the size of the underlying productive base, which provides insight into the sustainability of economic activities and indicates the potential for intergenerational well-being. An empirical methodology was developed to measure wealth and then used to analyse multiple Asian countries. A common theme found across the Asian countries was the depletion of natural capital (forests, minerals and energy) and the development of human and produced capital. A strong correlation between growth in GDP per capita and wealth per capita was also found, but there are instances of GDP growth and wealth growth having different signs.","PeriodicalId":18164,"journal":{"name":"Macroeconomics: National Income & Product Accounts eJournal","volume":"20 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2016-05-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"78840656","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 27
Did TARP Distort Competition Among Sound Unsupported Banks? 问题资产救助计划是否扭曲了健康的无支持银行之间的竞争?
Pub Date : 2016-04-01 DOI: 10.1111/ecin.12281
M. Koetter, Felix Noth
This study investigates if the Troubled Asset Relief Program (TARP) distorted price competition in U.S. banking. Political indicators reveal bailout expectations after 2009, manifested as beliefs about the predicted probability of receiving equity support relative to failing during the TARP disbursement period. In addition, the TARP affected the competitive conduct of unsupported banks after the program stopped in the fourth quarter of 2009. Loan rates were higher, and the risk premium required by depositors was lower for banks with higher bailout expectations. The interest margins of unsupported banks increased in the immediate aftermath of the TARP disbursement but not after 2010. No effects emerged for loan or deposit growth, which suggests that protected banks did not increase their market shares at the expense of less protected banks.
本研究探讨问题资产救助计划(TARP)是否扭曲了美国银行业的价格竞争。政治指标揭示了2009年之后的救助预期,表现为对在问题资产救助计划(TARP)发放期间获得股权支持相对于失败的预测概率的信念。此外,问题资产救助计划在2009年第四季度停止后,影响了没有得到支持的银行的竞争行为。对于救助预期较高的银行,贷款利率较高,储户要求的风险溢价较低。在问题资产救助计划(TARP)发放后不久,未得到支持的银行的息差有所增加,但在2010年之后就没有了。贷款或存款增长没有受到影响,这表明受保护的银行并没有以牺牲受保护程度较低的银行为代价来增加市场份额。
{"title":"Did TARP Distort Competition Among Sound Unsupported Banks?","authors":"M. Koetter, Felix Noth","doi":"10.1111/ecin.12281","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1111/ecin.12281","url":null,"abstract":"This study investigates if the Troubled Asset Relief Program (TARP) distorted price competition in U.S. banking. Political indicators reveal bailout expectations after 2009, manifested as beliefs about the predicted probability of receiving equity support relative to failing during the TARP disbursement period. In addition, the TARP affected the competitive conduct of unsupported banks after the program stopped in the fourth quarter of 2009. Loan rates were higher, and the risk premium required by depositors was lower for banks with higher bailout expectations. The interest margins of unsupported banks increased in the immediate aftermath of the TARP disbursement but not after 2010. No effects emerged for loan or deposit growth, which suggests that protected banks did not increase their market shares at the expense of less protected banks.","PeriodicalId":18164,"journal":{"name":"Macroeconomics: National Income & Product Accounts eJournal","volume":"19 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2016-04-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"90289516","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 24
期刊
Macroeconomics: National Income & Product Accounts eJournal
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1