首页 > 最新文献

Oxford Research Encyclopedia of Economics and Finance最新文献

英文 中文
Studying Long-Term Changes in the Economy and Society Using the HISCO Family of Occupational Measures 用HISCO家族职业测度研究经济社会的长期变化
Pub Date : 2020-05-29 DOI: 10.1093/acrefore/9780190625979.013.541
Marco H. D. van Leeuwen
Occupations are a key characteristic for analyzing momentous changes in economy and society. Classical economists rooted their analyses in occupational divisions, emphasizing the division of work and its continuous evolution. Modern economists and economic historians also debate the wealth of nations by looking at the global changes in the labor force, at changing labor force participation rates, at winners and losers in the class structure, and in variations in this across the globe—stressing the importance of human capital for work and of changes therein for economic growth. To study such momentous changes over past centuries, historical occupational data are needed as well as measures and procedures to work with these data systematically and comparatively. The Historical International Standard Classification of Occupations (HISCO) maps occupational titles into a common coding scheme across the globe. HISCO-based measures of economic sector and economic specialization have been derived. To answer a number of interesting questions, the HISCO family has been extended to include HISCO-based measures of social status (HISCAM) and social classes (HISCLASS). Armed with his toolbox, scholars are able to study the development of the economy and society over past centuries.
职业是分析经济和社会重大变化的关键特征。古典经济学家的分析植根于职业分工,强调分工及其持续演变。现代经济学家和经济历史学家还通过观察劳动力的全球变化、劳动力参与率的变化、阶级结构中的赢家和输家,以及全球范围内的变化来讨论国家财富——强调人力资本对工作的重要性,以及其中的变化对经济增长的重要性。为了研究过去几个世纪的这些重大变化,需要历史的职业数据,以及系统地、比较地处理这些数据的措施和程序。历史国际职业标准分类(HISCO)将职业名称映射到全球通用的编码方案中。以hisco为基础的经济部门和经济专业化措施已经推导出来。为了回答一些有趣的问题,HISCO家族已经扩展到包括基于HISCO的社会地位(HISCAM)和社会阶层(HISCLASS)的措施。有了他的工具箱,学者们就能够研究过去几个世纪的经济和社会发展。
{"title":"Studying Long-Term Changes in the Economy and Society Using the HISCO Family of Occupational Measures","authors":"Marco H. D. van Leeuwen","doi":"10.1093/acrefore/9780190625979.013.541","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1093/acrefore/9780190625979.013.541","url":null,"abstract":"Occupations are a key characteristic for analyzing momentous changes in economy and society. Classical economists rooted their analyses in occupational divisions, emphasizing the division of work and its continuous evolution. Modern economists and economic historians also debate the wealth of nations by looking at the global changes in the labor force, at changing labor force participation rates, at winners and losers in the class structure, and in variations in this across the globe—stressing the importance of human capital for work and of changes therein for economic growth. To study such momentous changes over past centuries, historical occupational data are needed as well as measures and procedures to work with these data systematically and comparatively. The Historical International Standard Classification of Occupations (HISCO) maps occupational titles into a common coding scheme across the globe. HISCO-based measures of economic sector and economic specialization have been derived. To answer a number of interesting questions, the HISCO family has been extended to include HISCO-based measures of social status (HISCAM) and social classes (HISCLASS). Armed with his toolbox, scholars are able to study the development of the economy and society over past centuries.","PeriodicalId":211658,"journal":{"name":"Oxford Research Encyclopedia of Economics and Finance","volume":"33 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2020-05-29","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"125353896","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2
The Protection of Intellectual Property in the Global Economy 全球经济中的知识产权保护
Pub Date : 2020-05-29 DOI: 10.1093/acrefore/9780190625979.013.444
Kamal Saggi, Olena Ivus
Longstanding international frictions over uneven levels of protection granted to intellectual property rights (IPR) in different parts of the world culminated in 1995 in the form of the Agreement on Trade Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS)—a multilateral trade agreement that all member countries of the World Trade Organization (WTO) are obligated to follow. This landmark agreement was controversial from the start since it required countries with dramatically different economic and technological capabilities to abide by essentially the same rules and regulations with respect to IPRs, with some temporary leeway granted to developing and least developed countries. As one might expect, developing countries objected to the agreement on philosophical and practical grounds while developed countries, especially the United States, championed it strongly. Over the years, a vast and rich economics literature has emerged that helps understand this international divide. More specifically, several fundamental issues related to the protection of IPRs in the global economy have been addressed: are IPRs trade-related? Do the incentives for patent protection of an open economy differ from those of a closed one and, if so, why? What is the rationale for international coordination over national patent policies? Why do developed and developing countries have such radically different views regarding the protection of IPRs? What is the level of empirical support underlying the major arguments for and against the TRIPS-mandated strengthening of IPRs in the world economy? Can the core obligations of the TRIPS Agreement as well as the flexibilities it contains be justified on the basis of economic logic? We discuss the key conclusions that can be drawn from decades of rigorous theoretical and empirical research and also offer some suggestions for future work.
世界不同地区对知识产权的保护水平参差不齐的长期国际摩擦在1995年以《与贸易有关的知识产权协定》(TRIPS)的形式达到顶峰。TRIPS是世界贸易组织(WTO)所有成员国都有义务遵守的多边贸易协定。这项具有里程碑意义的协议从一开始就存在争议,因为它要求经济和技术能力截然不同的国家在知识产权方面遵守基本相同的规则和条例,并给予发展中国家和最不发达国家一些临时的回旋余地。正如人们所预料的那样,发展中国家出于哲学和实践的考虑反对该协议,而发达国家,尤其是美国,则强烈支持该协议。多年来,出现了大量丰富的经济学文献,有助于理解这种国际鸿沟。更具体地说,讨论了与全球经济中知识产权保护有关的几个基本问题:知识产权与贸易有关吗?开放经济体的专利保护动机与封闭经济体不同吗?如果不同,原因何在?对国家专利政策进行国际协调的理由是什么?为什么发达国家和发展中国家对知识产权的保护有着如此截然不同的看法?支持和反对《与贸易有关的知识产权协定》要求在世界经济中加强知识产权的主要论点的经验支持程度如何?《与贸易有关的知识产权协定》的核心义务及其所包含的灵活性能否在经济逻辑的基础上得到证明?我们讨论了几十年来严格的理论和实证研究得出的关键结论,并对未来的工作提出了一些建议。
{"title":"The Protection of Intellectual Property in the Global Economy","authors":"Kamal Saggi, Olena Ivus","doi":"10.1093/acrefore/9780190625979.013.444","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1093/acrefore/9780190625979.013.444","url":null,"abstract":"Longstanding international frictions over uneven levels of protection granted to intellectual property rights (IPR) in different parts of the world culminated in 1995 in the form of the Agreement on Trade Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS)—a multilateral trade agreement that all member countries of the World Trade Organization (WTO) are obligated to follow. This landmark agreement was controversial from the start since it required countries with dramatically different economic and technological capabilities to abide by essentially the same rules and regulations with respect to IPRs, with some temporary leeway granted to developing and least developed countries. As one might expect, developing countries objected to the agreement on philosophical and practical grounds while developed countries, especially the United States, championed it strongly.\u0000 Over the years, a vast and rich economics literature has emerged that helps understand this international divide. More specifically, several fundamental issues related to the protection of IPRs in the global economy have been addressed: are IPRs trade-related? Do the incentives for patent protection of an open economy differ from those of a closed one and, if so, why? What is the rationale for international coordination over national patent policies? Why do developed and developing countries have such radically different views regarding the protection of IPRs? What is the level of empirical support underlying the major arguments for and against the TRIPS-mandated strengthening of IPRs in the world economy? Can the core obligations of the TRIPS Agreement as well as the flexibilities it contains be justified on the basis of economic logic? We discuss the key conclusions that can be drawn from decades of rigorous theoretical and empirical research and also offer some suggestions for future work.","PeriodicalId":211658,"journal":{"name":"Oxford Research Encyclopedia of Economics and Finance","volume":"1 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2020-05-29","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"130604865","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 5
Guilds and the Economy 行会与经济
Pub Date : 2020-05-29 DOI: 10.1093/acrefore/9780190625979.013.538
Sheilagh Ogilvie
Guilds ruled many European crafts and trades from the Middle Ages to the Industrial Revolution. Each guild regulated entry to its occupation, requiring any practitioner to become a guild member and then limiting admission to the guild. Guilds intervened in the markets for their members’ products, striving to keep prices high, limit output, suppress competition, and block innovations that might disrupt the status quo. Guilds also acted in input markets, seeking to control access to raw materials, keep wages low, hinder employers from competing for workers, and prevent workers from agitating for better conditions. Guilds treated women particularly severely, usually excluding them from apprenticeship and forbidding any female other than a guild member’s widow from running a workshop. Guilds invested large sums in lobbying governments and political elites to grant, maintain, and extend these privileges. Guilds had the potential to compensate for their cartelistic activities by creating countervailing benefits. Guild quality certification was one possible solution to information asymmetries between producers and consumers, which could have made markets work better. Guild apprenticeship had the potential to solve imperfections in markets for skilled training, and thus to encourage human capital investment. The cartel profits generated by guilds could in theory have encouraged technological innovation by enabling guild masters to appropriate more of the social benefits of their innovations, while guild journeymanship and spatial clustering could diffuse new technical knowledge. A rich scholarship on European guilds makes it possible to assess the degree to which guilds created such benefits, outweighing the harm they caused. After about 1500, guild strength diverged across Europe, declining gradually in Flanders, the Netherlands, and England, surviving in France and Italy, and intensifying across large tracts of Iberia, Scandinavia, and the German-speaking lands. The activities of guilds contributed to variations across Europe in economic performance, urban growth, and inequality. Guilds interacted significantly with both markets and states, which helps explain why European economies diverged in the crucial centuries before industrialization.
从中世纪到工业革命,行会统治着欧洲的许多手工业和贸易。每个行会对其职业的进入都有规定,要求任何从业者成为行会成员,然后限制进入行会。行会为其成员的产品干预市场,努力保持高价格,限制产量,抑制竞争,并阻止可能破坏现状的创新。行会还在投入市场中发挥作用,试图控制原材料的获取,保持低工资,阻碍雇主争夺工人,阻止工人争取更好的工作条件。行会对女性的待遇尤为苛刻,通常不让她们当学徒,除了行会成员的遗孀之外,禁止任何女性经营车间。行会投入大量资金游说政府和政治精英,以授予、维持和扩大这些特权。行会有可能通过创造抵消性利益来补偿他们的卡特尔活动。协会质量认证是解决生产者和消费者之间信息不对称的一个可能的解决方案,它可以使市场更好地运作。行会学徒制有可能解决技能培训市场的缺陷,从而鼓励人力资本投资。从理论上讲,公会产生的卡特尔利润可以鼓励技术创新,使公会的主人能够从他们的创新中获得更多的社会利益,而公会的旅行和空间集群可以传播新的技术知识。对欧洲行会的大量研究使我们有可能评估行会在多大程度上创造了这些利益,而不是它们造成的伤害。大约1500年后,行会的力量在欧洲各地分化,在佛兰德斯、荷兰和英格兰逐渐衰落,在法国和意大利幸存下来,在伊比利亚半岛、斯堪的纳维亚半岛和德语地区的大片地区加强。行会的活动导致了整个欧洲在经济表现、城市发展和不平等方面的差异。行会与市场和国家都有重要的互动,这有助于解释为什么欧洲经济在工业化前的关键世纪出现了分歧。
{"title":"Guilds and the Economy","authors":"Sheilagh Ogilvie","doi":"10.1093/acrefore/9780190625979.013.538","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1093/acrefore/9780190625979.013.538","url":null,"abstract":"Guilds ruled many European crafts and trades from the Middle Ages to the Industrial Revolution. Each guild regulated entry to its occupation, requiring any practitioner to become a guild member and then limiting admission to the guild. Guilds intervened in the markets for their members’ products, striving to keep prices high, limit output, suppress competition, and block innovations that might disrupt the status quo. Guilds also acted in input markets, seeking to control access to raw materials, keep wages low, hinder employers from competing for workers, and prevent workers from agitating for better conditions. Guilds treated women particularly severely, usually excluding them from apprenticeship and forbidding any female other than a guild member’s widow from running a workshop. Guilds invested large sums in lobbying governments and political elites to grant, maintain, and extend these privileges.\u0000 Guilds had the potential to compensate for their cartelistic activities by creating countervailing benefits. Guild quality certification was one possible solution to information asymmetries between producers and consumers, which could have made markets work better. Guild apprenticeship had the potential to solve imperfections in markets for skilled training, and thus to encourage human capital investment. The cartel profits generated by guilds could in theory have encouraged technological innovation by enabling guild masters to appropriate more of the social benefits of their innovations, while guild journeymanship and spatial clustering could diffuse new technical knowledge. A rich scholarship on European guilds makes it possible to assess the degree to which guilds created such benefits, outweighing the harm they caused.\u0000 After about 1500, guild strength diverged across Europe, declining gradually in Flanders, the Netherlands, and England, surviving in France and Italy, and intensifying across large tracts of Iberia, Scandinavia, and the German-speaking lands. The activities of guilds contributed to variations across Europe in economic performance, urban growth, and inequality. Guilds interacted significantly with both markets and states, which helps explain why European economies diverged in the crucial centuries before industrialization.","PeriodicalId":211658,"journal":{"name":"Oxford Research Encyclopedia of Economics and Finance","volume":"32 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2020-05-29","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"116678798","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
The State of DSGE Modeling DSGE建模的现状
Pub Date : 2020-04-30 DOI: 10.1093/acrefore/9780190625979.013.403
P. Levine
Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) modeling can be structured around six key criticisms leveled at the approach. The first is fundamental and common to macroeconomics and microeconomics alike—namely, problems with rationality and expected utility maximization (EUM). The second is that DSGE models examine fluctuations about an exogenous balanced growth path and there is no role for endogenous growth. The third consists of a number of concerns associated with estimation. The fourth is another fundamental problem with any micro-founded macro-model—that of heterogeneity and aggregation. The fifth and sixth concern focus on the rudimentary nature of earlier models that lacked unemployment and a banking sector. A widely used and referenced example of DSGE modeling is the Smets-Wouters (SW) medium-sized NK model. The model features rational expectations and, in an environment of uncertainty, EUM by households and firms. Preferences are consistent with a nonstochastic exogenous balanced growth path about which the model is solved. The model can be estimated by a Bayesian systems estimation method that involves four types of representative agents (households, final goods producers, trade unions, and intermediate good producers). The latter two produce differentiated labor and goods, respectively, and, in each period of time, consist of a proportion locked into existing contracts and the rest that can reoptimize. There is underemployment but no unemployment. Finally, an arbitrage condition imposed on the return on capital and bonds rules out financial frictions. Thus the model, which has become the gold standard for DSGE macro-modeling, features all six areas of concern. The model can be used as a platform to examine how the current generation of DSGE models has developed in these six dimensions. This modeling framework has also used for macro-economic policy design.
动态随机一般均衡(DSGE)建模可以围绕针对该方法的六个关键批评进行构建。第一个问题是宏观经济学和微观经济学的基本问题,即理性和预期效用最大化(EUM)问题。第二,DSGE模型考察的是外源性平衡增长路径的波动,而内源性增长没有作用。第三个由许多与评估相关的关注点组成。第四个问题是任何微观宏观模型的另一个基本问题——异质性和聚集性。第五个和第六个担忧集中在缺乏失业和银行业的早期模型的基本性质上。DSGE建模的一个广泛使用和参考的例子是Smets-Wouters (SW)中型NK模型。该模型以家庭和企业的理性预期和在不确定环境下的EUM为特征。偏好与模型求解的非随机外生平衡增长路径一致。该模型可以通过贝叶斯系统估计方法进行估计,该方法涉及四种类型的代表性代理人(家庭,最终产品生产者,工会和中间产品生产者)。后两者分别生产差异化的劳动力和商品,并且在每一段时间内,由固定在现有合同中的比例和可以重新优化的剩余比例组成。有就业不足,但没有失业。最后,对资本和债券回报施加的套利条件排除了金融摩擦。因此,该模型已成为DSGE宏观建模的黄金标准,它包含了所有六个关注领域。该模型可以作为一个平台来研究当前一代的DSGE模型在这六个维度上是如何发展的。这种建模框架也被用于宏观经济政策设计。
{"title":"The State of DSGE Modeling","authors":"P. Levine","doi":"10.1093/acrefore/9780190625979.013.403","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1093/acrefore/9780190625979.013.403","url":null,"abstract":"Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) modeling can be structured around six key criticisms leveled at the approach. The first is fundamental and common to macroeconomics and microeconomics alike—namely, problems with rationality and expected utility maximization (EUM). The second is that DSGE models examine fluctuations about an exogenous balanced growth path and there is no role for endogenous growth. The third consists of a number of concerns associated with estimation. The fourth is another fundamental problem with any micro-founded macro-model—that of heterogeneity and aggregation. The fifth and sixth concern focus on the rudimentary nature of earlier models that lacked unemployment and a banking sector.\u0000 A widely used and referenced example of DSGE modeling is the Smets-Wouters (SW) medium-sized NK model. The model features rational expectations and, in an environment of uncertainty, EUM by households and firms. Preferences are consistent with a nonstochastic exogenous balanced growth path about which the model is solved. The model can be estimated by a Bayesian systems estimation method that involves four types of representative agents (households, final goods producers, trade unions, and intermediate good producers). The latter two produce differentiated labor and goods, respectively, and, in each period of time, consist of a proportion locked into existing contracts and the rest that can reoptimize. There is underemployment but no unemployment. Finally, an arbitrage condition imposed on the return on capital and bonds rules out financial frictions. Thus the model, which has become the gold standard for DSGE macro-modeling, features all six areas of concern. The model can be used as a platform to examine how the current generation of DSGE models has developed in these six dimensions. This modeling framework has also used for macro-economic policy design.","PeriodicalId":211658,"journal":{"name":"Oxford Research Encyclopedia of Economics and Finance","volume":"50 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2020-04-30","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"133944112","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Financial Inclusion and Human Development 普惠金融与人类发展
Pub Date : 2020-03-31 DOI: 10.1093/acrefore/9780190625979.013.354
María Soledad Martínez Pería, M. Shin
The link between financial inclusion and human development is examined here. Using cross-country data, the behavior of variables that try to capture these concepts is examined and preliminary evidence of a positive association is offered. However, because establishing a causal relationship with macro-data is difficult, a thorough review of the literature on the impact of financial inclusion, focusing on micro-studies that can better address identification is conducted. The literature generally distinguishes between different dimensions of financial inclusion: access to credit, access to bank branches, and access to saving instruments (i.e., accounts). Despite promising results from a first wave of studies, the impact of expanding access to credit seems limited at best, with little evidence of transformative effects on human development outcomes. While there is more promising evidence on the impact of expanding access to bank branches and formal saving instruments, studies show that some interventions such as one-time account opening subsidies are unlikely to have a sizable impact on social and economic outcomes. Instead well-designed interventions catering to individuals’ specific needs in different contexts seem to be required to realize the full potential of formal financial services to enrich human lives.
本文探讨了普惠金融与人类发展之间的联系。利用跨国数据,研究了试图捕捉这些概念的变量的行为,并提供了积极关联的初步证据。然而,由于与宏观数据建立因果关系是困难的,因此我们对有关普惠金融影响的文献进行了全面的回顾,重点关注能够更好地解决识别问题的微观研究。文献一般区分了金融普惠的不同维度:获得信贷、获得银行分支机构和获得储蓄工具(即账户)。尽管第一波研究取得了令人鼓舞的结果,但扩大获得信贷的机会的影响似乎充其量是有限的,几乎没有证据表明它对人类发展结果产生了变革性影响。虽然有更有希望的证据表明,扩大银行网点和正式储蓄工具的使用范围会产生影响,但研究表明,一些干预措施,如一次性开户补贴,不太可能对社会和经济结果产生重大影响。相反,要充分发挥正规金融服务丰富人类生活的潜力,似乎需要精心设计的干预措施,以满足个人在不同背景下的具体需求。
{"title":"Financial Inclusion and Human Development","authors":"María Soledad Martínez Pería, M. Shin","doi":"10.1093/acrefore/9780190625979.013.354","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1093/acrefore/9780190625979.013.354","url":null,"abstract":"The link between financial inclusion and human development is examined here. Using cross-country data, the behavior of variables that try to capture these concepts is examined and preliminary evidence of a positive association is offered. However, because establishing a causal relationship with macro-data is difficult, a thorough review of the literature on the impact of financial inclusion, focusing on micro-studies that can better address identification is conducted. The literature generally distinguishes between different dimensions of financial inclusion: access to credit, access to bank branches, and access to saving instruments (i.e., accounts). Despite promising results from a first wave of studies, the impact of expanding access to credit seems limited at best, with little evidence of transformative effects on human development outcomes. While there is more promising evidence on the impact of expanding access to bank branches and formal saving instruments, studies show that some interventions such as one-time account opening subsidies are unlikely to have a sizable impact on social and economic outcomes. Instead well-designed interventions catering to individuals’ specific needs in different contexts seem to be required to realize the full potential of formal financial services to enrich human lives.","PeriodicalId":211658,"journal":{"name":"Oxford Research Encyclopedia of Economics and Finance","volume":"30 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2020-03-31","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"121839038","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Markov Switching 马尔可夫切换
Pub Date : 2020-02-10 DOI: 10.1093/acrefore/9780190625979.013.174
Yong Song, T. Wo'zniak
Markov switching models are a family of models that introduces time variation in the parameters in the form of their state, or regime-specific values. This time variation is governed by a latent discrete-valued stochastic process with limited memory. More specifically, the current value of the state indicator is determined by the value of the state indicator from the previous period only implying the Markov property. A transition matrix characterizes the properties of the Markov process by determining with what probability each of the states can be visited next period conditionally on the state in the current period. This setup decides on the two main advantages of the Markov switching models: the estimation of the probability of state occurrences in each of the sample periods by using filtering and smoothing methods and the estimation of the state-specific parameters. These two features open the possibility for interpretations of the parameters associated with specific regimes combined with the corresponding regime probabilities. The most commonly applied models from this family are those that presume a finite number of regimes and the exogeneity of the Markov process, which is defined as its independence from the model’s unpredictable innovations. In many such applications, the desired properties of the Markov switching model have been obtained either by imposing appropriate restrictions on transition probabilities or by introducing the time dependence of these probabilities determined by explanatory variables or functions of the state indicator. One of the extensions of this basic specification includes infinite hidden Markov models that provide great flexibility and excellent forecasting performance by allowing the number of states to go to infinity. Another extension, the endogenous Markov switching model, explicitly relates the state indicator to the model’s innovations, making it more interpretable and offering promising avenues for development.
马尔可夫切换模型是一类以状态或特定状态值的形式在参数中引入时间变化的模型。这种时间变化是由一个具有有限记忆的潜在离散值随机过程控制的。更具体地说,状态指标的当前值是由前一时期的状态指标的值决定的,这只意味着马尔可夫属性。转移矩阵通过确定每个状态在当前周期的状态下有条件地在下一周期访问的概率来表征马尔可夫过程的特性。这种设置决定了马尔可夫切换模型的两个主要优点:通过使用滤波和平滑方法估计每个样本周期中状态发生的概率,以及估计特定于状态的参数。这两个特征打开了解释与特定状态相关联的参数与相应状态概率相结合的可能性。这个家族中最常用的模型是那些假设有限数量的制度和马尔可夫过程的外生性的模型,这被定义为它独立于模型的不可预测的创新。在许多这样的应用中,通过对转移概率施加适当的限制或通过引入由解释变量或状态指示器函数决定的这些概率的时间依赖性,可以获得马尔可夫切换模型的期望性质。这个基本规范的扩展之一包括无限隐马尔可夫模型,该模型通过允许状态的数量趋于无穷大,提供了极大的灵活性和出色的预测性能。另一个扩展,即内生马尔可夫转换模型,明确地将状态指标与模型的创新联系起来,使其更具可解释性,并为发展提供了有希望的途径。
{"title":"Markov Switching","authors":"Yong Song, T. Wo'zniak","doi":"10.1093/acrefore/9780190625979.013.174","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1093/acrefore/9780190625979.013.174","url":null,"abstract":"Markov switching models are a family of models that introduces time variation in the parameters in the form of their state, or regime-specific values. This time variation is governed by a latent discrete-valued stochastic process with limited memory. More specifically, the current value of the state indicator is determined by the value of the state indicator from the previous period only implying the Markov property. A transition matrix characterizes the properties of the Markov process by determining with what probability each of the states can be visited next period conditionally on the state in the current period. This setup decides on the two main advantages of the Markov switching models: the estimation of the probability of state occurrences in each of the sample periods by using filtering and smoothing methods and the estimation of the state-specific parameters. These two features open the possibility for interpretations of the parameters associated with specific regimes combined with the corresponding regime probabilities.\u0000 The most commonly applied models from this family are those that presume a finite number of regimes and the exogeneity of the Markov process, which is defined as its independence from the model’s unpredictable innovations. In many such applications, the desired properties of the Markov switching model have been obtained either by imposing appropriate restrictions on transition probabilities or by introducing the time dependence of these probabilities determined by explanatory variables or functions of the state indicator. One of the extensions of this basic specification includes infinite hidden Markov models that provide great flexibility and excellent forecasting performance by allowing the number of states to go to infinity. Another extension, the endogenous Markov switching model, explicitly relates the state indicator to the model’s innovations, making it more interpretable and offering promising avenues for development.","PeriodicalId":211658,"journal":{"name":"Oxford Research Encyclopedia of Economics and Finance","volume":"53 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2020-02-10","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"126623426","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 4
Geography, Trade, and Power-Law Phenomena 地理、贸易和幂律现象
Pub Date : 2020-01-30 DOI: 10.1093/ACREFORE/9780190625979.013.296
P. Chang, Wen-Tai Hsu
This article reviews interrelated power-law phenomena in geography and trade. Given the empirical evidence on the gravity equation in trade flows across countries and regions, its theoretical underpinnings are reviewed. The gravity equation amounts to saying that trade flows follow a power law in distance (or geographic barriers). It is concluded that in the environment with firm heterogeneity, the power law in firm size is the key condition for the gravity equation to arise. A distribution is said to follow a power law if its tail probability follows a power function in the distribution’s right tail. The second part of this article reviews the literature that provides the microfoundation for the power law in firm size and reviews how this power law (in firm size) may be related to the power laws in other distributions (in incomes, firm productivity and city size).
本文回顾了地理和贸易中相关的幂律现象。鉴于各国和各地区贸易流动中的重力方程的经验证据,本文回顾了其理论基础。引力方程等于说,贸易流动遵循距离(或地理障碍)的幂律。结果表明,在企业异质性环境下,企业规模的幂律是重力方程成立的关键条件。如果一个分布的尾部概率遵循分布右尾部的幂函数,则该分布遵循幂律。本文的第二部分回顾了为企业规模幂律提供微观基础的文献,并回顾了该幂律(企业规模)如何与其他分布(收入、企业生产率和城市规模)中的幂律相关联。
{"title":"Geography, Trade, and Power-Law Phenomena","authors":"P. Chang, Wen-Tai Hsu","doi":"10.1093/ACREFORE/9780190625979.013.296","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1093/ACREFORE/9780190625979.013.296","url":null,"abstract":"This article reviews interrelated power-law phenomena in geography and trade. Given the empirical evidence on the gravity equation in trade flows across countries and regions, its theoretical underpinnings are reviewed. The gravity equation amounts to saying that trade flows follow a power law in distance (or geographic barriers). It is concluded that in the environment with firm heterogeneity, the power law in firm size is the key condition for the gravity equation to arise. A distribution is said to follow a power law if its tail probability follows a power function in the distribution’s right tail. The second part of this article reviews the literature that provides the microfoundation for the power law in firm size and reviews how this power law (in firm size) may be related to the power laws in other distributions (in incomes, firm productivity and city size).","PeriodicalId":211658,"journal":{"name":"Oxford Research Encyclopedia of Economics and Finance","volume":"33 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2020-01-30","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"124944580","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Age-Period-Cohort Models Age-Period-Cohort模型
Pub Date : 2019-12-23 DOI: 10.1093/ACREFORE/9780190625979.013.495
B. Nielsen
Outcomes of interest often depend on the age, period, or cohort of the individual observed, where cohort and age add up to period. An example is consumption: consumption patterns change over the lifecycle (age) but are also affected by the availability of products at different times (period) and by birth-cohort-specific habits and preferences (cohort). Age-period-cohort (APC) models are additive models where the predictor is a sum of three time effects, which are functions of age, period, and cohort, respectively. Variations of these models are available for data aggregated over age, period, and cohort, and for data drawn from repeated cross-sections, where the time effects can be combined with individual covariates. The age, period, and cohort time effects are intertwined. Inclusion of an indicator variable for each level of age, period, and cohort results in perfect collinearity, which is referred to as “the age-period-cohort identification problem.” Estimation can be done by dropping some indicator variables. However, dropping indicators has adverse consequences such as the time effects are not individually interpretable and inference becomes complicated. These consequences are avoided by instead decomposing the time effects into linear and non-linear components and noting that the identification problem relates to the linear components, whereas the non-linear components are identifiable. Thus, confusion is avoided by keeping the identifiable non-linear components of the time effects and the unidentifiable linear components apart. A variety of hypotheses of practical interest can be expressed in terms of the non-linear components.
感兴趣的结果通常取决于观察个体的年龄、时期或队列,其中队列和年龄加起来等于时间段。一个例子是消费:消费模式在生命周期(年龄)中发生变化,但也受到不同时间(时期)产品的可用性以及出生队列特定的习惯和偏好(队列)的影响。年龄-时期-队列(APC)模型是加性模型,其中预测因子是三个时间效应的总和,分别是年龄、时期和队列的函数。这些模型的变化可用于按年龄、时期和队列汇总的数据,以及从重复横截面提取的数据,其中时间效应可以与单个协变量相结合。年龄、时期和群体时间的影响是相互交织的。在年龄、时期和队列的每个水平上包含一个指标变量,结果是完全共线性,这被称为“年龄-时期-队列识别问题”。估计可以通过删除一些指示变量来完成。然而,下降指标也会带来一些不利的后果,如时间效应不能单独解释,推理变得复杂。通过将时间效应分解为线性和非线性分量,并注意到识别问题与线性分量有关,而非线性分量是可识别的,从而避免了这些后果。因此,通过保持时间效应的可识别的非线性成分和不可识别的线性成分分开,可以避免混淆。各种有实际意义的假设都可以用非线性分量来表示。
{"title":"Age-Period-Cohort Models","authors":"B. Nielsen","doi":"10.1093/ACREFORE/9780190625979.013.495","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1093/ACREFORE/9780190625979.013.495","url":null,"abstract":"Outcomes of interest often depend on the age, period, or cohort of the individual observed, where cohort and age add up to period. An example is consumption: consumption patterns change over the lifecycle (age) but are also affected by the availability of products at different times (period) and by birth-cohort-specific habits and preferences (cohort). Age-period-cohort (APC) models are additive models where the predictor is a sum of three time effects, which are functions of age, period, and cohort, respectively. Variations of these models are available for data aggregated over age, period, and cohort, and for data drawn from repeated cross-sections, where the time effects can be combined with individual covariates.\u0000 The age, period, and cohort time effects are intertwined. Inclusion of an indicator variable for each level of age, period, and cohort results in perfect collinearity, which is referred to as “the age-period-cohort identification problem.” Estimation can be done by dropping some indicator variables. However, dropping indicators has adverse consequences such as the time effects are not individually interpretable and inference becomes complicated. These consequences are avoided by instead decomposing the time effects into linear and non-linear components and noting that the identification problem relates to the linear components, whereas the non-linear components are identifiable. Thus, confusion is avoided by keeping the identifiable non-linear components of the time effects and the unidentifiable linear components apart. A variety of hypotheses of practical interest can be expressed in terms of the non-linear components.","PeriodicalId":211658,"journal":{"name":"Oxford Research Encyclopedia of Economics and Finance","volume":"62 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2019-12-23","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"116920273","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 13
Predictive Regressions 预测回归
Pub Date : 2019-11-22 DOI: 10.1093/acrefore/9780190625979.013.494
J. Gonzalo, Jean-Yves Pitarakis
Predictive regressions are a widely used econometric environment for assessing the predictability of economic and financial variables using past values of one or more predictors. The nature of the applications considered by practitioners often involve the use of predictors that have highly persistent, smoothly varying dynamics as opposed to the much noisier nature of the variable being predicted. This imbalance tends to affect the accuracy of the estimates of the model parameters and the validity of inferences about them when one uses standard methods that do not explicitly recognize this and related complications. A growing literature aimed at introducing novel techniques specifically designed to produce accurate inferences in such environments ensued. The frequent use of these predictive regressions in applied work has also led practitioners to question the validity of viewing predictability within a linear setting that ignores the possibility that predictability may occasionally be switched off. This in turn has generated a new stream of research aiming at introducing regime-specific behavior within predictive regressions in order to explicitly capture phenomena such as episodic predictability.
预测回归是一种广泛使用的计量经济学环境,用于使用一个或多个预测因子的过去值来评估经济和金融变量的可预测性。从业人员考虑的应用程序的性质通常涉及使用具有高度持久、平滑变化动态的预测器,而不是被预测的变量的嘈杂性。当使用没有明确认识到这一点和相关并发症的标准方法时,这种不平衡倾向于影响模型参数估计的准确性和关于它们的推断的有效性。越来越多的文献旨在引入专门设计用于在这种环境中产生准确推断的新技术。这些预测回归在应用工作中的频繁使用也导致从业者质疑在线性设置中观察可预测性的有效性,这种设置忽略了可预测性偶尔被关闭的可能性。这反过来又产生了一种新的研究流,旨在在预测回归中引入特定制度的行为,以便明确地捕捉诸如情景可预测性之类的现象。
{"title":"Predictive Regressions","authors":"J. Gonzalo, Jean-Yves Pitarakis","doi":"10.1093/acrefore/9780190625979.013.494","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1093/acrefore/9780190625979.013.494","url":null,"abstract":"Predictive regressions are a widely used econometric environment for assessing the predictability of economic and financial variables using past values of one or more predictors. The nature of the applications considered by practitioners often involve the use of predictors that have highly persistent, smoothly varying dynamics as opposed to the much noisier nature of the variable being predicted. This imbalance tends to affect the accuracy of the estimates of the model parameters and the validity of inferences about them when one uses standard methods that do not explicitly recognize this and related complications. A growing literature aimed at introducing novel techniques specifically designed to produce accurate inferences in such environments ensued. The frequent use of these predictive regressions in applied work has also led practitioners to question the validity of viewing predictability within a linear setting that ignores the possibility that predictability may occasionally be switched off. This in turn has generated a new stream of research aiming at introducing regime-specific behavior within predictive regressions in order to explicitly capture phenomena such as episodic predictability.","PeriodicalId":211658,"journal":{"name":"Oxford Research Encyclopedia of Economics and Finance","volume":"31 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2019-11-22","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"134522643","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Economic Theory of Criminal Law 刑法经济理论“,
Pub Date : 2019-08-28 DOI: 10.1093/ACREFORE/9780190625979.013.344
Keith N. Hylton
Criminal law consists of substantive and procedural parts. Substantive law is the set of rules defining conduct that violates the law. Procedural criminal law is the set of rules regulating the process of punishment. Substantive rules apply mostly to individual actors, and procedural rules apply to public enforcement agencies and adjudicators. Economic theory of criminal law consists of normative and positive parts. Normative economic theory, which began with writings by Beccaria and Bentham, aims to recommend an ideal criminal punishment scheme. Positive economic theory, which appeared later in writings by Holmes and Posner, aims to justify and to better understand the criminal law rules that exist. Since the purpose of criminal law is to deter socially undesirable conduct, economic theory, which emphasizes incentives, would appear to be an important perspective from which to examine criminal law. Positive economic theory, applied to substantive criminal law, seeks to explain and to justify criminal law doctrine in economic terms—that is, in terms that emphasize the incentive effects created by the law. The positive economic theory of criminal law literature can be divided into three phases: Classical deterrence theory, neoclassical deterrence, and modern synthesis. The modern synthesis provides a rationale for fundamental criminal law doctrines and also more puzzling portions of the law such as the doctrines of intent and necessity. Positive economic theory also provides a rationale for the allocation of enforcement responsibilities.
刑法由实体法和程序法两部分组成。实体法是一套规定违反法律行为的规则。程序刑法是规范刑罚过程的一套规则。实体规则主要适用于个体行为者,程序规则适用于公共执法机构和裁决人员。刑法经济理论分为规范性和实证两个部分。规范经济理论始于贝卡利亚和边沁的著作,旨在推荐一种理想的刑事惩罚方案。实证经济理论后来出现在福尔摩斯和波斯纳的著作中,旨在证明并更好地理解现有的刑法规则。由于刑法的目的是阻止不受社会欢迎的行为,强调激励的经济理论似乎是研究刑法的一个重要视角。实证经济理论应用于实体刑法,试图从经济角度解释和证明刑法理论的合理性,也就是说,从强调法律产生的激励效应的角度。刑法文献的实证经济理论可以分为古典威慑理论、新古典威慑理论和现代综合理论三个阶段。现代综合理论为刑法的基本理论提供了理论基础,也为刑法中较为令人费解的部分提供了理论基础,如意图理论和必要性理论。实证经济理论也为执法责任的分配提供了理论依据。
{"title":"Economic Theory of Criminal Law","authors":"Keith N. Hylton","doi":"10.1093/ACREFORE/9780190625979.013.344","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1093/ACREFORE/9780190625979.013.344","url":null,"abstract":"Criminal law consists of substantive and procedural parts. Substantive law is the set of rules defining conduct that violates the law. Procedural criminal law is the set of rules regulating the process of punishment. Substantive rules apply mostly to individual actors, and procedural rules apply to public enforcement agencies and adjudicators.\u0000 Economic theory of criminal law consists of normative and positive parts. Normative economic theory, which began with writings by Beccaria and Bentham, aims to recommend an ideal criminal punishment scheme. Positive economic theory, which appeared later in writings by Holmes and Posner, aims to justify and to better understand the criminal law rules that exist. Since the purpose of criminal law is to deter socially undesirable conduct, economic theory, which emphasizes incentives, would appear to be an important perspective from which to examine criminal law.\u0000 Positive economic theory, applied to substantive criminal law, seeks to explain and to justify criminal law doctrine in economic terms—that is, in terms that emphasize the incentive effects created by the law. The positive economic theory of criminal law literature can be divided into three phases: Classical deterrence theory, neoclassical deterrence, and modern synthesis. The modern synthesis provides a rationale for fundamental criminal law doctrines and also more puzzling portions of the law such as the doctrines of intent and necessity. Positive economic theory also provides a rationale for the allocation of enforcement responsibilities.","PeriodicalId":211658,"journal":{"name":"Oxford Research Encyclopedia of Economics and Finance","volume":"38 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2019-08-28","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"124868578","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
期刊
Oxford Research Encyclopedia of Economics and Finance
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1