首页 > 最新文献

New Institutional Economics最新文献

英文 中文
War's Legacy in International Investment Law 战争对国际投资法的影响
Pub Date : 2009-03-10 DOI: 10.1163/187197409X12525781476088
J. Gathii
This article discusses the role war has played in shaping the rules of international investment law from the late nineteenth century. At the end of the nineteenth century and the beginning of the twentieth century, the move towards institutions, such as arbitration forums, and rules as an alternative to the use of force gave new impetus to the growth of international commercial law and related institutions. These rules and institutions represented the hope that the use of force would be eclipsed as States moved forward towards more cooperative, consensual and non-coercive mechanisms of dispute settlement. Capital-importing states in Latin America however became acutely aware that these institutions and rules did not completely erase the coercive and uneven relations they had with capital-exporting states. In era after era of reformism from the Calvo era, to the NIEO and to the era in opposition to neo-liberal economic governance, capital-importing States have continued to resist and sometimes adapt to the coercive realities of the rules of international investment law. The article begins by tracing the origin of the Drago doctrine as a response to the practice of European states that engaged in aggression and conquest against militarily and economically weaker Latin American states as a means of collecting debts owed to their citizens. It then shows that while the denouement of forcible measures to resolve contract debt was overstated by early twentieth century international lawyers, international law nevertheless provided avenues for dispute settlement outside the use of force in international commercial relations. Thus while protecting commerce from the scourge of war was a primary inspiration for the post-Second World War international economic order, the author shows how war has nevertheless continued to be an animating factor for former colonies particularly with regard to their State responsibility for war damage in the context of foreign investment.
本文讨论了自19世纪后期以来,战争在国际投资法规则的形成中所起的作用。在19世纪末和20世纪初,建立仲裁论坛等机构和规则作为使用武力的替代办法,为国际商法和有关机构的发展提供了新的动力。这些规则和机构代表着一种希望,即随着各国朝着更加合作、协商一致和非强制性的解决争端机制迈进,使用武力将会黯然失色。然而,拉丁美洲的资本输入国家敏锐地意识到,这些制度和规则并没有完全消除它们与资本输出国家之间的强制性和不平衡关系。从卡尔沃时代到NIEO和反对新自由主义经济治理的时代,在一个又一个改革主义时代,资本输入国继续抵制,有时还适应国际投资法规则的强制性现实。文章首先追溯了德拉戈主义的起源,以回应欧洲国家对军事和经济上较弱的拉丁美洲国家进行侵略和征服的做法,以此作为收取欠其公民债务的手段。然后,它表明,虽然二十世纪初的国际律师夸大了解决合同债务的强制措施的结果,但国际法仍然提供了在国际商业关系中使用武力之外解决争端的途径。因此,虽然保护商业免受战祸是第二次世界大战后国际经济秩序的主要灵感,但作者表明,战争如何继续成为前殖民地的一个活跃因素,特别是在外国投资方面,它们的国家对战争损害的责任方面。
{"title":"War's Legacy in International Investment Law","authors":"J. Gathii","doi":"10.1163/187197409X12525781476088","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1163/187197409X12525781476088","url":null,"abstract":"This article discusses the role war has played in shaping the rules of international investment law from the late nineteenth century. At the end of the nineteenth century and the beginning of the twentieth century, the move towards institutions, such as arbitration forums, and rules as an alternative to the use of force gave new impetus to the growth of international commercial law and related institutions. These rules and institutions represented the hope that the use of force would be eclipsed as States moved forward towards more cooperative, consensual and non-coercive mechanisms of dispute settlement. Capital-importing states in Latin America however became acutely aware that these institutions and rules did not completely erase the coercive and uneven relations they had with capital-exporting states. In era after era of reformism from the Calvo era, to the NIEO and to the era in opposition to neo-liberal economic governance, capital-importing States have continued to resist and sometimes adapt to the coercive realities of the rules of international investment law. The article begins by tracing the origin of the Drago doctrine as a response to the practice of European states that engaged in aggression and conquest against militarily and economically weaker Latin American states as a means of collecting debts owed to their citizens. It then shows that while the denouement of forcible measures to resolve contract debt was overstated by early twentieth century international lawyers, international law nevertheless provided avenues for dispute settlement outside the use of force in international commercial relations. Thus while protecting commerce from the scourge of war was a primary inspiration for the post-Second World War international economic order, the author shows how war has nevertheless continued to be an animating factor for former colonies particularly with regard to their State responsibility for war damage in the context of foreign investment.","PeriodicalId":383948,"journal":{"name":"New Institutional Economics","volume":"34 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2009-03-10","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"128317697","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 11
Efficiency, Welfare and Ownership of Private Information 效率、福利与私人信息所有权
Pub Date : 2009-03-05 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.963155
Qihong Liu, Konstantinos Serfes
Unrestricted flows of information usually improve efficiency. The recent growth of the Internet as a medium of communication and commerce, combined with the development of sophisticated software tools have paved the road for the collection and analysis of a vast amount of data about consumers. Firms who possess such information can target individual consumers (or certain groups of consumers) more effectively. We investigate whether consumers can claim some of the value of their own private information, while at the same time efficient flows of information are guaranteed. We address this question in a principal-agent adverse selection model. Prior to the contracting stage, the agent (consumer) chooses how much (precision) of his private information to sell to the principal. This gives rise to a signaling game that precedes the adverse selection stage. We show that there exists a pooling efficient equilibrium, where both agent types sell all their information to the principal.
不受限制的信息流动通常会提高效率。作为通信和商业媒介的互联网最近的发展,加上复杂软件工具的发展,为收集和分析大量消费者数据铺平了道路。拥有这些信息的公司可以更有效地瞄准个别消费者(或某些消费者群体)。我们研究消费者是否可以主张他们自己的私人信息的一些价值,同时保证信息的有效流动。我们在一个委托代理逆向选择模型中解决了这个问题。在签约阶段之前,代理人(消费者)选择向委托人出售多少(精确)他的私人信息。这就产生了逆向选择阶段之前的信号博弈。我们证明了存在一个池化有效均衡,其中两种代理类型都将其所有信息出售给委托人。
{"title":"Efficiency, Welfare and Ownership of Private Information","authors":"Qihong Liu, Konstantinos Serfes","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.963155","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.963155","url":null,"abstract":"Unrestricted flows of information usually improve efficiency. The recent growth of the Internet as a medium of communication and commerce, combined with the development of sophisticated software tools have paved the road for the collection and analysis of a vast amount of data about consumers. Firms who possess such information can target individual consumers (or certain groups of consumers) more effectively. We investigate whether consumers can claim some of the value of their own private information, while at the same time efficient flows of information are guaranteed. We address this question in a principal-agent adverse selection model. Prior to the contracting stage, the agent (consumer) chooses how much (precision) of his private information to sell to the principal. This gives rise to a signaling game that precedes the adverse selection stage. We show that there exists a pooling efficient equilibrium, where both agent types sell all their information to the principal.","PeriodicalId":383948,"journal":{"name":"New Institutional Economics","volume":"26 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2009-03-05","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"123939004","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Retailing Governance? The Rise of Accountability Communities 零售管理?问责社区的兴起
Pub Date : 2009-03-03 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.1352770
Kanishka Jayasuriya
'Who' is accountable to 'whom' becomes a crucial issue in new modes of governance. The thrust of a substantial literature on regulatory governance at the global or national level is towards a search for substitute mechanisms of accountability and monitoring, operating outside formal governmental institutions. And here, what I term 'accountability communities' perform a crucial function. Accountability communities are complex and composed of public and/or private organisations and they: a) perform legislative, monitoring and compliance activities in specific functionally based regulatory regimes within and beyond, national boundaries; b) operate through institutional forms such as deliberative forums, markets, or use of network mechanisms; and c) possess particular understandings of accountability that binds various actors together.
在新的治理模式中,“谁”对“谁”负责成为一个关键问题。关于全球或国家一级管制治理的大量文献的主旨是寻求在正式政府机构之外运作的问责制和监督的替代机制。在这里,我所说的“问责社区”发挥着至关重要的作用。问责社区是复杂的,由公共和/或私人组织组成,它们:a)在国家境内外的特定职能监管制度中进行立法、监督和合规活动;B)通过协商论坛、市场或网络机制等制度形式运作;c)对将不同行为者联系在一起的问责制有特殊的理解。
{"title":"Retailing Governance? The Rise of Accountability Communities","authors":"Kanishka Jayasuriya","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.1352770","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1352770","url":null,"abstract":"'Who' is accountable to 'whom' becomes a crucial issue in new modes of governance. The thrust of a substantial literature on regulatory governance at the global or national level is towards a search for substitute mechanisms of accountability and monitoring, operating outside formal governmental institutions. And here, what I term 'accountability communities' perform a crucial function. Accountability communities are complex and composed of public and/or private organisations and they: a) perform legislative, monitoring and compliance activities in specific functionally based regulatory regimes within and beyond, national boundaries; b) operate through institutional forms such as deliberative forums, markets, or use of network mechanisms; and c) possess particular understandings of accountability that binds various actors together.","PeriodicalId":383948,"journal":{"name":"New Institutional Economics","volume":"41 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2009-03-03","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"114835327","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 6
The Exercise of International Public Authority through National Policy Assessment: The OECD's PISA Policy as a Paradigm for a New International Standard Instrument 通过国家政策评估行使国际公共权力:经合组织的PISA政策作为一种新的国际标准工具的范例
Pub Date : 2009-02-11 DOI: 10.1163/157237408X412907
Armin von Bogdandy, Matthias Goldmann
The OECD Programme for International Student Assessment (PISA) is probably the most prominent signpost for the internationalization of educational policy. The PISA reports on the performance of secondary school students have become an important factor for educational policy-making in the developed world. In some states PISA has spurred more educational reforms than anything before it during the last decades. What is more, PISA succeeded in shifting approach and focus in a most sensitive area of domestic policy touching on social justice and the self-understanding of the citizenry: Because of PISA, policy-making in the field of school education changed from normative, input-oriented reasoning to comparative, empirical, output-oriented analysis. The international plane succeeded in establishing itself as indispensable in a field thus far essentially conceived as domestic.PISA owes its impact on educational policy to a mode of governance which we call "governance by information". It describes mechanisms which impact on a given policy field by shaping the cognitive framework of policy-making through the collection, processing and dissemination of information. International and supranational institutions more and more often take recourse to governance by information. This article explores the repercussions of governance by information for international law in an approach that stresses the publicness of public international law and the role of international institutional law in legally framing global governance. Thus far, these questions have been hardly explored, in spite of the enormous impact of PISA on national policy. We hypothesize that this is because the knowledge and experience of international lawyers relate mostly to international treaties and other binding legal instruments. Governance by information, by contrast, determines society indirectly through instruments which establish or contribute to the cognitive setting within which policy-makers operate. But since no legal obligations are imposed upon states or individuals, it escapes the established perspective of international lawyers, just as many other instruments, actors and processes of global governance do.In the article, we first provide an overview of PISA and its legal framework (II). Thereafter, we explain why PISA should be considered an exercise of public authority and why it therefore needs a solid public law framework. This part develops a concept of international public authority that focuses on the social relevance of official acts and their impact on individual freedom (III). Third, we explore on a theoretical level how a legal framework could be established for new forms of public authority. In the tradition of German and Italian public law scholarship we suggest the doctrinal construction of "standard instruments" (Handlungsformen). This doctrinal construction does not rest on the belief that legal concepts automatically evoke legitimacy. Rather, it stresses the communicat
经合组织国际学生评估项目(PISA)可能是教育政策国际化最突出的路标。关于中学生表现的PISA报告已经成为发达国家教育政策制定的一个重要因素。在过去的几十年里,PISA在一些州推动了前所未有的教育改革。更重要的是,PISA成功地将方法和重点转移到了涉及社会正义和公民自我理解的国内政策最敏感的领域:由于PISA,学校教育领域的政策制定从规范的、以投入为导向的推理转变为比较的、经验的、以产出为导向的分析。国际飞机成功地在一个迄今基本上被认为是国内飞机的领域确立了自己不可或缺的地位。PISA将其对教育政策的影响归功于一种我们称之为“信息治理”的治理模式。它描述了通过收集、处理和传播信息来塑造决策认知框架,从而对特定政策领域产生影响的机制。国际和超国家机构越来越多地诉诸信息治理。本文探讨了信息治理对国际法的影响,强调了国际公法的公共性和国际机构法在法律框架下全球治理中的作用。迄今为止,尽管PISA对国家政策产生了巨大影响,但这些问题几乎没有被探讨过。我们假设这是因为国际律师的知识和经验主要与国际条约和其他有约束力的法律文书有关。相比之下,信息治理通过建立或促进决策者在其中运作的认知环境的工具间接地决定社会。但由于没有将任何法律义务强加给国家或个人,就像全球治理的许多其他工具、行为体和进程一样,它逃脱了国际律师的既定视角。在文章中,我们首先概述了PISA及其法律框架(II)。此后,我们解释了为什么PISA应被视为公共权力的行使,以及为什么它因此需要一个坚实的公法框架。这一部分发展了一个国际公共权威的概念,重点关注官方行为的社会相关性及其对个人自由的影响(III)。第三,我们在理论层面探索如何为新形式的公共权威建立法律框架。在德国和意大利公法学术的传统中,我们建议“标准文书”(Handlungsformen)的理论建构。这种理论建构并不建立在法律概念自动唤起合法性的信念之上。相反,它强调法律原则的沟通功能,它为行使权力提供了稳定的基础,同时作为争论的论坛(IV)。在接下来的部分中,我们构建并提出了一个名为“国家政策评估”(Politikbewertung)的标准工具,旨在以具有法律意义的方式把握PISA和类似政策的主旨(V)。国家政策评估的法律制度是通过确定PISA法律框架内的基本法律要素来制定的,我们认为这些要素有助于这一标准工具的合法性和有效运作。这些因素涉及国家政策评估所依据的任务、尊重科学标准和专业知识的代表性、获得评估数据以及国家对评估结果的所有权。在对这些因素进行批判性评价之后,我们考虑到由此建立的国家政策评估法律制度对其他在教育领域冒险的国际机构的影响。PISA的例子表明,信息治理是建立在一个相当复杂的法律框架之上的。标准文书是从这一法律框架中抽象出基本法律要素和原则的一个有用的理论类别,它增加了这样行使的权力的合法性和效力。这种抽象也使得从不同的理论角度进行批评成为可能。此外,制定标准文书为国际机构的决策者提供了一种资源,以便将这类治理转移到其他问题领域。一旦这种法律制度足够复杂,足以确保合法性和效率,它就可以适用于其他领域。在这方面,教义概念化具有理性化和澄清性的作用。
{"title":"The Exercise of International Public Authority through National Policy Assessment: The OECD's PISA Policy as a Paradigm for a New International Standard Instrument","authors":"Armin von Bogdandy, Matthias Goldmann","doi":"10.1163/157237408X412907","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1163/157237408X412907","url":null,"abstract":"The OECD Programme for International Student Assessment (PISA) is probably the most prominent signpost for the internationalization of educational policy. The PISA reports on the performance of secondary school students have become an important factor for educational policy-making in the developed world. In some states PISA has spurred more educational reforms than anything before it during the last decades. What is more, PISA succeeded in shifting approach and focus in a most sensitive area of domestic policy touching on social justice and the self-understanding of the citizenry: Because of PISA, policy-making in the field of school education changed from normative, input-oriented reasoning to comparative, empirical, output-oriented analysis. The international plane succeeded in establishing itself as indispensable in a field thus far essentially conceived as domestic.PISA owes its impact on educational policy to a mode of governance which we call \"governance by information\". It describes mechanisms which impact on a given policy field by shaping the cognitive framework of policy-making through the collection, processing and dissemination of information. International and supranational institutions more and more often take recourse to governance by information. This article explores the repercussions of governance by information for international law in an approach that stresses the publicness of public international law and the role of international institutional law in legally framing global governance. Thus far, these questions have been hardly explored, in spite of the enormous impact of PISA on national policy. We hypothesize that this is because the knowledge and experience of international lawyers relate mostly to international treaties and other binding legal instruments. Governance by information, by contrast, determines society indirectly through instruments which establish or contribute to the cognitive setting within which policy-makers operate. But since no legal obligations are imposed upon states or individuals, it escapes the established perspective of international lawyers, just as many other instruments, actors and processes of global governance do.In the article, we first provide an overview of PISA and its legal framework (II). Thereafter, we explain why PISA should be considered an exercise of public authority and why it therefore needs a solid public law framework. This part develops a concept of international public authority that focuses on the social relevance of official acts and their impact on individual freedom (III). Third, we explore on a theoretical level how a legal framework could be established for new forms of public authority. In the tradition of German and Italian public law scholarship we suggest the doctrinal construction of \"standard instruments\" (Handlungsformen). This doctrinal construction does not rest on the belief that legal concepts automatically evoke legitimacy. Rather, it stresses the communicat","PeriodicalId":383948,"journal":{"name":"New Institutional Economics","volume":"29 15","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2009-02-11","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"120957296","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 29
Law as the Interplay of Ideas, Institutions, and Interests: Using Polyani (and Foucault) to Ask TWAIL Questions 法律作为思想、制度和利益的相互作用:用波利亚尼(和福柯)来问TWAIL问题
Pub Date : 2009-02-02 DOI: 10.1163/187197308x356912
Michael Fakhri
Th is paper sketches out some preliminary thoughts on political economy that stem from problematics that emerge from Third World Approaches to International Law (TWAIL). The TWAIL story of international law is one of frustration and disappointment because of the constant exploitation of the Third World despite all the historic changes in international legal ideas and institutions, but it also a story of hope in the moments of resistance. In order to better debate how particular international institutions should be changed or whether particular international institutions should be renounced, I suggest that we need to explicate the theories of political economy embedded within these institutions. Drawing from Karl Polanyi's Th e Great Transformation, bringing alongside the work of Michel Foucault, I sketch out one way of conducting a study of international political economy by suggesting that we can think of law as the interplay of ideas, institutions, and interests.
本文从“第三世界的国际法方法”(TWAIL)中出现的问题出发,提出了一些关于政治经济学的初步思考。TWAIL的国际法故事是一个沮丧和失望的故事,因为尽管国际法思想和制度发生了历史性的变化,第三世界仍在不断受到剥削,但它也是一个在抵抗时刻充满希望的故事。为了更好地讨论应该如何改变特定的国际制度,或者是否应该放弃特定的国际制度,我建议我们需要解释这些制度中隐含的政治经济学理论。借鉴卡尔·波兰尼的《大转型》,结合米歇尔·福柯的著作,我提出了一种进行国际政治经济学研究的方法,即我们可以将法律视为思想、制度和利益的相互作用。
{"title":"Law as the Interplay of Ideas, Institutions, and Interests: Using Polyani (and Foucault) to Ask TWAIL Questions","authors":"Michael Fakhri","doi":"10.1163/187197308x356912","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1163/187197308x356912","url":null,"abstract":"Th is paper sketches out some preliminary thoughts on political economy that stem from problematics that emerge from Third World Approaches to International Law (TWAIL). The TWAIL story of international law is one of frustration and disappointment because of the constant exploitation of the Third World despite all the historic changes in international legal ideas and institutions, but it also a story of hope in the moments of resistance. In order to better debate how particular international institutions should be changed or whether particular international institutions should be renounced, I suggest that we need to explicate the theories of political economy embedded within these institutions. Drawing from Karl Polanyi's Th e Great Transformation, bringing alongside the work of Michel Foucault, I sketch out one way of conducting a study of international political economy by suggesting that we can think of law as the interplay of ideas, institutions, and interests.","PeriodicalId":383948,"journal":{"name":"New Institutional Economics","volume":"114 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2009-02-02","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"123294790","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 11
Preventing Markets from Self-Destruction: The Quality of Government Factor 防止市场自我毁灭:政府因素的质量
Pub Date : 2009-01-16 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.1328819
Bo Rothstein
Four interrelated arguments are presented to form a theory about the relation between the logic of markets, social efficiency and the quality of government. The first is that competitive markets with a certain set of characteristics are the most efficient organizational form for creating a utilitarian based economic efficiency for the production of most goods and services. The second argument is that in order to reach this utilitarian based social efficiency, markets need large and complicated set of institutions, formal as well as informal. Since such institutions will in the long run make all market agents better off, they are labelled efficient institutions. The third argument is that it is unlikely that such institutions will be created endogenously by market agents. Moreover, if such institutions have been created, we should expect market agents to try to destroy them. Based on insights from various approaches (institutional economics and research on neo-corporatism, clientilism, and corruption) there is no reason to expect that efficient institutions will evolve by any selection mechanism that is generated from the sum of agency that exists in markets. The conclusion reached is that if left to themselves, markets are inherently selfdestructive. The fourth argument is that markets can only reach social efficiency if the agents that reproduce the necessary efficient type of institutions act according to a logic that is different from the logic that market agents use when operating in the market. This operational logic is the ethical dimensions of what should count as quality of government.
本文提出了四个相互关联的论点,以形成一个关于市场逻辑、社会效率和政府质量之间关系的理论。首先,具有一定特征的竞争市场是为大多数商品和服务的生产创造基于功利主义的经济效率的最有效的组织形式。第二个论点是,为了达到这种基于功利主义的社会效率,市场需要一套庞大而复杂的制度,包括正式的和非正式的。因为从长远来看,这些制度将使所有市场主体变得更好,所以它们被称为高效制度。第三种观点是,这种制度不太可能由市场主体内生地创造出来。此外,如果这样的机构已经建立起来,我们应该预料到市场代理人会试图摧毁它们。根据各种方法(制度经济学和对新社团主义、客户主义和腐败的研究)的见解,没有理由期望有效的制度会通过市场中存在的代理总和产生的任何选择机制来发展。得出的结论是,如果放任市场自生自灭,市场本质上是自我毁灭的。第四个论点是,只有在生产必要的高效类型制度的主体按照不同于市场主体在市场中运作时使用的逻辑行事的情况下,市场才能达到社会效率。这种操作逻辑是政府质量的伦理维度。
{"title":"Preventing Markets from Self-Destruction: The Quality of Government Factor","authors":"Bo Rothstein","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.1328819","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1328819","url":null,"abstract":"Four interrelated arguments are presented to form a theory about the relation between the logic of markets, social efficiency and the quality of government. The first is that competitive markets with a certain set of characteristics are the most efficient organizational form for creating a utilitarian based economic efficiency for the production of most goods and services. The second argument is that in order to reach this utilitarian based social efficiency, markets need large and complicated set of institutions, formal as well as informal. Since such institutions will in the long run make all market agents better off, they are labelled efficient institutions. The third argument is that it is unlikely that such institutions will be created endogenously by market agents. Moreover, if such institutions have been created, we should expect market agents to try to destroy them. Based on insights from various approaches (institutional economics and research on neo-corporatism, clientilism, and corruption) there is no reason to expect that efficient institutions will evolve by any selection mechanism that is generated from the sum of agency that exists in markets. The conclusion reached is that if left to themselves, markets are inherently selfdestructive. The fourth argument is that markets can only reach social efficiency if the agents that reproduce the necessary efficient type of institutions act according to a logic that is different from the logic that market agents use when operating in the market. This operational logic is the ethical dimensions of what should count as quality of government.","PeriodicalId":383948,"journal":{"name":"New Institutional Economics","volume":"14 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2009-01-16","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"133286238","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 6
Can Pragmatists be Constitutionalists? Dewey, Jefferson and the Experimental Constitution 实用主义者能成为立宪主义者吗?杜威、杰弗逊与实验宪法
Pub Date : 2009-01-03 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.1322818
S. Ralston
At the beginning of the present century, a debate over the compatibility of constitutionalism and pragmatism erupted in the pages of the journal Administration and Society. Several scholars (especially James Stever, Kevin Snider and Patricia Shields) expressed concern that Deweyan pragmatism, or the classic pragmatism of John Dewey that some contemporary philosophers subscribe to, might be incompatible with the commitment to constitutional order found at the heart of the administrative state tradition. In this paper, the issue that arose in Administration and Society is framed more generally: Can pragmatists, and particularly Deweyan pragmatists, be constitutionalists? By way of answering this question, I define Dewey’s experimentalism in terms of his theory of inquiry and action, before proceeding to the administrative state debate, where the claim emerges that constitutional limits offend the experimentalist drive of Dewey’s pragmatism. Next, three typical (though by no means exhaustive) conceptions of constitutionalism are presented: (i) traditionalism (or that a constitution expresses the traditions or mores of its drafters’ society), (ii) organicism (or that a constitution is a living document, the meaning of which evolves with the changing values and norms of each new generation) and (iii) functionalism (or that a constitution functions as an ordering device, both creating and perpetuating legitimate legal-political frameworks). Then, I consider whether a founding document modeled after each conception can preserve political stability amidst a tolerable level of political change without offending Dewey’s experimentalism. In light of Dewey’s essay “Presenting Thomas Jefferson,” a related issue arises: Does Jefferson’s notion of generational sovereignty have any bearing on the matter of pragmatism and constitutionalism’s compatibility? The paper concludes with a final evaluation of the degree to which Deweyan experimentalism can accommodate a commitment to constitutionalism in its various forms.
本世纪初,《行政与社会》(administrative and Society)杂志上爆发了一场关于宪政与实用主义是否相容的辩论。一些学者(尤其是James Stever, Kevin Snider和Patricia Shields)表达了对杜威实用主义的担忧,或者一些当代哲学家赞同的约翰·杜威的经典实用主义,可能与行政国家传统核心的宪法秩序的承诺不相容。在本文中,《行政与社会》中出现的问题被更广泛地提出:实用主义者,特别是杜威实用主义者,能成为宪政主义者吗?为了回答这个问题,我将杜威的实验主义定义为他的调查和行动理论,然后再进行行政国家辩论,在辩论中出现了宪法限制冒犯了杜威实用主义的实验主义驱动的主张。接下来,提出了三个典型的(尽管并非详尽无遗的)宪政概念:(i)传统主义(或宪法表达了其起草者社会的传统或习俗),(ii)组织论(或宪法是一份活的文件,其意义随着每一代人不断变化的价值观和规范而演变)和(iii)功能主义(或宪法作为一种秩序工具,既创造又延续合法的法律政治框架)。然后,我考虑一个以每个概念为模型的建国文件是否可以在一个可容忍的政治变革水平中保持政治稳定,而不冒犯杜威的实验主义。根据杜威的文章“介绍托马斯·杰斐逊”,一个相关的问题出现了:杰斐逊的代际主权概念是否与实用主义和宪政主义的兼容性有关?本文最后对杜威的实验主义能在多大程度上容纳对各种形式的宪政的承诺作了最后的评价。
{"title":"Can Pragmatists be Constitutionalists? Dewey, Jefferson and the Experimental Constitution","authors":"S. Ralston","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.1322818","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1322818","url":null,"abstract":"At the beginning of the present century, a debate over the compatibility of constitutionalism and pragmatism erupted in the pages of the journal Administration and Society. Several scholars (especially James Stever, Kevin Snider and Patricia Shields) expressed concern that Deweyan pragmatism, or the classic pragmatism of John Dewey that some contemporary philosophers subscribe to, might be incompatible with the commitment to constitutional order found at the heart of the administrative state tradition. In this paper, the issue that arose in Administration and Society is framed more generally: Can pragmatists, and particularly Deweyan pragmatists, be constitutionalists? By way of answering this question, I define Dewey’s experimentalism in terms of his theory of inquiry and action, before proceeding to the administrative state debate, where the claim emerges that constitutional limits offend the experimentalist drive of Dewey’s pragmatism. Next, three typical (though by no means exhaustive) conceptions of constitutionalism are presented: (i) traditionalism (or that a constitution expresses the traditions or mores of its drafters’ society), (ii) organicism (or that a constitution is a living document, the meaning of which evolves with the changing values and norms of each new generation) and (iii) functionalism (or that a constitution functions as an ordering device, both creating and perpetuating legitimate legal-political frameworks). Then, I consider whether a founding document modeled after each conception can preserve political stability amidst a tolerable level of political change without offending Dewey’s experimentalism. In light of Dewey’s essay “Presenting Thomas Jefferson,” a related issue arises: Does Jefferson’s notion of generational sovereignty have any bearing on the matter of pragmatism and constitutionalism’s compatibility? The paper concludes with a final evaluation of the degree to which Deweyan experimentalism can accommodate a commitment to constitutionalism in its various forms.","PeriodicalId":383948,"journal":{"name":"New Institutional Economics","volume":"10 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2009-01-03","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"130165221","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Organizational Efficiency, Firm Capabilities, and Economic Organization of MNEs 组织效率、企业能力与跨国公司经济组织
Pub Date : 2009-01-01 DOI: 10.1108/1525383X200900021
P. Hwang, Ajai S. Gaur
We argue that multinational enterprises (MNEs) not only strive to minimize transaction costs but also attempt to maximize transaction values when interacting with local firms in foreign markets. We put forth our thesis regarding MNE governance structure, that it is contingent on the institutional environment of the host country and the characteristics of the transaction. Specifically, we suggest that MNEs’ choice of market, hierarchy or hybrid (joint ventures) form of governance, depends on the interplay between the costs and benefits of a transaction relationship. For high knowledge content products/services, MNEs choose hierarchy when the institutional environment is not well developed. As the institutional environment develops, hybrid replaces hierarchy. However, in a very strong institutional environment, hierarchy again turns out to be optimal for MNEs. For low or no knowledge content products/services, the presence of market is possible in a very advanced institutional environment.
我们认为,跨国企业(MNEs)在国外市场与当地企业互动时,不仅努力使交易成本最小化,而且试图使交易价值最大化。我们提出了跨国公司治理结构的理论,认为跨国公司治理结构取决于东道国的制度环境和交易的特点。具体而言,我们建议跨国公司选择市场、层级或混合(合资)治理形式,取决于交易关系的成本和收益之间的相互作用。对于高知识含量的产品/服务,跨国公司在制度环境不完善的情况下选择层次结构。随着制度环境的发展,混合制取代了等级制。然而,在一个非常强大的制度环境中,等级制度再次被证明是跨国公司的最佳选择。对于低知识含量或无知识含量的产品/服务,在非常先进的制度环境中,市场的存在是可能的。
{"title":"Organizational Efficiency, Firm Capabilities, and Economic Organization of MNEs","authors":"P. Hwang, Ajai S. Gaur","doi":"10.1108/1525383X200900021","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1108/1525383X200900021","url":null,"abstract":"We argue that multinational enterprises (MNEs) not only strive to minimize transaction costs but also attempt to maximize transaction values when interacting with local firms in foreign markets. We put forth our thesis regarding MNE governance structure, that it is contingent on the institutional environment of the host country and the characteristics of the transaction. Specifically, we suggest that MNEs’ choice of market, hierarchy or hybrid (joint ventures) form of governance, depends on the interplay between the costs and benefits of a transaction relationship. For high knowledge content products/services, MNEs choose hierarchy when the institutional environment is not well developed. As the institutional environment develops, hybrid replaces hierarchy. However, in a very strong institutional environment, hierarchy again turns out to be optimal for MNEs. For low or no knowledge content products/services, the presence of market is possible in a very advanced institutional environment.","PeriodicalId":383948,"journal":{"name":"New Institutional Economics","volume":"24 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2009-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"123325102","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 28
The Credit Crunch and the End of Neoliberalism 信贷紧缩和新自由主义的终结
Pub Date : 2008-12-07 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.1312722
Ioannis Glinavos
A comment on the theoretical consequences of the credit crunch on neoliberalism as a development doctrine.
评论信贷紧缩对新自由主义作为一种发展主义的理论影响。
{"title":"The Credit Crunch and the End of Neoliberalism","authors":"Ioannis Glinavos","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.1312722","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.1312722","url":null,"abstract":"A comment on the theoretical consequences of the credit crunch on neoliberalism as a development doctrine.","PeriodicalId":383948,"journal":{"name":"New Institutional Economics","volume":"57 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2008-12-07","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"126017528","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Who Should be Given More Foreign Aid? 谁应该得到更多的外援?
Pub Date : 2008-12-01 DOI: 10.1111/j.1468-0106.2008.00423.x
Wenli Cheng, DingSheng Zhang
This paper presents a simple model to investigate the effectiveness of foreign aid. It shows that foreign aid is most effective if it is given to a market economy with relatively high transaction efficiency. If transaction efficiency in a market economy is low due to, for instance, bad institutions or policies, then foreign aid will either be largely dissipated as transaction costs or can even lead to retrogression of market activities. In either case, it will be more effective to give foreign aid to poor primitive economies with no developed markets. Copyright 2008 The Authors. Journal compilation 2008 Blackwell Publishing Asia Pty Ltd
本文提出了一个简单的模型来考察外援的有效性。研究表明,在交易效率相对较高的市场经济中,对外援助是最有效的。如果市场经济中的交易效率低是因为,例如,糟糕的制度或政策,那么外援要么大部分作为交易成本消散,要么甚至可能导致市场活动的倒退。无论哪种情况,向没有发达市场的贫穷原始经济体提供外援都将更为有效。版权所有2008作者。2008年Blackwell出版亚洲有限公司
{"title":"Who Should be Given More Foreign Aid?","authors":"Wenli Cheng, DingSheng Zhang","doi":"10.1111/j.1468-0106.2008.00423.x","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0106.2008.00423.x","url":null,"abstract":"This paper presents a simple model to investigate the effectiveness of foreign aid. It shows that foreign aid is most effective if it is given to a market economy with relatively high transaction efficiency. If transaction efficiency in a market economy is low due to, for instance, bad institutions or policies, then foreign aid will either be largely dissipated as transaction costs or can even lead to retrogression of market activities. In either case, it will be more effective to give foreign aid to poor primitive economies with no developed markets. Copyright 2008 The Authors. Journal compilation 2008 Blackwell Publishing Asia Pty Ltd","PeriodicalId":383948,"journal":{"name":"New Institutional Economics","volume":"369 ","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2008-12-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"133652303","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
期刊
New Institutional Economics
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1