首页 > 最新文献

Household Finance eJournal最新文献

英文 中文
Does Lasting Behavior Change Require Knowledge Change? Evidence from Savings Interventions for Young Adults 持久的行为改变需要知识的改变吗?来自年轻人储蓄干预的证据
Pub Date : 2020-10-01 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3710862
Samantha Horn, Julian C. Jamison, Dean S. Karlan, Jonathan Zinman
Is financial knowledge change necessary for lasting savings behavior change? Or, akin to the canonical Friedman billiards player, can behavior persist “as if” such knowledge is held? We randomize 240 Ugandan young-adult clubs to financial education, savings account access, both, or neither. Each education arm, but not the account-only arm, increases financial knowledge and trust in banks at one-year. But at five-years the knowledge effects disappear, and the trust effects diminish. Savings activity, wealth, and income increase at both one-year and five-years for all treatment arms, suggesting that knowledge change is unnecessary for lasting impacts on behavior and outcomes.
金融知识的改变对持久储蓄行为的改变是必要的吗?或者,就像典型的弗里德曼台球选手所说的那样,行为能否“就像”掌握了这些知识一样持续下去?我们将240个乌干达青年俱乐部随机分配到金融教育,储蓄账户访问,两者都有,或者两者都没有。每个教育部门,但不只是账户部门,在一年期间增加了金融知识和对银行的信任。但5年后,知识效应消失,信任效应减弱。所有治疗组的储蓄活动、财富和收入在1年和5年后都有所增加,这表明知识的改变对于行为和结果的持久影响是不必要的。
{"title":"Does Lasting Behavior Change Require Knowledge Change? Evidence from Savings Interventions for Young Adults","authors":"Samantha Horn, Julian C. Jamison, Dean S. Karlan, Jonathan Zinman","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3710862","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3710862","url":null,"abstract":"Is financial knowledge change necessary for lasting savings behavior change? Or, akin to the canonical Friedman billiards player, can behavior persist “as if” such knowledge is held? We randomize 240 Ugandan young-adult clubs to financial education, savings account access, both, or neither. Each education arm, but not the account-only arm, increases financial knowledge and trust in banks at one-year. But at five-years the knowledge effects disappear, and the trust effects diminish. Savings activity, wealth, and income increase at both one-year and five-years for all treatment arms, suggesting that knowledge change is unnecessary for lasting impacts on behavior and outcomes.","PeriodicalId":428959,"journal":{"name":"Household Finance eJournal","volume":"21 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2020-10-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"133589399","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 8
Population Growth, Building, and Banking 人口增长、建筑和银行业
Pub Date : 2020-09-29 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3701501
A. Antoniades
US counties with higher population growth prior to 2000, experienced higher growth in residential construction in the run-up to the financial crisis of 2007-08. Banks operating in these counties shifted their loan portfolios more aggressively towards construction loans and away from other non-real estate loans. Although shifts towards construction lending that followed local construction activity did not lead to higher loan default rates, more aggressive shifts did.
2000年之前人口增长率较高的美国县,在2007-08年金融危机爆发前,住宅建设的增长率也较高。在这些县经营的银行更积极地将贷款组合转向建筑贷款,远离其他非房地产贷款。虽然随着地方建筑活动而转向建筑贷款并没有导致更高的贷款违约率,但更激进的转变确实导致了更高的贷款违约率。
{"title":"Population Growth, Building, and Banking","authors":"A. Antoniades","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3701501","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3701501","url":null,"abstract":"US counties with higher population growth prior to 2000, experienced higher growth in residential construction in the run-up to the financial crisis of 2007-08. Banks operating in these counties shifted their loan portfolios more aggressively towards construction loans and away from other non-real estate loans. Although shifts towards construction lending that followed local construction activity did not lead to higher loan default rates, more aggressive shifts did.","PeriodicalId":428959,"journal":{"name":"Household Finance eJournal","volume":"132 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2020-09-29","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"122173353","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Designing Dealer Compensation in the Auto Loan Market: Implications from a Policy Experiment 汽车贷款市场中经销商补偿的设计:一个政策实验的启示
Pub Date : 2020-09-29 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3702092
Zhenling Jiang, Y. Wei, T. Chan, Naser Hamdi
We study the design of dealer compensation policy in the indirect auto lending market, where most lenders give dealers the discretion to mark up interest rates. To protect consumers from potential discrimination by the dealer discretion, several banks switched to a new compensation scheme by fixing the markup as a percentage of the loan amount. We document that the market share of these banks responded positively (negatively) in the consumer segment where the policy increased (decreased) the interest rate — a reversal of the usual demand curve — which highlights the influence of dealers on the bank choice for financing loans. Accordingly, we develop and estimate an empirical model that allows for dealer–consumer bargaining, which depends on both the dealers' and the consumers' utility. Based on the estimation results, we explore alternative compensation policies that also eliminate dealers' discretion. We show that a lump-sum compensation that pays dealers a fixed dollar amount per loan dominates the current policy for the banks in terms of gaining market share. This is because dealers' equivalent markup rates would better align with their bargaining power. Our study highlights the importance of accounting for the interests and bargaining power of middlemen in designing a compensation scheme.
本文研究了间接汽车贷款市场中大多数贷款人给予经销商提高利率的自由裁量权的经销商补偿政策设计。为了保护消费者免受经销商的潜在歧视,几家银行采用了一种新的补偿方案,将加价固定为贷款金额的一定百分比。我们的研究表明,这些银行的市场份额在消费者市场上的反应是积极的(消极的),因为政策提高了(降低了)利率——与通常的需求曲线相反——这突出了经销商对银行融资贷款选择的影响。因此,我们开发并估计了一个允许经销商与消费者讨价还价的经验模型,这取决于经销商和消费者的效用。基于估计结果,我们探索了消除经销商自由裁量权的替代补偿政策。我们表明,在获得市场份额方面,向经销商支付每笔贷款固定金额的一次性补偿占主导地位。这是因为经销商的同等加价率将更好地与他们的议价能力相一致。我们的研究强调了在设计补偿方案时考虑中间商的利益和议价能力的重要性。
{"title":"Designing Dealer Compensation in the Auto Loan Market: Implications from a Policy Experiment","authors":"Zhenling Jiang, Y. Wei, T. Chan, Naser Hamdi","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3702092","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3702092","url":null,"abstract":"We study the design of dealer compensation policy in the indirect auto lending market, where most lenders give dealers the discretion to mark up interest rates. To protect consumers from potential discrimination by the dealer discretion, several banks switched to a new compensation scheme by fixing the markup as a percentage of the loan amount. We document that the market share of these banks responded positively (negatively) in the consumer segment where the policy increased (decreased) the interest rate — a reversal of the usual demand curve — which highlights the influence of dealers on the bank choice for financing loans. Accordingly, we develop and estimate an empirical model that allows for dealer–consumer bargaining, which depends on both the dealers' and the consumers' utility. Based on the estimation results, we explore alternative compensation policies that also eliminate dealers' discretion. We show that a lump-sum compensation that pays dealers a fixed dollar amount per loan dominates the current policy for the banks in terms of gaining market share. This is because dealers' equivalent markup rates would better align with their bargaining power. Our study highlights the importance of accounting for the interests and bargaining power of middlemen in designing a compensation scheme.","PeriodicalId":428959,"journal":{"name":"Household Finance eJournal","volume":"60 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2020-09-29","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"120848294","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
A Case Study in Multiperiod Portfolio Optimization: A Classic Problem Revisited 多期投资组合优化的案例研究:一个经典问题的重访
Pub Date : 2020-09-23 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3697948
M. Tarlie
Conventional wisdom holds that multiperiod portfolio optimization problems are best, if not only, solved by dynamic programming. But dynamic programming suffers from the curse of dimensionality whereby optimization becomes intractable as time horizon and number of assets increase, thereby limiting its practical applications. In this paper I show for a classic multiperiod investment problem that a feed-forward, open-loop procedure, amenable to solution by conventional methods (e.g. calculus of variations) and not subject to the curse of dimensionality, generates `here and now' portfolios identical to those generated by the dynamic programming approach. The analytic results in this paper demonstrate that for this classic problem a feed forward approach is not inferior to the more common backward induction approach, suggesting that an `open-loop with recourse' process is a viable closed-loop approach for some practically useful multiperiod investment problems.
传统观点认为,多期投资组合优化问题最好的解决方法是动态规划。但是动态规划受维度的困扰,随着时间范围和资产数量的增加,优化变得难以处理,从而限制了它的实际应用。在本文中,我展示了一个经典的多周期投资问题,前馈,开环过程,可以用传统方法(例如变分法)解决,不受维度诅咒的影响,生成“此时此地”的投资组合,与动态规划方法生成的投资组合相同。本文的分析结果表明,对于这一经典问题,前馈方法并不比一般的后向归纳法差,这表明对于一些实际有用的多周期投资问题,“带追索权的开环”过程是一种可行的闭环方法。
{"title":"A Case Study in Multiperiod Portfolio Optimization: A Classic Problem Revisited","authors":"M. Tarlie","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3697948","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3697948","url":null,"abstract":"Conventional wisdom holds that multiperiod portfolio optimization problems are best, if not only, solved by dynamic programming. But dynamic programming suffers from the curse of dimensionality whereby optimization becomes intractable as time horizon and number of assets increase, thereby limiting its practical applications. In this paper I show for a classic multiperiod investment problem that a feed-forward, open-loop procedure, amenable to solution by conventional methods (e.g. calculus of variations) and not subject to the curse of dimensionality, generates `here and now' portfolios identical to those generated by the dynamic programming approach. The analytic results in this paper demonstrate that for this classic problem a feed forward approach is not inferior to the more common backward induction approach, suggesting that an `open-loop with recourse' process is a viable closed-loop approach for some practically useful multiperiod investment problems.","PeriodicalId":428959,"journal":{"name":"Household Finance eJournal","volume":"13 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2020-09-23","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"130460991","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
The Market for Reverse Mortgages among Older Americans 美国老年人的反向抵押贷款市场
Pub Date : 2020-09-15 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3693460
C. Mayer, Stephanie Moulton
This paper examines the usage of reverse mortgages among mortgage borrowers, as well as rejected applicants for new mortgage credit who are age 62+. We find that 17-27 percent of actual and rejected borrowers would have qualified for a HECM reverse mortgage, or nine to 14 times the size of the actual HECM market. The existence of a large number of seniors with an existing mortgage or taking out a new mortgage with quite high LTVs (57-65%, depending on the product) suggests that many seniors do, in fact utilize home equity in order to fund their retirement. Yet they choose products that require monthly payments lasting decades into retirement and rising as a share of (declining) income as they age. We consider a number of possible explanations for why seniors in the US do not spend home equity and rely on loans with high payments, including precautionary savings for health shocks, bequest motives, high costs of reverse mortgages, and the lack of brand name institutions in the reverse mortgage business.
本文研究了反向抵押贷款在抵押贷款借款人中的使用情况,以及62岁以上的新抵押贷款申请人被拒绝的情况。我们发现,17- 27%的实际和被拒绝的借款人有资格获得HECM反向抵押贷款,或者是实际HECM市场规模的9到14倍。大量老年人有现有的抵押贷款或以相当高的ltv(57-65%,取决于产品)申请新的抵押贷款,这表明许多老年人实际上利用房屋净值来为他们的退休生活提供资金。然而,他们选择的产品需要每月支付,持续几十年,直到退休,随着年龄的增长,收入的比例会上升(下降)。我们考虑了一些可能的解释,为什么美国的老年人不花房屋净值,而依赖于高还款贷款,包括预防健康冲击的储蓄,遗赠动机,反向抵押贷款的高成本,以及反向抵押贷款业务中缺乏品牌机构。
{"title":"The Market for Reverse Mortgages among Older Americans","authors":"C. Mayer, Stephanie Moulton","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3693460","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3693460","url":null,"abstract":"This paper examines the usage of reverse mortgages among mortgage borrowers, as well as rejected applicants for new mortgage credit who are age 62+. We find that 17-27 percent of actual and rejected borrowers would have qualified for a HECM reverse mortgage, or nine to 14 times the size of the actual HECM market. The existence of a large number of seniors with an existing mortgage or taking out a new mortgage with quite high LTVs (57-65%, depending on the product) suggests that many seniors do, in fact utilize home equity in order to fund their retirement. Yet they choose products that require monthly payments lasting decades into retirement and rising as a share of (declining) income as they age. We consider a number of possible explanations for why seniors in the US do not spend home equity and rely on loans with high payments, including precautionary savings for health shocks, bequest motives, high costs of reverse mortgages, and the lack of brand name institutions in the reverse mortgage business.","PeriodicalId":428959,"journal":{"name":"Household Finance eJournal","volume":"14 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2020-09-15","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"115502666","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 6
The Distributional Consequences of Belief Heterogeneity 信念异质性的分布结果
Pub Date : 2020-09-10 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3654113
Nigel McClung
This paper studies a life-cycle model economy in which agents utilize idiosyncratic information to forecast personal income risk. Agents either inherit full information (``dynastic households") or learn to forecast lifetime income using personal employment data given incorrect initial beliefs (``non-dynastic households"). We find that the distribution of initial beliefs regarding the transition probabilities into and out of unemployment greatly impact both aggregate savings and the stationary wealth distribution in a simple model economy. The wealth Gini coefficient in a model economy comprised solely of dynastic agents is 18%-52% lower than in the simulations with both dynastic and non-dynastic households. Optimistic households accumulate less wealth and are more likely to enter states of unemployment with little or no savings and pessimistic households over-accumulate wealth relative to households who inherit correct beliefs. Further, our framework shows how the welfare of rational agents and the value of holding correct beliefs depends on the beliefs of other agents.
本文研究了agent利用特质信息预测个人收入风险的生命周期模型经济。代理人要么继承完整的信息(“王朝家庭”),要么学习使用不正确的初始信念(“非王朝家庭”)的个人就业数据来预测终身收入。我们发现,在一个简单的模型经济中,关于失业转移概率和失业转移概率的初始信念分布极大地影响了总储蓄和固定财富分配。仅由王朝主体组成的模型经济中的财富基尼系数比具有王朝和非王朝家庭的模拟低18%-52%。乐观的家庭积累较少的财富,更有可能进入失业状态,很少或没有储蓄,而悲观的家庭相对于继承正确信念的家庭积累过多的财富。此外,我们的框架显示了理性主体的福利和持有正确信念的价值如何取决于其他主体的信念。
{"title":"The Distributional Consequences of Belief Heterogeneity","authors":"Nigel McClung","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3654113","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3654113","url":null,"abstract":"This paper studies a life-cycle model economy in which agents utilize idiosyncratic information to forecast personal income risk. Agents either inherit full information (``dynastic households\") or learn to forecast lifetime income using personal employment data given incorrect initial beliefs (``non-dynastic households\"). We find that the distribution of initial beliefs regarding the transition probabilities into and out of unemployment greatly impact both aggregate savings and the stationary wealth distribution in a simple model economy. The wealth Gini coefficient in a model economy comprised solely of dynastic agents is 18%-52% lower than in the simulations with both dynastic and non-dynastic households. Optimistic households accumulate less wealth and are more likely to enter states of unemployment with little or no savings and pessimistic households over-accumulate wealth relative to households who inherit correct beliefs. Further, our framework shows how the welfare of rational agents and the value of holding correct beliefs depends on the beliefs of other agents.","PeriodicalId":428959,"journal":{"name":"Household Finance eJournal","volume":"215 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2020-09-10","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"121321339","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Are Investors Aware of Climate-Related Transition Risks? Evidence from Mutual Fund Flows 投资者是否意识到与气候相关的转型风险?共同基金流动的证据
Pub Date : 2020-09-03 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3685675
J. Reboredo, L. Otero
Abstract Using information on climate transition risks embedded in US equity mutual fund portfolios, we report evidence that mutual fund investors consider climate-related transition risk to be an undesirable fund feature and accordingly allocate more money to funds with lower climate-related transition risk. The size of the impact of this risk on fund flows differs depending on the performance expectations of investors and the socially responsible focus and sustainability of the fund. Our results suggest that mutual fund investors are aware of climate-related transition risks as evidenced by their investment decisions.
利用美国股票型共同基金投资组合中嵌入的气候转型风险信息,我们报告了共同基金投资者认为气候相关转型风险是一个不受欢迎的基金特征,并相应地将更多资金分配给气候相关转型风险较低的基金的证据。这种风险对资金流动的影响大小取决于投资者的业绩预期以及基金的社会责任重点和可持续性。我们的研究结果表明,共同基金投资者意识到气候相关的转型风险,这在他们的投资决策中得到了证明。
{"title":"Are Investors Aware of Climate-Related Transition Risks? Evidence from Mutual Fund Flows","authors":"J. Reboredo, L. Otero","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3685675","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3685675","url":null,"abstract":"Abstract Using information on climate transition risks embedded in US equity mutual fund portfolios, we report evidence that mutual fund investors consider climate-related transition risk to be an undesirable fund feature and accordingly allocate more money to funds with lower climate-related transition risk. The size of the impact of this risk on fund flows differs depending on the performance expectations of investors and the socially responsible focus and sustainability of the fund. Our results suggest that mutual fund investors are aware of climate-related transition risks as evidenced by their investment decisions.","PeriodicalId":428959,"journal":{"name":"Household Finance eJournal","volume":"1 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2020-09-03","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"122542572","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 14
Mortgage Prepayment, Race, and Monetary Policy 抵押贷款提前支付,种族和货币政策
Pub Date : 2020-09-01 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3697625
Kristopher Gerardi, P. Willen, D. Zhang
This paper documents large differences in mortgage prepayment behavior across racial and ethnic groups in the United States, which have significant implications for monetary policy, inequality, and pricing. Using a novel data set that combines administrative data on mortgage performance with information on race and ethnicity, we show that Black and Hispanic white borrowers have significantly lower prepayment rates compared with Non-Hispanic white borrowers, holding income, credit score, and equity constant. This gap is on the order of 50 percent and largely reflects different sensitivities to movements in market interest rates, and was particularly pronounced during QE1. Differences in prepayment speeds result in large disparities between white and minority borrowers in the distribution of rates paid on outstanding mortgages, which widens during periods of low mortgage rates and high refinance volumes. From 2010 to 2014, Black borrowers were paying 30 to 45 basis points more on average than Non-Hispanic whites despite only a small gap of about 5 basis points between the groups at the time of mortgage origination. The large differences in prepayment behavior have important pricing implications, as they suggest that minority borrowers are overpaying for their prepayment option. Our results show that inequality in mortgage markets is larger than previously realized and is exacerbated by expansionary monetary policy.
本文记录了美国不同种族和族裔群体在抵押贷款提前支付行为上的巨大差异,这对货币政策、不平等和定价具有重要意义。我们使用一个新的数据集,将抵押贷款绩效的管理数据与种族和民族信息相结合,结果表明,与非西班牙裔白人借款人相比,黑人和西班牙裔白人借款人的提前还款率、持有收入、信用评分和权益常数显著降低。这一差距约为50%,在很大程度上反映了对市场利率变动的不同敏感性,在第一轮量化宽松期间尤为明显。提前还款速度的差异导致了白人和少数族裔借款人在未偿还抵押贷款利率分配上的巨大差异,这种差异在抵押贷款利率较低和再融资量较高的时期会扩大。从2010年到2014年,黑人借款人平均比非西班牙裔白人多支付30到45个基点,尽管在抵押贷款发起时,这两个群体之间只有大约5个基点的微小差距。提前还款行为的巨大差异具有重要的定价含义,因为它们表明少数族裔借款人为他们的提前还款选择支付了过高的费用。我们的研究结果表明,抵押贷款市场的不平等比以前认识到的更大,并因扩张性货币政策而加剧。
{"title":"Mortgage Prepayment, Race, and Monetary Policy","authors":"Kristopher Gerardi, P. Willen, D. Zhang","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3697625","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3697625","url":null,"abstract":"This paper documents large differences in mortgage prepayment behavior across racial and ethnic groups in the United States, which have significant implications for monetary policy, inequality, and pricing. Using a novel data set that combines administrative data on mortgage performance with information on race and ethnicity, we show that Black and Hispanic white borrowers have significantly lower prepayment rates compared with Non-Hispanic white borrowers, holding income, credit score, and equity constant. This gap is on the order of 50 percent and largely reflects different sensitivities to movements in market interest rates, and was particularly pronounced during QE1. Differences in prepayment speeds result in large disparities between white and minority borrowers in the distribution of rates paid on outstanding mortgages, which widens during periods of low mortgage rates and high refinance volumes. From 2010 to 2014, Black borrowers were paying 30 to 45 basis points more on average than Non-Hispanic whites despite only a small gap of about 5 basis points between the groups at the time of mortgage origination. The large differences in prepayment behavior have important pricing implications, as they suggest that minority borrowers are overpaying for their prepayment option. Our results show that inequality in mortgage markets is larger than previously realized and is exacerbated by expansionary monetary policy.","PeriodicalId":428959,"journal":{"name":"Household Finance eJournal","volume":"34 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2020-09-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"125395418","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 34
Education and FinTech Adoption: Evidence from China 教育和金融科技的采用:来自中国的证据
Pub Date : 2020-09-01 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3765224
G. Niu, Qi Wang, Yang Zhou
In this paper, we explore the role of education in household FinTech adoption. Using representative nationwide household data from the 2017 China Household Finance Survey, we employ the change in China’s compulsory schooling law in the 1980s as an instrumental variable for educational attainment. We find that among Chinese households, education has statistically significant and economically important effects on the use of various FinTech services, including digital banking, mobile payment, digital wealth management, and digital consumer credit. Further analysis indicates that exogeneous increases in education lead to higher levels of financial literacy and social trust, both of which are potential drivers of FinTech adoption. Our findings provide new insights into the importance of education for household financial decision making and technology adoption.
在本文中,我们探讨了教育在家庭金融科技采用中的作用。我们使用2017年中国家庭金融调查中具有代表性的全国家庭数据,将20世纪80年代中国义务教育法的变化作为受教育程度的工具变量。我们发现,在中国家庭中,教育对各种金融科技服务的使用具有统计意义和经济意义上的重要影响,包括数字银行、移动支付、数字财富管理和数字消费信贷。进一步的分析表明,教育的外来增加导致更高水平的金融知识和社会信任,这两者都是金融科技采用的潜在驱动因素。我们的研究结果为教育对家庭财务决策和技术采用的重要性提供了新的见解。
{"title":"Education and FinTech Adoption: Evidence from China","authors":"G. Niu, Qi Wang, Yang Zhou","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3765224","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3765224","url":null,"abstract":"In this paper, we explore the role of education in household FinTech adoption. Using representative nationwide household data from the 2017 China Household Finance Survey, we employ the change in China’s compulsory schooling law in the 1980s as an instrumental variable for educational attainment. We find that among Chinese households, education has statistically significant and economically important effects on the use of various FinTech services, including digital banking, mobile payment, digital wealth management, and digital consumer credit. Further analysis indicates that exogeneous increases in education lead to higher levels of financial literacy and social trust, both of which are potential drivers of FinTech adoption. Our findings provide new insights into the importance of education for household financial decision making and technology adoption.","PeriodicalId":428959,"journal":{"name":"Household Finance eJournal","volume":"81 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2020-09-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"126255522","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 6
Household Wealth as a Factor of Economic Growth: A Case Study of Italy 家庭财富对经济增长的影响:以意大利为例
Pub Date : 2020-09-01 DOI: 10.5709/ce.1897-9254.408
Iacopo Odoardi, C. Pagliari
The wealth possessed by households, identifiable as so-called net worth, varies greatly in quantity and form between different socioeconomic contexts. We describe several forms of wealth typically owned by consumer households, considering their economic and social effects. We analyze the economic role of the wealth forms that compose the households’ net worth (real and financial assets minus the debt) in a panel data analysis of Italian regions, and we suggest a possible alternative use for a specific part of household net worth. In particular, the well-known financial share is already useful and exploited by the economic system, as confirmed empirically. Instead, a share of the real assets could prove useful as a source of support for the economy if some conditions are met. The results of the regional analysis illustrate the supposed lack of contribution and we suggest how the net worth not “fully exploited” could be integrated in the economic cycle, activating a propulsive mechanism to start “accelerated” growth processes.
家庭拥有的财富,即所谓的净资产,在不同的社会经济背景下,在数量和形式上都有很大差异。考虑到它们的经济和社会影响,我们描述了消费家庭通常拥有的几种财富形式。我们在意大利地区的面板数据分析中分析了构成家庭净资产(实际和金融资产减去债务)的财富形式的经济作用,并提出了家庭净资产特定部分的可能替代用途。特别是,众所周知的财政份额已经被经济系统利用,这是经验证实的。相反,如果满足某些条件,一部分实物资产可能会被证明是支持经济的有用来源。区域分析的结果说明了假定的缺乏贡献,我们建议如何将未“充分利用”的净值纳入经济周期,激活推进机制以启动“加速”增长过程。
{"title":"Household Wealth as a Factor of Economic Growth: A Case Study of Italy","authors":"Iacopo Odoardi, C. Pagliari","doi":"10.5709/ce.1897-9254.408","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.5709/ce.1897-9254.408","url":null,"abstract":"The wealth possessed by households, identifiable as so-called net worth, varies greatly in quantity and form between different socioeconomic contexts. We describe several forms of wealth typically owned by consumer households, considering their economic and social effects. We analyze the economic role of the wealth forms that compose the households’ net worth (real and financial assets minus the debt) in a panel data analysis of Italian regions, and we suggest a possible alternative use for a specific part of household net worth. In particular, the well-known financial share is already useful and exploited by the economic system, as confirmed empirically. Instead, a share of the real assets could prove useful as a source of support for the economy if some conditions are met. The results of the regional analysis illustrate the supposed lack of contribution and we suggest how the net worth not “fully exploited” could be integrated in the economic cycle, activating a propulsive mechanism to start “accelerated” growth processes.","PeriodicalId":428959,"journal":{"name":"Household Finance eJournal","volume":"76 3","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2020-09-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"120978195","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
期刊
Household Finance eJournal
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1