首页 > 最新文献

ERN: Productivity (Topic)最新文献

英文 中文
Productivity and the Financial Services Sector – How to Achieve New Heights 生产力与金融服务业-如何达到新的高度
Pub Date : 2019-10-17 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3478694
Farah Omran, Jeremy M. Kronick
Advanced economies must focus on improving productivity in order to achieve long-term sustainable economic growth. Increases in traditional inputs – labour and capital – can only go so far before generating diminishing returns. These economies, such as Canada’s, must then look beyond traditional inputs and seek to increase their productivity through competition and innovation. Financial services have a vital role to play in these efforts.

Unfortunately, Canada’s productivity growth has lagged behind that of its international peers for the past 15 years. The financial services sector, with its unique ability to improve its own productivity and the overall economy’s, has also fallen short in contributing to Canada’s overall productivity growth over that period. Improving the financial services sector’s productivity would not only boost its performance, but also that of Canada’s economy as a whole. In this Commentary, we focus on Canada’s financial services’ regulatory framework and its impact on productivity growth through three different channels: competition, attracting capital, and the allocation of capital.

Canada’s current regulatory framework has improved over the past decade; however, more could be done to remove regulatory barriers that hamper competition, the progress of innovative firms, and better reflect international best practices. Restrictive regulation and policy hinder productivity growth through their effects on competition, the environment they create for attracting foreign capital, and potential distortions in the allocation of capital.

To address these challenges, this Commentary recommends the following:

• a flexible regulatory approach that is both function based and proportional to functional risk;

• regulatory mandates that include more explicit references to competition as a way of spurring innovation;

• monitoring the new rules around the flexibility of banks to participate and invest in fintechs and other innovative technology-led institutions;

• improving the collection and sharing of financial market data between federal and provincial regulators;

• improving access for small and medium-sized businesses to affordable capital; and

• changing the incentive structure so that financial institutions move away from a focus on mortgage lending to one on business lending.
发达经济体必须把重点放在提高生产率上,以实现长期可持续的经济增长。传统投入——劳动力和资本——的增加只能到此为止,否则就会产生递减的回报。这些经济体,如加拿大,必须超越传统的投入,寻求通过竞争和创新来提高生产率。金融服务在这些努力中发挥着至关重要的作用。不幸的是,在过去的15年里,加拿大的生产率增长一直落后于国际同行。金融服务部门在提高自身生产率和整体经济生产率方面具有独特的能力,但在此期间对加拿大整体生产率增长的贡献也不足。提高金融服务业的生产率不仅会提高其表现,还会提高加拿大整体经济的表现。在本评论中,我们重点关注加拿大金融服务监管框架及其通过三个不同渠道对生产率增长的影响:竞争、吸引资本和资本配置。加拿大目前的监管框架在过去十年中有所改善;然而,在消除阻碍竞争、创新企业进步的监管障碍以及更好地反映国际最佳实践方面,还可以做更多的工作。限制性规章和政策对竞争的影响、它们为吸引外国资本所创造的环境以及资本分配的潜在扭曲,阻碍了生产率的增长。为了应对这些挑战,本评论建议:•灵活的监管方法,既要基于功能,又要与功能风险成比例;•监管任务,包括更明确地提及竞争作为刺激创新的一种方式;•监测围绕银行参与和投资金融科技和其他创新技术主导机构的灵活性的新规则;•改善联邦和省级监管机构之间金融市场数据的收集和共享改善中小企业获得负担得起的资金的途径;•改变激励结构,使金融机构从专注于抵押贷款转向专注于企业贷款。
{"title":"Productivity and the Financial Services Sector – How to Achieve New Heights","authors":"Farah Omran, Jeremy M. Kronick","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3478694","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3478694","url":null,"abstract":"Advanced economies must focus on improving productivity in order to achieve long-term sustainable economic growth. Increases in traditional inputs – labour and capital – can only go so far before generating diminishing returns. These economies, such as Canada’s, must then look beyond traditional inputs and seek to increase their productivity through competition and innovation. Financial services have a vital role to play in these efforts.<br><br>Unfortunately, Canada’s productivity growth has lagged behind that of its international peers for the past 15 years. The financial services sector, with its unique ability to improve its own productivity and the overall economy’s, has also fallen short in contributing to Canada’s overall productivity growth over that period. Improving the financial services sector’s productivity would not only boost its performance, but also that of Canada’s economy as a whole. In this Commentary, we focus on Canada’s financial services’ regulatory framework and its impact on productivity growth through three different channels: competition, attracting capital, and the allocation of capital.<br><br>Canada’s current regulatory framework has improved over the past decade; however, more could be done to remove regulatory barriers that hamper competition, the progress of innovative firms, and better reflect international best practices. Restrictive regulation and policy hinder productivity growth through their effects on competition, the environment they create for attracting foreign capital, and potential distortions in the allocation of capital.<br><br>To address these challenges, this Commentary recommends the following:<br><br>• a flexible regulatory approach that is both function based and proportional to functional risk;<br><br>• regulatory mandates that include more explicit references to competition as a way of spurring innovation;<br><br>• monitoring the new rules around the flexibility of banks to participate and invest in fintechs and other innovative technology-led institutions;<br><br>• improving the collection and sharing of financial market data between federal and provincial regulators;<br><br>• improving access for small and medium-sized businesses to affordable capital; and<br><br>• changing the incentive structure so that financial institutions move away from a focus on mortgage lending to one on business lending.<br>","PeriodicalId":448105,"journal":{"name":"ERN: Productivity (Topic)","volume":"35 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2019-10-17","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"132503016","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 7
Measuring Productivity Dispersion: A Parametric Approach Using the Lévy Alpha-Stable Distribution 测量生产率离散:一种使用lsamy α稳定分布的参数化方法
Pub Date : 2019-09-30 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3468301
Jangho Yang, T. Heinrich, Julian Winkler, F. Lafond, P. Koutroumpis, J. Farmer
Productivity levels and growth are extremely heterogeneous among firms. A vast literature has developed to explain the origins of productivity shocks, their dispersion, evolution and their relationship to the business cycle. We examine in detail the distribution of labor productivity levels and growth, and observe that they exhibit heavy tails. We propose to model these distributions using the four parameter Levy stable distribution, a natural candidate deriving from the generalised Central Limit Theorem. We show that it is a better fit than several standard alternatives, and is remarkably consistent over time, countries and sectors. In all samples considered, the tail parameter is such that the theoretical variance of the distribution is infinite, so that the sample standard deviation increases with sample size. We find a consistent positive skewness, a markedly different behaviour between the left and right tails, and a positive relationship between productivity and size. The distributional approach allows us to test different measures of dispersion and find that productivity dispersion has slightly decreased over the past decade.
企业之间的生产率水平和增长是极不相同的。已有大量文献解释生产率冲击的起源、分散、演变及其与商业周期的关系。我们详细考察了劳动生产率水平和增长的分布,并观察到它们表现出沉重的尾巴。我们建议使用四参数Levy稳定分布来建模这些分布,这是由广义中心极限定理推导出来的自然候选分布。我们表明,它比几种标准替代方案更适合,并且在时间、国家和行业方面具有显著的一致性。在所有考虑的样本中,尾部参数使得分布的理论方差无穷大,因此样本标准差随样本量的增大而增大。我们发现了一个一致的正偏度,左右尾巴之间的行为明显不同,生产力和规模之间的正关系。分布方法允许我们测试不同的分散度量,并发现生产力分散在过去十年中略有下降。
{"title":"Measuring Productivity Dispersion: A Parametric Approach Using the Lévy Alpha-Stable Distribution","authors":"Jangho Yang, T. Heinrich, Julian Winkler, F. Lafond, P. Koutroumpis, J. Farmer","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3468301","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3468301","url":null,"abstract":"Productivity levels and growth are extremely heterogeneous among firms. A vast literature has developed to explain the origins of productivity shocks, their dispersion, evolution and their relationship to the business cycle. We examine in detail the distribution of labor productivity levels and growth, and observe that they exhibit heavy tails. We propose to model these distributions using the four parameter Levy stable distribution, a natural candidate deriving from the generalised Central Limit Theorem. We show that it is a better fit than several standard alternatives, and is remarkably consistent over time, countries and sectors. In all samples considered, the tail parameter is such that the theoretical variance of the distribution is infinite, so that the sample standard deviation increases with sample size. We find a consistent positive skewness, a markedly different behaviour between the left and right tails, and a positive relationship between productivity and size. The distributional approach allows us to test different measures of dispersion and find that productivity dispersion has slightly decreased over the past decade.","PeriodicalId":448105,"journal":{"name":"ERN: Productivity (Topic)","volume":"11 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2019-09-30","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"124835966","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 6
Conference Presentations and Academic Publishing 会议报告和学术出版
Pub Date : 2019-09-01 DOI: 10.3386/w26240
Y. Gorodnichenko, Tho Pham, Oleksandr Talavera
Abstract This study contributes to the existing literature on the impact of conference presentations on career progression by quantifying the predictive power of conferences for publication success. Examining outcomes for more than 4000 papers presented at three leading economics conferences over the 2006–2012 period, we find a positive link between conference presentations and the publishing probability in high-quality journals. This impact is most profound for prominent authors and male authors. In contrast, lesser known authors and female authors appear to gain less from conferences. Additionally, participating in major conferences is also associated with improved metrics for other measures of academic success such as the number of citations or abstract views. Further examination shows that annual meetings of the American Economic Association are particularly valuable in these dimensions.
摘要本研究通过量化会议对发表成功的预测能力,对现有的关于会议演讲对职业发展影响的文献进行了补充。研究了2006-2012年期间在三个主要经济学会议上发表的4000多篇论文的结果,我们发现会议演讲与在高质量期刊上发表的概率之间存在正相关关系。这种影响对著名作家和男性作家最为深远。相比之下,知名度较低的作者和女性作者从会议中获得的收益似乎较少。此外,参加大型会议也与其他衡量学术成功的指标(如引用次数或抽象观点)的改进有关。进一步的研究表明,美国经济协会的年度会议在这些方面特别有价值。
{"title":"Conference Presentations and Academic Publishing","authors":"Y. Gorodnichenko, Tho Pham, Oleksandr Talavera","doi":"10.3386/w26240","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.3386/w26240","url":null,"abstract":"Abstract This study contributes to the existing literature on the impact of conference presentations on career progression by quantifying the predictive power of conferences for publication success. Examining outcomes for more than 4000 papers presented at three leading economics conferences over the 2006–2012 period, we find a positive link between conference presentations and the publishing probability in high-quality journals. This impact is most profound for prominent authors and male authors. In contrast, lesser known authors and female authors appear to gain less from conferences. Additionally, participating in major conferences is also associated with improved metrics for other measures of academic success such as the number of citations or abstract views. Further examination shows that annual meetings of the American Economic Association are particularly valuable in these dimensions.","PeriodicalId":448105,"journal":{"name":"ERN: Productivity (Topic)","volume":"211 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2019-09-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"123017398","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 9
How Can Inclusive Agricultural Health Policy Intervention Promote Shared Agricultural Productivity in Nigeria? Evidence from Randomized Control Trial 包容性农业卫生政策干预如何促进尼日利亚共享农业生产力?随机对照试验证据
Pub Date : 2019-07-01 DOI: 10.3386/W26043
T. Olowogbon, R. Babatunde, E. Asiedu
We engaged randomized control trial to measure the effects of an agricultural health training intervention among 480 randomly assigned crop farmers from 24 farming communities in Nigeria. Structured questionnaire, interviews and random farm visit were used for data collection. The intervention component includes one-time village level agricultural health training and a three-month farm safety mobile text messaging follow up. We engaged a peer-developed module covering safe ergonomic practices and safe use of agrochemicals for the training. Findings from the study revealed that every one day increase in sickness absence decreases farmers’ labour productivity by 3% (p
我们采用随机对照试验,对尼日利亚24个农业社区随机分配的480名农民进行农业健康培训干预,以衡量其效果。采用结构化问卷法、访谈法和随机农场走访法进行数据收集。干预部分包括一次性村级农业卫生培训和为期三个月的农场安全移动短信跟踪。我们采用了一个同行开发的模块,涵盖安全的人体工程学实践和安全使用农用化学品的培训。研究结果显示,病假每增加一天,农民的劳动生产率就会降低3%
{"title":"How Can Inclusive Agricultural Health Policy Intervention Promote Shared Agricultural Productivity in Nigeria? Evidence from Randomized Control Trial","authors":"T. Olowogbon, R. Babatunde, E. Asiedu","doi":"10.3386/W26043","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.3386/W26043","url":null,"abstract":"We engaged randomized control trial to measure the effects of an agricultural health training intervention among 480 randomly assigned crop farmers from 24 farming communities in Nigeria. Structured questionnaire, interviews and random farm visit were used for data collection. The intervention component includes one-time village level agricultural health training and a three-month farm safety mobile text messaging follow up. We engaged a peer-developed module covering safe ergonomic practices and safe use of agrochemicals for the training. Findings from the study revealed that every one day increase in sickness absence decreases farmers’ labour productivity by 3% (p","PeriodicalId":448105,"journal":{"name":"ERN: Productivity (Topic)","volume":"44 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2019-07-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"130767865","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2
Ex-ante Evaluation of a Policy's Effect on Productivity: The Substitution and Scale Effects of Carbon Taxation on Power Plant Productivity 政策对生产率影响的事前评价:碳税对电厂生产率的替代效应和规模效应
Pub Date : 2019-06-04 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3223189
Zach Flynn
I develop a general framework for ex-ante analysis of a policy's effect on productivity. I use it to study the effect of carbon taxation on power plant productivity in the United States. Carbon taxes increase the price of burning fossil fuels, potentially encouraging power plants to be more fuel efficient. Whether carbon taxes do so is ambiguous because carbon taxes also increase the overall cost of electricity production, encouraging power plants to reduce output which reduces the plant's incentive to take costly actions to be more productive. I find carbon taxation reduces fuel productivity at commonly-proposed carbon taxes.
我开发了一个总体框架,用于预先分析一项政策对生产率的影响。我用它来研究碳税对美国发电厂生产率的影响。碳税提高了燃烧化石燃料的价格,可能会鼓励发电厂提高燃料效率。碳税是否能起到这样的作用尚不明确,因为碳税也增加了电力生产的总成本,鼓励发电厂减少产量,从而降低了发电厂采取昂贵措施提高生产率的动力。我发现碳税降低了通常提议的碳税的燃料生产率。
{"title":"Ex-ante Evaluation of a Policy's Effect on Productivity: The Substitution and Scale Effects of Carbon Taxation on Power Plant Productivity","authors":"Zach Flynn","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3223189","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3223189","url":null,"abstract":"I develop a general framework for ex-ante analysis of a policy's effect on productivity. I use it to study the effect of carbon taxation on power plant productivity in the United States. Carbon taxes increase the price of burning fossil fuels, potentially encouraging power plants to be more fuel efficient. Whether carbon taxes do so is ambiguous because carbon taxes also increase the overall cost of electricity production, encouraging power plants to reduce output which reduces the plant's incentive to take costly actions to be more productive. I find carbon taxation reduces fuel productivity at commonly-proposed carbon taxes.","PeriodicalId":448105,"journal":{"name":"ERN: Productivity (Topic)","volume":"1 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2019-06-04","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"129224618","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Resource Misallocation Leading to Productivity Gaps in Malaysia's Manufacturing Sector? 资源配置不当导致马来西亚制造业生产力差距?
Pub Date : 2019-05-01 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3400507
Lay Lian Chuah, Norman V. Loayza, H. Nguyen
The reallocation of resources from low- to high-productivity firms can generate large aggregate productivity gains. The paper uses data from the Malaysian manufacturing censuses of 2005 and 2010 to measure the country’s hypothetical productivity gains if all misallocation within industries are removed. Comparing the results across the two census waves, we conclude that efficiency gaps (that is, the degree of misallocation) in Malaysia have narrowed by one-fifth. The efficiency gaps, however, appear to be over 40 percent, indicating a substantial room for improvement. This is important, particularly if total factor productivity growth is expected to support future economic growth. The analysis in this paper accounts only for resource misallocation within sectors. There may be other, possibly large, resource misallocation across sectors. Closing those gaps could boost total factor productivity and gross domestic product growth even further.
资源从低生产率企业向高生产率企业的再配置可以产生巨大的总生产率收益。这篇论文使用了马来西亚2005年和2010年的制造业普查数据,来衡量如果剔除所有行业内的错配,该国假设的生产率增长。比较两次人口普查的结果,我们得出结论,马来西亚的效率差距(即分配不当的程度)缩小了五分之一。然而,效率差距似乎超过40%,表明有很大的改进空间。这一点很重要,尤其是在全要素生产率增长有望支撑未来经济增长的情况下。本文的分析只考虑了部门内部的资源错配。各部门之间可能还存在其他的、可能很大的资源错配。缩小这些差距可能进一步提振全要素生产率和国内生产总值(gdp)增长。
{"title":"Resource Misallocation Leading to Productivity Gaps in Malaysia's Manufacturing Sector?","authors":"Lay Lian Chuah, Norman V. Loayza, H. Nguyen","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3400507","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3400507","url":null,"abstract":"The reallocation of resources from low- to high-productivity firms can generate large aggregate productivity gains. The paper uses data from the Malaysian manufacturing censuses of 2005 and 2010 to measure the country’s hypothetical productivity gains if all misallocation within industries are removed. Comparing the results across the two census waves, we conclude that efficiency gaps (that is, the degree of misallocation) in Malaysia have narrowed by one-fifth. The efficiency gaps, however, appear to be over 40 percent, indicating a substantial room for improvement. This is important, particularly if total factor productivity growth is expected to support future economic growth. The analysis in this paper accounts only for resource misallocation within sectors. There may be other, possibly large, resource misallocation across sectors. Closing those gaps could boost total factor productivity and gross domestic product growth even further.","PeriodicalId":448105,"journal":{"name":"ERN: Productivity (Topic)","volume":"30 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2019-05-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"115813651","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
The Gender Gap in International Trade: Female-run Firms and the Exporter Productivity Premium 国际贸易中的性别差距:女性经营的公司和出口商的生产率溢价
Pub Date : 2019-04-01 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3377140
Astrid Krenz
Female-run firms are less likely to be exporters although they exert positive influence in various aspects in an economy and society. With a new and comprehensive data set on manufacturing plants, I investigate the exporter productivity premium of female-run firms in Germany. The results show that female-run firms gain a higher exporter-productivity premium than male-run firms. I find evidence for selection into exporting but no impact for learning from exporting for female-run exporting firms. These results give hint to discrimination barriers that female-run firms face when they are exporting as compared to male-run firm exporters.
尽管女性经营的公司在经济和社会的各个方面发挥积极影响,但她们不太可能成为出口商。利用一组新的、全面的制造业工厂数据,我调查了德国女性经营企业的出口商生产率溢价。结果表明,女性经营的企业比男性经营的企业获得更高的出口生产率溢价。我发现,对于女性经营的出口企业来说,选择出口是有证据的,但对从出口中学习没有影响。这些结果暗示了与男性经营的公司出口商相比,女性经营的公司在出口时面临的歧视障碍。
{"title":"The Gender Gap in International Trade: Female-run Firms and the Exporter Productivity Premium","authors":"Astrid Krenz","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3377140","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3377140","url":null,"abstract":"Female-run firms are less likely to be exporters although they exert positive influence in various aspects in an economy and society. With a new and comprehensive data set on manufacturing plants, I investigate the exporter productivity premium of female-run firms in Germany. The results show that female-run firms gain a higher exporter-productivity premium than male-run firms. I find evidence for selection into exporting but no impact for learning from exporting for female-run exporting firms. These results give hint to discrimination barriers that female-run firms face when they are exporting as compared to male-run firm exporters.","PeriodicalId":448105,"journal":{"name":"ERN: Productivity (Topic)","volume":"84 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2019-04-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"121913431","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Difusión de choques de productividad en redes productivas con competencia imperfecta y quiebra de empresas (Productivity Shocks Diffusion in Firms Networks With Imperfect Competition and Bankruptcy) 生产率冲击在不完全竞争和破产的企业网络中的扩散(生产率冲击在不完全竞争和破产的企业网络中的扩散)
Pub Date : 2019-03-06 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3347880
José Ramírez-Álvarez, W. Perez-Oviedo
Spanish Abstract: ¿Cómo se propagan choques microeconómicos heterogéneos en una red productiva? Este documento estudia la difusión de los choques de productividad en las redes de empresas, donde (1) existe una competencia imperfecta; y (2) la quiebra de las empresas es una posibilidad. Para (1) se supone que cada empresa debe elegir, para cada uno de sus insumos, un proveedor entre un subconjunto de empresas competidoras que fijan los precios de sus productos. Cuando lo hace, el comprador acepta el precio establecido por el proveedor y puede exigir, a ese precio, la cantidad que desea; sin embargo, con cierta probabilidad, la transacción podría fallar, por ejemplo, los productos no tienen la calidad o características esperadas, lo que causa pérdidas para el comprador. Esta probabilidad es mayor para los proveedores no habituales del comprador, que tienen que ofrecer precios más bajos para poder competir. En este contexto, el comprador no solo busca el mayor beneficio esperado, sino también el menor riesgo de pérdida, lo que lo lleva a asignar una probabilidad de contratación a cada proveedor. Por lo tanto, la decisión del comprador se modela de manera diferente de la maximización clásica de la utilidad esperada, lo que nos permite representar un continuo de poder de mercado, diferente del clásico Cournot o Bertrand. Con respecto a (2), una vez que se realizan las asignaciones de los contratos, se producen todos los bienes, se pagan los salarios y el hogar representativo define sus canastas de consumo y se obtienen los beneficios de las empresas. Aquí, aquellas empresas con peor desempeño relativo durante más tiempo tienen mayores posibilidades de quiebra. Los resultados de este modelo muestran diferentes efectos en cascada sobre los precios y las cantidades que se comercializan en la red productiva. En particular, existe un efecto de cascada "aguas arriba" en la quiebra de empresas a lo largo del tiempo, que se transmite exclusivamente a los proveedores de menor riesgo en la red.

English Abstract: How do macroeconomic shocks propagate in a productive network? This document studies the diffusion of productivity shocks in networks of firms, where (1) there is imperfect competition; and (2) firms’ bankruptcy is a possibility. For (1) it is assumed that each company has to choose, for each one of its inputs, a provider among a subset of competing firms; when it does so, the buyer accepts the supplier-set price and can demand, at that price, the amount of the input it wants; however, with some probability, the transaction could fail -for example, the goods have not the expected quality or characteristics- causing losses to the buyer; this probability is greater for non-habitual suppliers to the buyer, who have to offer lower prices in order to compete. The buyer decides not only looking for the highest expected profit, but also pondering the risk of loss compared to the expected variation in profit that each provider offers, leadi
摘要:异质微观经济冲击如何在生产网络中传播?本文研究了生产率冲击在企业网络中的扩散,其中(1)存在不完全竞争;(2)公司破产是一种可能性。对于(1),假设每个企业必须从竞争企业的子集中为其每个投入选择一个供应商,这些竞争企业为其产品设定价格。当买方这样做时,他接受供应商确定的价格,并可以按该价格要求他想要的数量;然而,在一定的概率下,交易可能会失败,例如,产品没有预期的质量或特性,给买方造成损失。这种可能性对于买方的非常规供应商来说更大,他们必须提供更低的价格才能竞争。在这种情况下,买方不仅寻求最高的预期利润,而且寻求最低的损失风险,这导致他将合同概率分配给每个供应商。因此,买方决策的模型不同于经典的预期效用最大化,这使我们能够代表一个连续的市场力量,不同于经典的古诺或伯特兰。关于(2),一旦合同分配完成,所有商品都生产了,工资支付了,代表家庭定义了他们的消费篮子,并获得了公司的利润。在这里,相对表现较差的公司破产的可能性更大。该模型的结果表明,在生产网络中销售的价格和数量有不同的级联效应。特别是,随着时间的推移,企业破产会产生“上游”级联效应,这种效应只会传递给网络中风险最低的供应商。他的父亲是一名律师,母亲是一名律师。本文研究了(1)存在不完全竞争的企业网络中生产力的扩散冲击;= =地理= =根据美国人口普查,该镇总面积为,其中土地和(2.3%)水。对于(1),假定每个公司必须为其每一项投入选择一个竞争公司子集中的供应商;这样做时,买方接受供应商设定的价格,并可按该价格要求其所需投入的数量;但是,交易可能会失败,例如,货物没有预期的质量或特性,给买方造成损失;对于非标准供应商来说,这种可能性更大,因为它们必须提供较低的价格才能竞争。The buyer定是not only for The expected profit的,pondering expected variation in The risk of算不上第二十四to The profit处理每provider assign offers,导致他to a probability of to每一bidder征聘。Hence, the buyer ' s decision is modeled expected utility,允许有不同from the classic maximization of us to蒯庆华自始至终不同from the classic Cournot or of market power,伯特兰。关于(2),一旦订立合同,所有货物都已生产,支付工资,具有代表性的家庭确定其消费篮子,公司的利润也已实现。这些公司with greater罪大恶极:performance time for longer向志愿of条。当日of The平衡这种经济,包括纳什平衡with价格如strategies and supply-demand equilibium,日内瓦。然后,我们模拟了这个模型,显示了在生产网络中交易的价格和数量的不同级联效应。特别是,随着时间的推移,公司破产会产生一种“上游”级联效应,这种效应只传递给网络中风险最低的供应商。
{"title":"Difusión de choques de productividad en redes productivas con competencia imperfecta y quiebra de empresas (Productivity Shocks Diffusion in Firms Networks With Imperfect Competition and Bankruptcy)","authors":"José Ramírez-Álvarez, W. Perez-Oviedo","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3347880","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3347880","url":null,"abstract":"<b>Spanish Abstract:</b> ¿Cómo se propagan choques microeconómicos heterogéneos en una red productiva? Este documento estudia la difusión de los choques de productividad en las redes de empresas, donde (1) existe una competencia imperfecta; y (2) la quiebra de las empresas es una posibilidad. Para (1) se supone que cada empresa debe elegir, para cada uno de sus insumos, un proveedor entre un subconjunto de empresas competidoras que fijan los precios de sus productos. Cuando lo hace, el comprador acepta el precio establecido por el proveedor y puede exigir, a ese precio, la cantidad que desea; sin embargo, con cierta probabilidad, la transacción podría fallar, por ejemplo, los productos no tienen la calidad o características esperadas, lo que causa pérdidas para el comprador. Esta probabilidad es mayor para los proveedores no habituales del comprador, que tienen que ofrecer precios más bajos para poder competir. En este contexto, el comprador no solo busca el mayor beneficio esperado, sino también el menor riesgo de pérdida, lo que lo lleva a asignar una probabilidad de contratación a cada proveedor. Por lo tanto, la decisión del comprador se modela de manera diferente de la maximización clásica de la utilidad esperada, lo que nos permite representar un continuo de poder de mercado, diferente del clásico Cournot o Bertrand. Con respecto a (2), una vez que se realizan las asignaciones de los contratos, se producen todos los bienes, se pagan los salarios y el hogar representativo define sus canastas de consumo y se obtienen los beneficios de las empresas. Aquí, aquellas empresas con peor desempeño relativo durante más tiempo tienen mayores posibilidades de quiebra. Los resultados de este modelo muestran diferentes efectos en cascada sobre los precios y las cantidades que se comercializan en la red productiva. En particular, existe un efecto de cascada \"aguas arriba\" en la quiebra de empresas a lo largo del tiempo, que se transmite exclusivamente a los proveedores de menor riesgo en la red.<br><br><b>English Abstract:</b> How do macroeconomic shocks propagate in a productive network? This document studies the diffusion of productivity shocks in networks of firms, where (1) there is imperfect competition; and (2) firms’ bankruptcy is a possibility. For (1) it is assumed that each company has to choose, for each one of its inputs, a provider among a subset of competing firms; when it does so, the buyer accepts the supplier-set price and can demand, at that price, the amount of the input it wants; however, with some probability, the transaction could fail -for example, the goods have not the expected quality or characteristics- causing losses to the buyer; this probability is greater for non-habitual suppliers to the buyer, who have to offer lower prices in order to compete. The buyer decides not only looking for the highest expected profit, but also pondering the risk of loss compared to the expected variation in profit that each provider offers, leadi","PeriodicalId":448105,"journal":{"name":"ERN: Productivity (Topic)","volume":"88 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2019-03-06","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"114377954","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
The Complex Economics of Artificial Intelligence 人工智能的复杂经济学
Pub Date : 2018-12-02 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3294552
J. Mateos-Garcia
Artificial Intelligence (AI) systems help organisations manage complexity: they reduce the cost of predictions and hold the promise of more, better and faster decisions that enhance productivity and innovation. However, their deployment increases complexity at all levels of the economy, and with it, the risk of undesirable outcomes. Organisationally, uncertainty about how to adopt fallible AI systems could create AI divides between sectors and organisations. Transactionally, pervasive information asymmetries in AI markets could lead to unsafe, abusive and mediocre applications. Societally, individuals might opt for extreme levels of AI deployment in other sectors in exchange for lower prices and more convenience, creating disruption and inequality. Temporally, scientific, technological and market inertias could lock society into AI trajectories that are found to be inferior to alternative paths. New Sciences (and Policies) of the Artificial are needed to understand and manage the new economic complexities that AI brings, acknowledging that AI technologies are not neutral and can be steered in societally beneficial directions guided by the principles of experimentation and evidence to discover where and how to apply AI, transparency and compliance to remove information asymmetries and increase safety in AI markets, social solidarity to share the benefits and costs of AI deployment, and diversity in the AI trajectories that are explored and pursued and the perspectives that guide this process. This will involve an explicit elucidation of human and social goals and values, a mirror of the Turing test where different societies learn about themselves through their responses to the opportunities and challenges that powerful AI technologies pose.
人工智能(AI)系统帮助组织管理复杂性:它们降低了预测成本,并有望做出更多、更好、更快的决策,从而提高生产力和创新能力。然而,它们的部署增加了经济各个层面的复杂性,随之而来的是不良后果的风险。从组织上讲,关于如何采用易出错的人工智能系统的不确定性可能会在部门和组织之间造成人工智能鸿沟。在交易方面,人工智能市场中普遍存在的信息不对称可能导致不安全、滥用和平庸的应用程序。在社会上,个人可能会选择在其他领域极端部署人工智能,以换取更低的价格和更多的便利,从而造成破坏和不平等。在短期内,科学、技术和市场的惯性可能会将社会锁定在人工智能的轨迹上,人们发现这些轨迹不如其他路径。需要新的人工智能科学(和政策)来理解和管理人工智能带来的新经济复杂性,承认人工智能技术不是中立的,可以在实验和证据原则的指导下朝着有利于社会的方向发展,以发现人工智能应用的地点和方式,透明度和合规性以消除信息不对称并提高人工智能市场的安全性,社会团结以分享人工智能部署的收益和成本。探索和追求的人工智能轨迹的多样性以及指导这一过程的观点。这将涉及对人类和社会目标和价值观的明确阐明,这是图灵测试的一面镜子,在图灵测试中,不同的社会通过对强大的人工智能技术带来的机遇和挑战的反应来了解自己。
{"title":"The Complex Economics of Artificial Intelligence","authors":"J. Mateos-Garcia","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3294552","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3294552","url":null,"abstract":"Artificial Intelligence (AI) systems help organisations manage complexity: they reduce the cost of predictions and hold the promise of more, better and faster decisions that enhance productivity and innovation. However, their deployment increases complexity at all levels of the economy, and with it, the risk of undesirable outcomes. Organisationally, uncertainty about how to adopt fallible AI systems could create AI divides between sectors and organisations. Transactionally, pervasive information asymmetries in AI markets could lead to unsafe, abusive and mediocre applications. Societally, individuals might opt for extreme levels of AI deployment in other sectors in exchange for lower prices and more convenience, creating disruption and inequality. Temporally, scientific, technological and market inertias could lock society into AI trajectories that are found to be inferior to alternative paths. New Sciences (and Policies) of the Artificial are needed to understand and manage the new economic complexities that AI brings, acknowledging that AI technologies are not neutral and can be steered in societally beneficial directions guided by the principles of experimentation and evidence to discover where and how to apply AI, transparency and compliance to remove information asymmetries and increase safety in AI markets, social solidarity to share the benefits and costs of AI deployment, and diversity in the AI trajectories that are explored and pursued and the perspectives that guide this process. This will involve an explicit elucidation of human and social goals and values, a mirror of the Turing test where different societies learn about themselves through their responses to the opportunities and challenges that powerful AI technologies pose.","PeriodicalId":448105,"journal":{"name":"ERN: Productivity (Topic)","volume":"31 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2018-12-02","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"124173877","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 14
Connected, but Qualified? Social Affiliations, Human Capital, and Service Professional Performance 有人脉,但有资格?社会关系、人力资本与服务专业绩效
Pub Date : 2018-11-16 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.2837885
Timothy Gubler
While social capital has been found to play an important role in economic transactions when information is incomplete, it remains unclear how it interacts with human capital in transaction performance. This paper explores the complementarity between social affiliations and human capital in transaction performance, and how affiliations influence the match between qualified professionals and consumers. I argue that human capital is important to professional performance, but that social affiliations lead consumers to increasingly match with lower human capital professionals. Thus, while social and human capital function as complements in transaction performance, social capital can substitute for human capital in the selection process. I test my argument using a novel approach that pairs data from a primary real estate multiple listing service in Utah with hand-collected data on geographically assigned church congregation boundaries. This setting allows me to identify listings for which real estate agents and home sellers share a common church congregation, and to explore the impact of this affiliation, as well as human capital variables, on transaction outcomes. I find that agent performance improves when listing for affiliates, on average, and that gains increase with agent human capital. However, consistent with my theory, I find that sellers are more likely to use inexperienced and underqualified affiliated agents. Human capital deficiencies reduce benefits from social affiliations, and lead to inferior transaction outcomes in extreme cases. This suggests a new underexplored dark side to social capital from human capital deficiencies, which is driven by the selection process under incomplete information.
虽然社会资本已被发现在信息不完整的经济交易中发挥重要作用,但它在交易绩效中如何与人力资本相互作用仍不清楚。本文探讨了社会关系与人力资本在交易绩效中的互补性,以及社会关系如何影响专业人才与消费者之间的匹配。我认为人力资本对职业表现很重要,但社会关系导致消费者越来越多地与人力资本较低的专业人士匹配。因此,社会资本和人力资本在交易绩效上互为补充,但在选择过程中,社会资本可以替代人力资本。我使用一种新颖的方法来验证我的论点,该方法将来自犹他州主要房地产多重上市服务的数据与手工收集的地理上分配的教会会众边界数据配对。这种设置使我能够识别房地产经纪人和房屋卖家共享共同教堂会众的列表,并探索这种隶属关系以及人力资本变量对交易结果的影响。我发现代理的绩效在为附属公司上市时平均有所提高,并且收益随着代理人力资本的增加而增加。然而,与我的理论一致,我发现卖家更有可能使用缺乏经验和不合格的附属代理。人力资本不足降低了社会关系的收益,在极端情况下导致交易结果较差。这表明,在不完全信息条件下的选择过程中,人力资本不足给社会资本带来了新的未被充分发掘的阴暗面。
{"title":"Connected, but Qualified? Social Affiliations, Human Capital, and Service Professional Performance","authors":"Timothy Gubler","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.2837885","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2837885","url":null,"abstract":"While social capital has been found to play an important role in economic transactions when information is incomplete, it remains unclear how it interacts with human capital in transaction performance. This paper explores the complementarity between social affiliations and human capital in transaction performance, and how affiliations influence the match between qualified professionals and consumers. I argue that human capital is important to professional performance, but that social affiliations lead consumers to increasingly match with lower human capital professionals. Thus, while social and human capital function as complements in transaction performance, social capital can substitute for human capital in the selection process. I test my argument using a novel approach that pairs data from a primary real estate multiple listing service in Utah with hand-collected data on geographically assigned church congregation boundaries. This setting allows me to identify listings for which real estate agents and home sellers share a common church congregation, and to explore the impact of this affiliation, as well as human capital variables, on transaction outcomes. I find that agent performance improves when listing for affiliates, on average, and that gains increase with agent human capital. However, consistent with my theory, I find that sellers are more likely to use inexperienced and underqualified affiliated agents. Human capital deficiencies reduce benefits from social affiliations, and lead to inferior transaction outcomes in extreme cases. This suggests a new underexplored dark side to social capital from human capital deficiencies, which is driven by the selection process under incomplete information.","PeriodicalId":448105,"journal":{"name":"ERN: Productivity (Topic)","volume":"23 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2018-11-16","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"123506423","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
期刊
ERN: Productivity (Topic)
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1