首页 > 最新文献

Asian Economic Policy Review最新文献

英文 中文
Implications of Deglobalization on Energy and Carbon Neutrality in Asia and the Pacific Region 去全球化对亚太地区能源和碳中和的影响
IF 3.9 3区 经济学 Q1 Economics, Econometrics and Finance Pub Date : 2023-10-07 DOI: 10.1111/aepr.12444
Toshi H. Arimura, Makoto Sugino

The IPCC (Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change) special report on the impacts of global warming of 1.5°C urged the world to move toward carbon neutrality (CN). Following the announcement by European countries of their CN target by 2050, Japan, South Korea, and the USA announced their CN targets by 2050. However, the Russian invasion of Ukraine has divided the world and drastically changed energy markets, including natural gas. Moreover, the EU is now implementing controversial policies on carbon border adjustment mechanisms which may impose a heavier burden on developing countries. This study discusses how global divisions may influence energy strategies and climate policy for various Asian countries.

政府间气候变化专门委员会(IPCC)关于全球升温 1.5°C 影响的特别报告敦促全球实现碳中和(CN)。继欧洲国家宣布到 2050 年实现碳中和目标之后,日本、韩国和美国也宣布了到 2050 年实现碳中和的目标。然而,俄罗斯对乌克兰的入侵分裂了世界,并极大地改变了包括天然气在内的能源市场。此外,欧盟目前正在实施有争议的碳边界调整机制政策,这可能会加重发展中国家的负担。本研究探讨了全球分裂如何影响亚洲各国的能源战略和气候政策。
{"title":"Implications of Deglobalization on Energy and Carbon Neutrality in Asia and the Pacific Region","authors":"Toshi H. Arimura,&nbsp;Makoto Sugino","doi":"10.1111/aepr.12444","DOIUrl":"10.1111/aepr.12444","url":null,"abstract":"<div>\u0000 \u0000 <p>The IPCC (Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change) special report on the impacts of global warming of 1.5°C urged the world to move toward carbon neutrality (CN). Following the announcement by European countries of their CN target by 2050, Japan, South Korea, and the USA announced their CN targets by 2050. However, the Russian invasion of Ukraine has divided the world and drastically changed energy markets, including natural gas. Moreover, the EU is now implementing controversial policies on carbon border adjustment mechanisms which may impose a heavier burden on developing countries. This study discusses how global divisions may influence energy strategies and climate policy for various Asian countries.</p>\u0000 </div>","PeriodicalId":45430,"journal":{"name":"Asian Economic Policy Review","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":3.9,"publicationDate":"2023-10-07","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"135254994","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Comment on “Can the World Trade Organization Act as a Bulwark Against Deglobalization?” 评论 "世界贸易组织能否成为抵御去全球化的屏障?
IF 3.9 3区 经济学 Q1 Economics, Econometrics and Finance Pub Date : 2023-10-02 DOI: 10.1111/aepr.12447
Junji Nakagawa

Evenett (2024) makes a well-evidenced argument on the capacity of the World Trade Organization (WTO) rules to contain deglobalization. His argument is straightforward. He argues that the WTO rules offer little constraint on state-led deglobalization. He justifies this argument with three sets of evidence. First is the set of evidence from recent high-profile commercial policy episodes such as the US–China trade war, the “weaponization” of medical goods and food exports under the outbreak of the COVID-19 pandemic, and the discriminatory tariff hike invoking national security by the US Trump administration. These episodes show us that governments violated WTO rules without hesitation either overtly in the case of the US–China trade war, or less overtly in the case of export restrictions on medical goods and foods.

The weakness of the WTO rules is, however, not a recent phenomenon. The second set of evidence that Evenett (2024) presents is on commercial policy choices since the Global Financial Crisis of 2008. According to the Global Trade Alert, created by Evenett and his team, commercial policy interventions implemented by about 200 customs territories since 1 November 2008 are traced. The result is striking. The share of world goods trade covered by discriminatory unilateral commercial policy grew over time, and now it is about 80% (Evenett's figure 4).

The third set of evidence is from the WTO tariff schedules of the G20 members. It shows that eight G20 members can legally raise tariff rates by more than 7%, that is, the Smoot Hawley tariff rate, due to the difference between applied tariff rates and bound tariff rates (Evenett's tables 1 and 2). This means that the WTO tariff bindings do not constrain the capacity of these governments to substantively raise tariffs.

The argument of Evenett (2024) aims at demystifying the capacity of WTO rules in controlling member states' commercial policy. If we look at only the recent episodes of deglobalization such as the US–China trade war, we may still expect that the WTO rules will regain their capacity soon after the end of these episodes. However, Evenett (2024) does not allow us to embrace such an illusion, because discriminatory unilateral commercial policy has been growing at least since the Global Financial Crisis of 2008.

Still, we can argue that many governments observe the WTO rules, notably the most favored nation (MFN) principle and tariff binding. For instance, even though governments have cumulated discriminatory unilateral commercial policy since the Global Financial Crisis, they have depended more on non-tariff measures than tariff measures. The fact that eight G20 members can legally raise tariff rates by more than the Smoot Hauley tariff rate does not mean that they actually did so. The fact is that these countries unilaterally lowered the applied tariff rates substantively below the bound tariff rates, while

Evenett(2024)对世界贸易组织(WTO)规则遏制去全球化的能力提出了一个有充分证据的论点。他的论点直截了当。他认为,WTO规则对国家主导的去全球化几乎没有什么约束。他用三组证据来证明他的论点。首先是近期备受关注的商业政策事件,如中美贸易战、新冠肺炎疫情下医疗产品和食品出口“武器化”、美国特朗普政府以国家安全为由歧视性提高关税等。这些事件告诉我们,各国政府要么在中美贸易战中公然违反世贸组织规则,要么在医疗产品和食品出口限制方面不那么公然违反世贸组织规则。然而,世贸组织规则的弱点并不是最近才出现的现象。Evenett(2024)提出的第二组证据是2008年全球金融危机以来的商业政策选择。根据Evenett和他的团队创建的全球贸易警报,追踪了自2008年11月1日以来约200个关税区实施的商业政策干预。结果是惊人的。歧视性单边商业政策所涵盖的世界货物贸易份额随着时间的推移而增长,现在约为80% (Evenett的图4)。第三组证据来自世贸组织G20成员的关税表。它表明,由于适用关税税率和约束关税税率之间的差异,8个G20成员可以合法地提高7%以上的关税税率,即斯姆特霍利关税税率(Evenett的表1和表2)。这意味着WTO关税约束并不限制这些政府大幅提高关税的能力。Evenett(2024)的论点旨在揭示WTO规则控制成员国商业政策的能力。如果我们只看最近的去全球化事件,比如美中贸易战,我们可能仍然会期望世贸组织规则在这些事件结束后不久就会恢复其能力。然而,Evenett(2024)不允许我们接受这样的错觉,因为歧视性的单边商业政策至少自2008年全球金融危机以来一直在增长。尽管如此,我们可以说,许多政府遵守世贸组织的规则,特别是最惠国原则和关税约束。例如,尽管自全球金融危机以来,各国政府积累了歧视性的单边商业政策,但它们更多地依赖非关税措施,而不是关税措施。8个G20成员国可以合法地将关税税率提高到超过斯姆特-豪利关税税率的水平,但这并不意味着它们实际上这样做了。事实是,这些国家单方面将实施关税税率大幅降低到约束关税税率以下,而由于多哈回合关税谈判失败,约束关税税率仍然很高。这强化了Evenett(2024)的观点,即WTO的关税约束并不控制成员国政府的商业政策。如果我们要客观评估世贸组织规则约束歧视性单边商业政策的能力,我们必须认识到这种能力的局限性。正如Evenett(2024)所证明的那样,各国政府能够采取除关税措施以外的政策措施,而不会公然违反WTO规则。WTO规则控制此类措施(尤其是地方补贴)的能力有限。虽然世贸组织的规则不能有效地控制成员国政府的商业政策,但一些成员国可能希望通过谈判自由贸易协定(FTAs)和/或具有更广泛和更严格规则的诸边协定来引入这种控制。《全面与进步跨太平洋伙伴关系协定》(CPTPP)是前者的一个例子,《关于电子商务的联合声明倡议》是后者的一个例子。Evenett(2024)承认,CPTPP可能会在其成员国之间创造一个较少扭曲的贸易绿洲。虽然这并不能反驳他的主要论点,但寻求比世贸组织规则更广泛、更深入的双边、区域和/或诸边贸易规则,将继续成为弥补世贸组织控制成员国政府商业政策能力有限的一种选择。最后,Evenett(2024)认为商界可能是对抗去全球化的一股力量。诚然,工商界一直支持以规则为基础的多边贸易体制(例如,日本经济联合会,2022年),但这还不足以遏制去全球化。正如美国、日本和荷兰最近收紧对半导体制造设备的出口管制所显示的那样,企业界正面临着来自各自政府的强大压力,要求它们与供应链脱钩。 Evenett (2024) 对世界贸易组织(WTO)规则遏制去全球化的能力进行了论证。他的论点直截了当。他认为,世贸组织规则对国家主导的去全球化几乎没有制约作用。他用三组证据来证明这一论点。首先是近期备受瞩目的商业政策事件所提供的一系列证据,如中美贸易战、COVID-19 大流行病爆发时医疗产品和食品出口的 "武器化",以及美国特朗普政府以国家安全为由歧视性地提高关税。这些事件向我们表明,无论是在中美贸易战的情况下,还是在医疗产品和食品出口限制的情况下,各国政府都毫不犹豫地违反了世贸组织的规则。Evenett (2024) 提出的第二组证据涉及 2008 年全球金融危机以来的商业政策选择。根据埃文尼特及其团队创建的 "全球贸易快讯",对约 200 个关税区自 2008 年 11 月 1 日以来实施的商业政策干预进行了追踪。结果令人震惊。随着时间的推移,歧视性单边商业政策所覆盖的世界货物贸易份额不断增加,目前已达到约 80%(Evenett 的图 4)。第三组证据来自世贸组织 20 国集团成员的关税税率表,它显示 20 国集团中有 8 个成员可以合法地将关税税率提高 7%以上,即斯穆特-霍利关税税率,原因是适用关税税率与约束关税税率之间存在差异(埃文尼特的表 1 和表 2)。埃文尼特(2024 年)的论点旨在揭开世贸组织规则控制成员国商业政策能力的神秘面纱。如果我们只看最近发生的中美贸易战等去全球化事件,我们可能仍然会认为世贸组织规则会在这些事件结束后很快恢复其能力。然而,Evenett(2024 年)并不允许我们抱有这样的幻想,因为至少自 2008 年全球金融危机以来,歧视性的单边商业政策一直在增长。尽管如此,我们仍然可以认为许多政府遵守了世贸组织的规则,尤其是最惠国待遇原则和关税约束。例如,尽管自全球金融危机以来,各国政府累积了歧视性的单边商业政策,但它们更多依赖的是非关税措施,而非关税措施。20 国集团的八个成员国可以合法地将关税税率提高到斯穆特-豪利关税税率以上,但这并不意味着它们实际上这样做了。事实是,由于多哈回合关税谈判的失败,这些国家单方面将适用税率大幅降低到约束税率以下,而约束税率仍然很高。如果我们要对世贸组织规则约束歧视性单边商业政策的能力进行客观评估,就必须认识到这种能力的局限性。Evenett (2024) 指出,除关税措施外,各国政府还可以采取其他政策措施,但这些措施并没有公然违反世贸组织规则。虽然世贸组织规则不能有效控制成员国政府的商业政策,但一些成员国可能希望通过谈判自由贸易协定和/或具有更广泛、更严格规则的诸边协定来引入这种控制。跨太平洋伙伴关系全面进步协定》(CPTPP)就是前者的一个例子,而关于电子商务的联合声明倡议则是后者的一个例子。Evenett(2024 年)承认,CPTPP 可能会在其成员之间创造一个扭曲程度较低的贸易绿洲。尽管这并不能反驳他的主要论点,但寻求比世贸组织规则覆盖面更广、更深的双边、区域和/或诸边贸易规则仍将是一种选择,以弥补世贸组织控制成员国政府商业政策的能力有限的不足。诚然,商界一直支持以规则为基础的多边贸易体系(例如,日本商业联合会,2022 年),但这还不足以遏制去全球化。正如美国、日本和荷兰最近收紧半导体制造设备出口管制所表明的那样,企业界正面临着来自各自政府的强大压力,要求其供应链脱钩。 开放贸易体系的支持者,尤其是商界,对这种脆弱的局面感到沮丧。
{"title":"Comment on “Can the World Trade Organization Act as a Bulwark Against Deglobalization?”","authors":"Junji Nakagawa","doi":"10.1111/aepr.12447","DOIUrl":"10.1111/aepr.12447","url":null,"abstract":"<p>Evenett (<span>2024</span>) makes a well-evidenced argument on the capacity of the World Trade Organization (WTO) rules to contain deglobalization. His argument is straightforward. He argues that the WTO rules offer little constraint on state-led deglobalization. He justifies this argument with three sets of evidence. First is the set of evidence from recent high-profile commercial policy episodes such as the US–China trade war, the “weaponization” of medical goods and food exports under the outbreak of the COVID-19 pandemic, and the discriminatory tariff hike invoking national security by the US Trump administration. These episodes show us that governments violated WTO rules without hesitation either overtly in the case of the US–China trade war, or less overtly in the case of export restrictions on medical goods and foods.</p><p>The weakness of the WTO rules is, however, not a recent phenomenon. The second set of evidence that Evenett (<span>2024</span>) presents is on commercial policy choices since the Global Financial Crisis of 2008. According to the Global Trade Alert, created by Evenett and his team, commercial policy interventions implemented by about 200 customs territories since 1 November 2008 are traced. The result is striking. The share of world goods trade covered by discriminatory unilateral commercial policy grew over time, and now it is about 80% (Evenett's figure 4).</p><p>The third set of evidence is from the WTO tariff schedules of the G20 members. It shows that eight G20 members can legally raise tariff rates by more than 7%, that is, the Smoot Hawley tariff rate, due to the difference between applied tariff rates and bound tariff rates (Evenett's tables 1 and 2). This means that the WTO tariff bindings do not constrain the capacity of these governments to substantively raise tariffs.</p><p>The argument of Evenett (<span>2024</span>) aims at demystifying the capacity of WTO rules in controlling member states' commercial policy. If we look at only the recent episodes of deglobalization such as the US–China trade war, we may still expect that the WTO rules will regain their capacity soon after the end of these episodes. However, Evenett (<span>2024</span>) does not allow us to embrace such an illusion, because discriminatory unilateral commercial policy has been growing at least since the Global Financial Crisis of 2008.</p><p>Still, we can argue that many governments observe the WTO rules, notably the most favored nation (MFN) principle and tariff binding. For instance, even though governments have cumulated discriminatory unilateral commercial policy since the Global Financial Crisis, they have depended more on non-tariff measures than tariff measures. The fact that eight G20 members can legally raise tariff rates by more than the Smoot Hauley tariff rate does not mean that they actually did so. The fact is that these countries unilaterally lowered the applied tariff rates substantively below the bound tariff rates, while ","PeriodicalId":45430,"journal":{"name":"Asian Economic Policy Review","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":3.9,"publicationDate":"2023-10-02","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/aepr.12447","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"135791904","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"OA","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Can the World Trade Organization Act as a Bulwark Against Deglobalization? 世界贸易组织能否成为抵御去全球化的屏障?
IF 3.9 3区 经济学 Q1 Economics, Econometrics and Finance Pub Date : 2023-10-02 DOI: 10.1111/aepr.12445
Simon J. Evenett

Whether existing multilateral trade commitments really deter larger trading nations from taking steps that further weaken cross-border commercial ties is assessed here. Evidence from salient commercial policy episodes of recent years is combined with information on the actual leeway available to G-20 members under extant World Trade Organization rules. The upshot is a bleak assessment of the capacity of the existing multilateral trade rule book to rein in any attempt by larger trading nations to “deglobalize” the world economy.

本文评估了现有的多边贸易承诺是否真的能阻止较大的贸易国采取进一步削弱跨境商业联系的措施。本文将近年来突出的商业政策事件的证据与 20 国集团成员在世界贸易组织现有规则下的实际回旋余地的信息相结合。结果是对现有多边贸易规则在遏制贸易大国 "去全球化 "世界经济的任何企图方面的能力进行了暗淡的评估。
{"title":"Can the World Trade Organization Act as a Bulwark Against Deglobalization?","authors":"Simon J. Evenett","doi":"10.1111/aepr.12445","DOIUrl":"10.1111/aepr.12445","url":null,"abstract":"<p>Whether existing multilateral trade commitments really deter larger trading nations from taking steps that further weaken cross-border commercial ties is assessed here. Evidence from salient commercial policy episodes of recent years is combined with information on the actual leeway available to G-20 members under extant World Trade Organization rules. The upshot is a bleak assessment of the capacity of the existing multilateral trade rule book to rein in any attempt by larger trading nations to “deglobalize” the world economy.</p>","PeriodicalId":45430,"journal":{"name":"Asian Economic Policy Review","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":3.9,"publicationDate":"2023-10-02","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/aepr.12445","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"135791905","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"OA","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Comment on “Can the World Trade Organization Act as a Bulwark Against Deglobalization?” 评论 "世界贸易组织能否成为抵御去全球化的屏障?
IF 3.9 3区 经济学 Q1 Economics, Econometrics and Finance Pub Date : 2023-10-02 DOI: 10.1111/aepr.12448
Bernard Hoekman

The World Trade Organization (WTO) has not been effective in providing a forum for members to negotiate, monitor, and enforce trade policy commitments. Members failed to conclude its first (and only) multilateral trade negotiation (the Doha Round). Following the deadlock in 2008, veto players, empowered by the consensus working practice, impeded the ability of members to use WTO bodies to discuss ways to address trade tensions. The US has been a key veto player, defenestrating the Appellate Body by blocking new appointments. As Evenett (2024) documents, the danger is clear and present, reflected in the increasing use of policies to support domestic firms, notably subsidies and local content requirements, and recourse to export controls for essential products (medical, food, energy) and advanced technologies.

Evenett argues that governments contemplating large increases in protection are not (much) constrained by WTO commitments. In part this is because of significant policy space to increase protection if deemed necessary (contra the common canard that WTO agreements greatly reduce policy space), and in part because states accept the potential costs of retaliation. A point that deserves greater emphasis is that there is no collective (“WTO”) enforcement of commitments. The threat of withdrawal of concessions (retaliation) by affected trading partners sustains cooperation. Size and power matter in this regard. If a small nation unilaterally greatly increases protection, it can expect retaliation. If trade (exports) matter (more likely for small nations than major economies), WTO commitments may bind more than suggested by Evenett. Conversely, insofar as large powers target each other through subsidies and industrial policies this may benefit other countries by encouraging redirection of investment and GVC activities to their markets. It may also result in lower-cost access to green technologies insofar as global supply expands.

The evidence compiled by Evenett that many of the discriminatory measures post-2009 are less tightly or not constrained by the WTO suggests that the main issue concerns the incentives (prospects) for WTO members to negotiate a new understanding. Reestablishing the Appellate Body will serve little purpose in strengthening the WTO as a bulwark against deglobalization, as seeking to make the Appellate Body operational without a clear path towards updating and filling key gaps in the rulebook will not change the dynamics documented by Evenett. In the unlikely event this could be done it may disincentivize negotiations to address the underlying sources of trade conflicts. Instead, what is needed is to identify the incidence and size of spillovers and consider dispute settlement reforms as one element of a broader effort to revitalize the WTO as a forum for trade cooperation.

While clearly violating substantive and procedural WTO rules, implicit in the unilateral US decision to launch a trade war

世贸组织成员有充分的动机和空间开展针对具体问题的合作,包括通过诸边协定,提高政策的有效性,减轻政策溢出效应。美国(和其他国家)是否会做出这样的努力,部分取决于国内的社会经济发展政策是否到位,以促进对外部竞争、技术和气候变化的调整。可以说,它们的缺席是推动美国对WTO和贸易协定采取修正主义的一个重要因素。国内政策是维持以规则为基础的开放贸易秩序所需的国内稳定的主要决定因素。 美国(和其他国家)是否会参与这些努力在一定程度上取决于是否制定了国内社会经济发展政策来促进对外部竞争以及技术和气候变化的调整。可以说,这些政策的缺失是促使美国对世贸组织和贸易协定采取修正主义态度的一个重要因素。国内政策是维持基于规则的开放贸易秩序所需的内部稳定的主要决定因素。
{"title":"Comment on “Can the World Trade Organization Act as a Bulwark Against Deglobalization?”","authors":"Bernard Hoekman","doi":"10.1111/aepr.12448","DOIUrl":"10.1111/aepr.12448","url":null,"abstract":"<p>The World Trade Organization (WTO) has not been effective in providing a forum for members to negotiate, monitor, and enforce trade policy commitments. Members failed to conclude its first (and only) multilateral trade negotiation (the Doha Round). Following the deadlock in 2008, veto players, empowered by the consensus working practice, impeded the ability of members to use WTO bodies to discuss ways to address trade tensions. The US has been a key veto player, defenestrating the Appellate Body by blocking new appointments. As Evenett (<span>2024</span>) documents, the danger is clear and present, reflected in the increasing use of policies to support domestic firms, notably subsidies and local content requirements, and recourse to export controls for essential products (medical, food, energy) and advanced technologies.</p><p>Evenett argues that governments contemplating large increases in protection are not (much) constrained by WTO commitments. In part this is because of significant policy space to increase protection if deemed necessary (contra the common canard that WTO agreements greatly reduce policy space), and in part because states accept the potential costs of retaliation. A point that deserves greater emphasis is that there is no collective (“WTO”) enforcement of commitments. The threat of withdrawal of concessions (retaliation) by affected trading partners sustains cooperation. Size and power matter in this regard. If a small nation unilaterally greatly increases protection, it can expect retaliation. If trade (exports) matter (more likely for small nations than major economies), WTO commitments may bind more than suggested by Evenett. Conversely, insofar as large powers target each other through subsidies and industrial policies this may benefit other countries by encouraging redirection of investment and GVC activities to their markets. It may also result in lower-cost access to green technologies insofar as global supply expands.</p><p>The evidence compiled by Evenett that many of the discriminatory measures post-2009 are less tightly or not constrained by the WTO suggests that the main issue concerns the incentives (prospects) for WTO members to negotiate a new understanding. Reestablishing the Appellate Body will serve little purpose in strengthening the WTO as a bulwark against deglobalization, as seeking to make the Appellate Body operational without a clear path towards updating and filling key gaps in the rulebook will not change the dynamics documented by Evenett. In the unlikely event this could be done it may disincentivize negotiations to address the underlying sources of trade conflicts. Instead, what is needed is to identify the incidence and size of spillovers and consider dispute settlement reforms as one element of a broader effort to revitalize the WTO as a forum for trade cooperation.</p><p>While clearly violating substantive and procedural WTO rules, implicit in the unilateral US decision to launch a trade war","PeriodicalId":45430,"journal":{"name":"Asian Economic Policy Review","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":3.9,"publicationDate":"2023-10-02","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/aepr.12448","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"135792101","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"OA","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Comment on “Deconstructing Deglobalization: The Future of Trade is in Intermediate Services” 评论 "解构去全球化:贸易的未来在于中间服务" 评论
IF 3.9 3区 经济学 Q1 Economics, Econometrics and Finance Pub Date : 2023-09-17 DOI: 10.1111/aepr.12446
Ayako Obashi

The degree of globalization is often assessed using a conventional measure of global trade openness, namely the ratio of world trade in goods to world gross domestic product (GDP). This conventional measure of globalization peaked in 2008 at the onset of the Great Trade Collapse, which is treated by some commenters as a sign that the world has entered an era of delocalization. However, looking only at trade in goods might overlook an important fact that the nature of globalized economic activities is evolving. Baldwin et al. (2024) highlight the contrasting trend that world trade in goods has peaked, or at least plateaued, in 2008 whereas world trade in services has continued to grow rapidly from 1990 to 2019.

The history of globalization is inextricably linked to technological advances, and so will its future. Advances in information and communications technologies (ICT) enable the digitalization of services, leading to increased trade in digitally deliverable services. Also, new data networks, digital tools and platforms enable suppliers to expand their customer base beyond the national boundary and give consumers better access to a wider variety of good quality services at competitive prices. More importantly, ICT facilitates offshoring of intermediate services, which are purchased and used as inputs throughout the economy, including the production of manufactured goods. Interested in such a rising role of services trade, Baldwin et al. (2024) examine trade data on Other Commercial Services (OCS) and the cross-border flows of intermediate services. Based on simple statistics and economic logic, Baldwin et al. develop compelling arguments that services trade will continue to grow faster than goods trade and the future of world trade will lie in services, especially in intermediate services.

Although left aside in the data analysis and discussions of Baldwin et al. (2024), I have some comments regarding the data used in Baldwin et al. and the enabling condition for the expected growth of services trade, both of which should ideally be addressed in future research. First, for the purpose of comparison with goods trade, Baldwin et al. focus on examining services trade of the traditional made-here-and-sold-there type, which falls under Mode 1 of the World Trade Organization (WTO) services trade nomenclature. However, finance, engineering, and other business services supplied through foreign affiliates, which correspond to Mode 3, appear to be increasingly important. According to US Bureau of Economic Analysis,1 for instance, about 70% of services supplied by US-based firms to foreign persons in 2019 are accounted for by those through the majority-owned foreign affiliates of US multinationals, that is, Mode 3. To better assess the rising role of services in globalized economic activities in general, it would be called for to analyze services tr

全球化程度通常是用传统的全球贸易开放衡量标准来评估的,即世界货物贸易与世界国内生产总值(GDP)的比率。这种传统的全球化衡量标准在2008年贸易大崩溃开始时达到顶峰,一些评论人士认为,这标志着世界已经进入了一个去本地化的时代。然而,只看货物贸易可能会忽视一个重要的事实,即全球化经济活动的性质正在演变。Baldwin等人(2023)强调了对比趋势,即世界货物贸易在2008年达到顶峰,或至少达到稳定,而世界服务贸易在1990年至2019年期间继续快速增长。全球化的历史与技术进步有着千丝万缕的联系,其未来也将如此。信息通信技术(ICT)的进步使服务数字化成为可能,从而增加了以数字方式提供的服务的贸易。此外,新的数据网络、数字工具和平台使供应商能够将其客户群扩展到国界之外,并使消费者能够以具有竞争力的价格更好地获得更多种类的优质服务。更重要的是,信息和通信技术促进了中间服务的离岸外包,这些中间服务被购买并用作整个经济的投入,包括制成品的生产。Baldwin等人(2024)对服务贸易日益增长的作用感兴趣,研究了其他商业服务(OCS)和中间服务跨境流动的贸易数据。基于简单的统计和经济逻辑,Baldwin等人提出了令人信服的论点,即服务贸易将继续以比货物贸易更快的速度增长,世界贸易的未来将取决于服务,特别是中间服务。虽然鲍德温等人(2024)的数据分析和讨论中没有提到,但我对鲍德温等人使用的数据和服务贸易预期增长的有利条件有一些评论,这两个问题都应该在未来的研究中得到解决。首先,为了与货物贸易进行比较,Baldwin等人重点研究了传统的“这里制造,那里销售”类型的服务贸易,它属于世界贸易组织(WTO)服务贸易术语的模式1。然而,与模式3相对应的金融、工程和其他通过外国子公司提供的商业服务似乎越来越重要。以美国经济分析局(Bureau of Economic Analysis)的数据为例,2019年,美国企业向外国人提供的服务中,约有70%是通过美国跨国公司控股的外国子公司提供的,即模式3。为了更好地评估服务在全球化经济活动中日益重要的作用,需要分析以所有权为基础和以居住为基础的国家边界的服务贸易。此外,利益的中间服务不仅在市场上交易,而且在公司的边界内交易。更复杂的服务,如决定公司竞争优势的研发、设计和营销,更有可能被保留为内部投入,而不是依赖于外包(参见,例如Miroudot & Cadestin, 2017)。公司内部的服务投入,例如跨国公司母公司向其外国子公司提供的服务投入,很难被普通的服务贸易统计数据或国际投入产出表所捕捉。在阅读中间服务贸易的数据时,我们应该注意到外包相对于内部服务投入的比例下降或上升的不可观察的趋势。其次,尽管Baldwin等人(2024)认为未来服务贸易的扩张空间很大,但数字技术作为加速服务贸易的杠杆不会无条件地在各国之间均匀扩散。此外,技术的传播本身并不一定意味着促进采用技术的国家的自治和这些国家之间经济活动的分化。相反,数字转型的不平衡性可能导致财富向少数国家和少数公司集中。为了更深入地思考服务贸易的未来前景,似乎有必要澄清什么条件使“人人享有技术”能够最大限度地从新的全球化浪潮中获得潜在利益,并增加服务贸易。至少,除了强调数字化转型为地理位置分散的服务供应商和买家带来的机遇之外,还需要理清欠发达国家和不在技术前沿的公司面临的挑战。 需要克服的挑战从数字基础设施不发达到监管框架薄弱,从数字能力有限到金融支持不足(见联合国贸易和发展会议,2022 年)。面对机遇和挑战,政府的政策努力和企业的战略应对将决定服务贸易的未来格局。 需要克服的挑战包括从数字基础设施不发达到监管框架薄弱,从数字能力有限到资金支持不足(例如,参见联合国贸易和发展会议,2022年)。面对机遇和挑战,政府的政策努力和企业的战略应对将决定未来服务贸易的格局。
{"title":"Comment on “Deconstructing Deglobalization: The Future of Trade is in Intermediate Services”","authors":"Ayako Obashi","doi":"10.1111/aepr.12446","DOIUrl":"10.1111/aepr.12446","url":null,"abstract":"<p>The degree of globalization is often assessed using a conventional measure of global trade openness, namely the ratio of world trade in goods to world gross domestic product (GDP). This conventional measure of globalization peaked in 2008 at the onset of the Great Trade Collapse, which is treated by some commenters as a sign that the world has entered an era of delocalization. However, looking only at trade in goods might overlook an important fact that the nature of globalized economic activities is evolving. Baldwin <i>et al</i>. (<span>2024</span>) highlight the contrasting trend that world trade in goods has peaked, or at least plateaued, in 2008 whereas world trade in services has continued to grow rapidly from 1990 to 2019.</p><p>The history of globalization is inextricably linked to technological advances, and so will its future. Advances in information and communications technologies (ICT) enable the digitalization of services, leading to increased trade in digitally deliverable services. Also, new data networks, digital tools and platforms enable suppliers to expand their customer base beyond the national boundary and give consumers better access to a wider variety of good quality services at competitive prices. More importantly, ICT facilitates offshoring of intermediate services, which are purchased and used as inputs throughout the economy, including the production of manufactured goods. Interested in such a rising role of services trade, Baldwin <i>et al</i>. (<span>2024</span>) examine trade data on Other Commercial Services (OCS) and the cross-border flows of intermediate services. Based on simple statistics and economic logic, Baldwin <i>et al</i>. develop compelling arguments that services trade will continue to grow faster than goods trade and the future of world trade will lie in services, especially in intermediate services.</p><p>Although left aside in the data analysis and discussions of Baldwin <i>et al</i>. (<span>2024</span>), I have some comments regarding the data used in Baldwin <i>et al</i>. and the enabling condition for the expected growth of services trade, both of which should ideally be addressed in future research. First, for the purpose of comparison with goods trade, Baldwin <i>et al</i>. focus on examining services trade of the traditional made-here-and-sold-there type, which falls under Mode 1 of the World Trade Organization (WTO) services trade nomenclature. However, finance, engineering, and other business services supplied through foreign affiliates, which correspond to Mode 3, appear to be increasingly important. According to US Bureau of Economic Analysis,<sup>1</sup> for instance, about 70% of services supplied by US-based firms to foreign persons in 2019 are accounted for by those through the majority-owned foreign affiliates of US multinationals, that is, Mode 3. To better assess the rising role of services in globalized economic activities in general, it would be called for to analyze services tr","PeriodicalId":45430,"journal":{"name":"Asian Economic Policy Review","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":3.9,"publicationDate":"2023-09-17","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/aepr.12446","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"135258410","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"OA","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Comment on “Deconstructing Deglobalization: The Future of Trade is in Intermediate Services” 评论 "解构去全球化:贸易的未来在于中间服务" 评论
IF 3.9 3区 经济学 Q1 Economics, Econometrics and Finance Pub Date : 2023-09-11 DOI: 10.1111/aepr.12443
Prema-chandra Athukorala

The paper by Baldwin et al. (2024) aims to demonstrate that the future of economic globalization lies in services trade as the expansion of merchandise trade has already begun to run out of steam.

Baldwin et al. begin with a narrative of growth of world merchandise trade relative to world income (gross domestic product [GDP]), both in aggregate and by major trading nations and the three main sectors, manufacturing, mining and fuel, and agriculture. The data suggest that the trade-to-GDP ratio peeked around 2008, even though the peak was not equally present in all major nations and all sectors. However, Baldwin et al. have stopped short of probing the underlying drivers of the observed structural change. If the “hyper globalization” during 1985–2008 had been largely driven by cyclical rather than structural factors, it is hazardous to treat the subsequent slowdown as a structural phenomenon. Moreover, the observed trends in the trade to GDP ratio need to be treated with caution because the well-known structural shift in the composition of GDP from tradable production and toward services. Given this structural change, the measured trade-to-GDP ratio is likely to face downward pressure, thus confirming the fear of deglobalization.

My major concern with the inference of trade slowdown is that it has overlooked possible changes in the price structure of global manufacturing trade associated with production fragmentation (vertical specialization). Production fragmentation essentially means restructuring of the production process of a given product among firms located in different regions and countries. In this process, as Young (1928) postulates, increasing returns take place throughout the industry rather than at the individual firm level, generating cumulative, rather than firm-specific, gains from scale economies. Therefore, goods traded within global manufacturing value chain (GMVCs) could experience slower price increases (and hence faster volume growth) compared to the other traded goods.

There is evidence of significant decline, rooted in developments in semiconductor technology, of prices of information technology (IT) products (computers, and data storage and communicating equipment), automobiles and a wide range of other related GMVC products from about the early 1990s (Jorgenson, 2001; Byrne et al., 2016). The relative stability of the real trade-to-GDP ratio after 2008, compared to the sharp decline in the two nominal ratios in Baldwin et al.'s figure 1, is perhaps indicative of this price effect. However, I suspect that, the price index used to deflate the nominal exports does not fully capture the price lowering effect of global production sharing. An analysis using a new dataset, which is carefully constructed to better capture the price effects of GMVC trade, yields the inference that merchandise trade to GDP ratio has not yet pee

Baldwin et al.(2023)的论文旨在证明,由于商品贸易的扩张已经开始失去动力,经济全球化的未来在于服务贸易。Baldwin等人首先叙述了世界商品贸易相对于世界收入(国内生产总值[GDP])的增长,包括总量和主要贸易国以及三个主要部门,制造业,采矿业和燃料,以及农业。数据显示,贸易与gdp之比在2008年左右见顶,尽管在所有主要国家和所有行业中,这一峰值并不平均。然而,Baldwin等人没有探究所观察到的结构变化的潜在驱动因素。如果1985年至2008年期间的“超级全球化”主要是由周期性因素而非结构性因素推动的,那么将随后的放缓视为结构性现象是危险的。此外,观察到的贸易占国内生产总值比率的趋势需要谨慎对待,因为众所周知,国内生产总值构成的结构性转变是从可贸易生产转向服务。鉴于这种结构性变化,衡量的贸易与gdp之比可能面临下行压力,从而证实了对去全球化的担忧。我对贸易放缓推断的主要担忧是,它忽略了与生产碎片化(垂直专业化)相关的全球制造业贸易价格结构可能发生的变化。生产碎片化本质上是指在位于不同区域和国家的公司之间对某一产品的生产过程进行重组。在这个过程中,正如Young(1928)所假设的那样,增加的回报发生在整个行业,而不是单个企业层面,产生累积的,而不是特定于企业的规模经济收益。因此,与其他贸易商品相比,在全球制造业价值链(GMVCs)内交易的商品可能会经历较慢的价格上涨(从而更快的数量增长)。有明显下降的证据,扎根于半导体技术的发展,信息技术(IT)产品的价格(电脑、和数据存储和通信设备),汽车和各种各样的其他相关GMVC产品从1990年代初(Jorgenson, 2001;Byrne et al., 2016)。贸易占gdp比重相对稳定的比率在2008年之后,相比大幅下滑两个名义上的比率在鲍德温et al。图1,可能是这种价格效应的反映。然而,我怀疑,用于抑制名义出口的价格指数不完全捕捉全球生产共享的价格降低效果。使用精心构建的新数据集进行分析,以更好地捕捉GMVC贸易的价格效应,得出的结论是,商品贸易占GDP的比例尚未见顶,并且在2008-2009年急剧下降之后继续保持其危机前的趋势(Athukorala, 2023)。Baldwin等人的其余部分基于从分散来源收集的数据,对全球服务贸易的趋势和模式进行了全面分析。全球服务贸易增长持续繁荣的关键结论令人放心。我只有两点意见,可以帮助进一步丰富分析。首先,Baldwin等人没有充分关注制造业“服务化”的新兴过程:将一些传统上被视为制造业产出一部分的制造业相关服务转移到服务业公司,作为GMVC运营的一个组成部分。未能区分这些服务,制造业不可或缺的一部分,从中间服务会人为地增加服务在经济全球化中的作用。此外,服务化对贸易和产业政策的制定提出了挑战,因为不仅传统形式的贸易保护,而且针对服务业的壁垒也可能影响制造业(Hoekman & Shepherd, 2017)。因此,Baldwin等人在服务贸易和商品贸易之间所做的明显的二分法值得重新考虑。其次,Baldwin等人的数据似乎表明,服务贸易的增长可能进一步扩大世界经济中的南北差距。与商品贸易不同,服务贸易主要集中在北方国家(Baldwin等人的数字7和11)。与出口能力不是从事服务贸易的限制因素的说法相反,缺乏适当技能的劳动力仍然是大多数发展中国家参与与信息技术有关的现代服务业所面临的主要制约因素。此外,现代服务业不可能匹配制造业的就业潜力的一代,特别是吸收非熟练劳动力。 鲍德温等人(2024 年)的论文旨在证明,经济全球化的未来在于服务贸易,因为商品贸易的扩张已经开始力不从心。鲍德温等人首先叙述了世界商品贸易相对于世界收入(国内生产总值 [GDP])的增长情况,既有总体情况,也有按主要贸易国和三个主要部门(制造业、采矿和燃料以及农业)分列的情况。数据表明,贸易与国内生产总值的比率在 2008 年左右达到顶峰,尽管并非所有主要国家和所有部门都同样达到顶峰。然而,鲍德温等人并没有探究所观察到的结构变化的根本原因。如果说 1985-2008 年期间的 "超全球化 "主要是由周期性因素而非结构性因素驱动的,那么将随后的放缓视为结构性现象则是危险的。此外,由于国内生产总值的构成发生了众所周知的结构性变化,从可贸易生产转向服务业,因此需要谨慎对待所观察到的贸易与国内生产总值之比趋势。我对贸易放缓推论的主要担忧是,它忽略了与生产分散化(垂直专业化)相关的全球制造业贸易价格结构的可能变化。生产分化主要是指位于不同地区和国家的企业对特定产品的生产流程进行重组。在这一过程中,正如 Young(1928 年)所假设的,收益递增发生在整个行业而不是单个企业层面,从而产生规模经济的累积收益,而不是特定企业的收益。因此,与其他贸易产品相比,全球制造业价值链(GMVCs)内的贸易产品可能会经历较慢的价格上涨(从而较快的数量增长)。有证据表明,大约从 20 世纪 90 年代初开始,信息技术(IT)产品(计算机、数据存储和通信设备)、汽车和其他各种相关的 GMVC 产品的价格大幅下降,其根源在于半导体技术的发展(Jorgenson,2001 年;Byrne 等人,2016 年)。与 Baldwin 等人的图 1 中两个名义比率的急剧下降相比,2008 年后实际贸易与 GDP 比率的相对稳定或许表明了这种价格效应。不过,我怀疑用于平减名义出口的价格指数并不能完全反映全球生产共享的降价效应。为了更好地捕捉全球生产共享贸易的价格效应,我们精心构建了一个新的数据集,使用该数据集进行分析后得出的推论是,商品贸易与国内生产总值的比率尚未见顶,在 2008-2009 年期间急剧下降之后,该比率继续保持危机前的趋势(Athukorala,2023 年)。全球服务贸易持续蓬勃发展这一重要推论令人欣慰。首先,鲍德温等人没有充分关注新出现的制造业 "服务化 "进程:传统上被视为制造业产出一部分的一些与制造业相关的服务转移到服务业公司,成为全球价值链运作的一个组成部分。如果不将这些作为制造业组成部分的服务与中间服务区分开来,就会人为地增加服务在经济全球化中的作用。此外,服务化对贸易和产业政策的制定也提出了挑战,因为不仅是传统形式的贸易保护,针对服务业的壁垒也可能影响制造业(Hoekman &amp; Shepherd, 2017)。因此,鲍德温等人将服务贸易与商品贸易截然分开的做法值得重新考虑。其次,鲍德温等人的数据似乎表明,服务贸易的增长可能会进一步扩大世界经济的南北差距。与商品贸易不同,服务贸易主要集中在北方国家(鲍德温等人的图 7 和图 11)。与出口能力不是从事服务贸易的限制因素的说法相反,缺乏适当技能的劳动力仍然是大多数发展中国家在参与与信息技术相关的现代服务业时面临的主要制约因素。此外,就创造就业的潜力而言,现代服务业不可能与制造业相提并论,特别是在吸收非熟练劳动力方面。 例如,印度以信息技术为基础的服务行业的就业弹性相对较低,该行业的就业至少需要大学教育水平(Panagariya,2008 年,第 286 页)。
{"title":"Comment on “Deconstructing Deglobalization: The Future of Trade is in Intermediate Services”","authors":"Prema-chandra Athukorala","doi":"10.1111/aepr.12443","DOIUrl":"10.1111/aepr.12443","url":null,"abstract":"<p>The paper by Baldwin <i>et al</i>. (<span>2024</span>) aims to demonstrate that the future of economic globalization lies in services trade as the expansion of merchandise trade has already begun to run out of steam.</p><p>Baldwin <i>et al</i>. begin with a narrative of growth of world merchandise trade relative to world income (gross domestic product [GDP]), both in aggregate and by major trading nations and the three main sectors, manufacturing, mining and fuel, and agriculture. The data suggest that the trade-to-GDP ratio peeked around 2008, even though the peak was not equally present in all major nations and all sectors. However, Baldwin <i>et al</i>. have stopped short of probing the underlying drivers of the observed structural change. If the “hyper globalization” during 1985–2008 had been largely driven by cyclical rather than structural factors, it is hazardous to treat the subsequent slowdown as a structural phenomenon. Moreover, the observed trends in the trade to GDP ratio need to be treated with caution because the well-known structural shift in the composition of GDP from tradable production and toward services. Given this structural change, the measured trade-to-GDP ratio is likely to face downward pressure, thus confirming the fear of deglobalization.</p><p>My major concern with the inference of trade slowdown is that it has overlooked possible changes in the price structure of global manufacturing trade associated with production fragmentation (vertical specialization). Production fragmentation essentially means restructuring of the production process of a given product among firms located in different regions and countries. In this process, as Young (<span>1928</span>) postulates, increasing returns take place throughout the industry rather than at the individual firm level, generating cumulative, rather than firm-specific, gains from scale economies. Therefore, goods traded within global manufacturing value chain (GMVCs) could experience slower price increases (and hence faster volume growth) compared to the other traded goods.</p><p>There is evidence of significant decline, rooted in developments in semiconductor technology, of prices of information technology (IT) products (computers, and data storage and communicating equipment), automobiles and a wide range of other related GMVC products from about the early 1990s (Jorgenson, <span>2001</span>; Byrne <i>et al</i>., <span>2016</span>). The relative stability of the real trade-to-GDP ratio after 2008, compared to the sharp decline in the two nominal ratios in Baldwin <i>et al</i>.'s figure 1, is perhaps indicative of this price effect. However, I suspect that, the price index used to deflate the nominal exports does not fully capture the price lowering effect of global production sharing. An analysis using a new dataset, which is carefully constructed to better capture the price effects of GMVC trade, yields the inference that merchandise trade to GDP ratio has not yet pee","PeriodicalId":45430,"journal":{"name":"Asian Economic Policy Review","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":3.9,"publicationDate":"2023-09-11","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/aepr.12443","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"136024699","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"OA","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Comment on “Supply Chain Decoupling: Geopolitical Debates and Economic Dynamism in East Asia” 评论 "供应链脱钩:东亚的地缘政治辩论与经济活力" 发表评论
IF 3.9 3区 经济学 Q1 Economics, Econometrics and Finance Pub Date : 2023-09-04 DOI: 10.1111/aepr.12442
Sébastien Miroudot

While the COVID-19 pandemic raised questions about vulnerabilities to economic shocks resulting from production in global supply chains, the debate has recently shifted to geopolitical risks. Russia's war of aggression against Ukraine has highlighted that trade dependencies in international production networks can be “weaponized” (Farrell & Newman, 2022). Escalating geopolitical tensions between the USA and China hint at a potential “bifurcated global economy” (Teece, 2022).

However, contrary to the prevailing narrative, compelling evidence of widespread decoupling or deglobalization remains elusive. Inter-country input–output tables that track flows of value added across countries at the aggregate level reveal a slowdown in the fragmentation of production since the 2008–2009 Financial Crisis (Jaax et al., 2023). Yet, globalization has not regressed. Production fragmentation persists at historically high levels, even after the COVID-19 pandemic. However, East Asia presents a nuanced picture with China moving toward more domestic supply chains since the mid-2000s. This trend can be explained by a decline in processing trade and more exports of branded products following the upgrading of Chinese value chains. It is therefore important to disentangle recent trends related to COVID-19 and geopolitical tensions from more structural trends.

The paper by Ando et al. (2024) is one of the first to look at some evidence of supply chain decoupling in East Asia, with a focus on machinery international production networks. Ando et al. confirm that, when looking at aggregate trade data, there is no significant change in exports and imports in the region, despite the recently introduced trade controls that affect this industry. However, disaggregated trade data, coupled with econometric analyses accounting for COVID-19-induced shifts, reveal the negative impact of some US export restrictions on high-tech goods. The impact on Japanese exports to China is particularly strong in the case of wireless communication equipment.

A notable conceptual contribution from Ando et al. is the distinction between “defensive” and “offensive” decoupling. Defensive decoupling encompasses policy measures that are aimed at mitigating the impact of sudden disruptions in the supply of imported products from strategic rivals. The debate on reshoring, “friend-shoring” or diversification of supply to reduce trade dependencies is often focused on this type of decoupling. Leaving aside the case of reshoring (which is generally not a realistic option), defensive decoupling is more likely to lead to a re-organization of supply chains for domestic firms (still with important costs). Conversely, offensive decoupling entails measures that are designed to restrict access to technologies and products in nonfriendly countries and that directly hurt exports of domestic firms and firms in partne

尽管 COVID-19 大流行病提出了全球供应链中的生产易受经济冲击影响的问题,但最近的讨论已转向地缘政治风险。俄罗斯对乌克兰的侵略战争突出表明,国际生产网络中的贸易依赖性可以被 "武器化"(Farrell & Newman, 2022)。美国和中国之间不断升级的地缘政治紧张局势暗示着潜在的 "全球经济分叉"(Teece,2022 年)。然而,与普遍的说法相反,关于普遍脱钩或去全球化的令人信服的证据仍然难以捉摸。国家间投入产出表在总体水平上跟踪了各国间的附加值流动,显示自 2008-2009 年金融危机以来,生产的分散化程度有所放缓(Jaax 等人,2023 年)。然而,全球化并未倒退。即使在 COVID-19 大流行之后,生产分化仍处于历史高位。然而,东亚的情况却有细微差别,自 2000 年代中期以来,中国正朝着更多国内供应链的方向发展。这一趋势的原因是,随着中国价值链的升级,加工贸易减少,品牌产品出口增加。因此,将与 COVID-19 和地缘政治紧张局势有关的近期趋势与更具结构性的趋势区分开来非常重要。Ando 等人证实,从总体贸易数据来看,尽管最近出台的贸易管制措施对该行业产生了影响,但该地区的进出口并没有发生重大变化。然而,分类贸易数据以及考虑到 COVID-19 引起的变化的计量经济学分析表明,美国的一些出口限制措施对高科技产品产生了负面影响。Ando 等人在概念上的一个显著贡献是区分了 "防御性 "和 "进攻性 "脱钩。防御性脱钩包括旨在减轻战略竞争对手进口产品供应突然中断的影响的政策措施。关于转厂、"友商转厂 "或供应多样化以减少贸易依赖性的辩论往往集中在这种类型的脱钩上。撇开转产的情况不谈(一般来说这不是一个现实的选择),防御性脱钩更有可能导致国内企业重新组织供应链(仍然会产生重要的成本)。反之,进攻性脱钩则需要采取措施,限制获得非友好国家的技术和产品,并在没有明确替代市场的情况下直接损害国内企业和伙伴国企业的出口。正如 Ando 等人(2024 年)所总结的,应在受出口管制的经济部分与其他活动之间设定一条明确的边界线,在这些活动中,国际生产网络的利益将得到保留。对 "西方 "和 "东方 "之间更广泛脱钩的经济模拟显示,福利损失巨大(Felbermayr et al.因此,有必要对政策措施进行细致的影响分析,并将合规成本降至最低。进攻性脱钩可能会适得其反,或在伙伴国造成 "友军误伤"。Ando 等人在研究中提出的一个重要观点是,很难评估在地缘政治风险背景下制定的贸易管制和新措施的影响。除了常规的贸易数据汇总问题外,还缺乏有关政府制定的规则及其执行情况的信息。提高透明度不仅对影响评估很重要,而且对企业更好地进行调整也很重要,同时还能维护公平的竞争环境。在当前的国际商业环境中,不确定性已成为贸易和投资的一个重要障碍。
{"title":"Comment on “Supply Chain Decoupling: Geopolitical Debates and Economic Dynamism in East Asia”","authors":"Sébastien Miroudot","doi":"10.1111/aepr.12442","DOIUrl":"10.1111/aepr.12442","url":null,"abstract":"<p>While the COVID-19 pandemic raised questions about vulnerabilities to economic shocks resulting from production in global supply chains, the debate has recently shifted to geopolitical risks. Russia's war of aggression against Ukraine has highlighted that trade dependencies in international production networks can be “weaponized” (Farrell &amp; Newman, <span>2022</span>). Escalating geopolitical tensions between the USA and China hint at a potential “bifurcated global economy” (Teece, <span>2022</span>).</p><p>However, contrary to the prevailing narrative, compelling evidence of widespread decoupling or deglobalization remains elusive. Inter-country input–output tables that track flows of value added across countries at the aggregate level reveal a slowdown in the fragmentation of production since the 2008–2009 Financial Crisis (Jaax <i>et al</i>., <span>2023</span>). Yet, globalization has not regressed. Production fragmentation persists at historically high levels, even after the COVID-19 pandemic. However, East Asia presents a nuanced picture with China moving toward more domestic supply chains since the mid-2000s. This trend can be explained by a decline in processing trade and more exports of branded products following the upgrading of Chinese value chains. It is therefore important to disentangle recent trends related to COVID-19 and geopolitical tensions from more structural trends.</p><p>The paper by Ando <i>et al</i>. (<span>2024</span>) is one of the first to look at some evidence of supply chain decoupling in East Asia, with a focus on machinery international production networks. Ando <i>et al</i>. confirm that, when looking at aggregate trade data, there is no significant change in exports and imports in the region, despite the recently introduced trade controls that affect this industry. However, disaggregated trade data, coupled with econometric analyses accounting for COVID-19-induced shifts, reveal the negative impact of some US export restrictions on high-tech goods. The impact on Japanese exports to China is particularly strong in the case of wireless communication equipment.</p><p>A notable conceptual contribution from Ando <i>et al</i>. is the distinction between “defensive” and “offensive” decoupling. Defensive decoupling encompasses policy measures that are aimed at mitigating the impact of sudden disruptions in the supply of imported products from strategic rivals. The debate on reshoring, “friend-shoring” or diversification of supply to reduce trade dependencies is often focused on this type of decoupling. Leaving aside the case of reshoring (which is generally not a realistic option), defensive decoupling is more likely to lead to a re-organization of supply chains for domestic firms (still with important costs). Conversely, offensive decoupling entails measures that are designed to restrict access to technologies and products in nonfriendly countries and that directly hurt exports of domestic firms and firms in partne","PeriodicalId":45430,"journal":{"name":"Asian Economic Policy Review","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":3.9,"publicationDate":"2023-09-04","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/aepr.12442","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"73121168","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"OA","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Comment on “Supply Chain Decoupling: Geopolitical Debates and Economic Dynamism in East Asia” 评论 "供应链脱钩:东亚的地缘政治辩论与经济活力" 发表评论
IF 3.9 3区 经济学 Q1 Economics, Econometrics and Finance Pub Date : 2023-08-29 DOI: 10.1111/aepr.12441
Keiko Ito

Ando et al. (2024) examine how the tightening of export control regulations by the USA in recent years has affected the exports of three East Asian countries – Japan, South Korea, and Taiwan – to China. Given that China is the most important trading partner for these three countries, Ando et al.'s paper focuses on a very important issue for the region.

Ando et al. closely examine the impact of the US Foreign Direct Product Rule (FDPR) on Japan's exports. Many interesting results are presented, but I would like to highlight two in particular. First, Ando et al. find that the strengthening of the US FDPR significantly reduced Japan's exports of related products to China. Interestingly, their estimation results (Ando et al.'s table 2) imply that it is the more semiconductor-intensive, that is, more high-tech, products that are negatively affected, while exports of less high-tech products may have increased. Since the US FDPR specifically targets high-tech products, the finding suggests that the measure is having the intended effect.

Second, in terms of the size of the impact, Ando et al. estimate that the reduction of Japanese exports to China due to the FDPR amounted to 3.3% of the total value of Japanese exports to China in 2019. Accurately measuring the impact of export controls is very difficult, and the 3.3% estimate may be a slight overestimate. However, compared to the increase in exports from Japan to China (in Japanese yen terms) from 2014 to 2019 of about 10% over the 5-year period, this 3.3% impact is too large to ignore.

While Ando et al.'s attempt to quantitatively examine the impact of export controls is an important first step, there are still a large range of issues that have not yet been addressed. I would like to highlight key issues that warrant attention in the future. First, it is very difficult to identify the scope of export controls and quantitatively measure the impact of export controls. For example, Hayakawa et al. (2023) also show the negative impact of the tightening of the US FDPR, but their estimate of the size of the impact (0.2%) was considerably smaller than Ando et al.'s (3.3%). Although the two results cannot be compared directly because of the different empirical methods and time periods, this difference in the results may partly reflect the difficulty of quantifying the impact of export controls. Nevertheless, it is worth trying to investigate the impact, and accumulating empirical results will help us get closer to the true picture.

Second, I would like to highlight the importance of micro-level studies. Export controls may severely affect specific firms that heavily rely on exports of the products subject to the regulations. For example, it has been reported that some Japanese firms that had heavily relied on exports of hydrogen fluoride to Korea experienced a large decline in exports and profits

Ando 等人(2024 年)研究了近年来美国收紧出口管制法规对日本、韩国和中国台湾这三个东亚国家对华出口的影响。鉴于中国是这三个国家最重要的贸易伙伴,Ando 等人的论文聚焦于该地区一个非常重要的问题。Ando 等人仔细研究了美国外国直接产品规则(FDPR)对日本出口的影响。文中提出了许多有趣的结果,但我想特别强调其中的两项。首先,Ando 等人发现美国 FDPR 的加强大大减少了日本相关产品对中国的出口。有趣的是,他们的估计结果(Ando 等人的表 2)表明,受到负面影响的是半导体密集型产品,即高科技产品,而高科技含量较低的产品的出口可能有所增加。由于美国的 FDPR 专门针对高科技产品,这一结果表明该措施正在产生预期效果。其次,就影响的规模而言,Ando 等人估计,FDPR 导致的日本对华出口减少额占 2019 年日本对华出口总值的 3.3%。准确衡量出口管制的影响非常困难,3.3% 的估计可能略有高估。然而,与 2014 年至 2019 年这 5 年间日本对华出口额(按日元计算)约 10%的增长相比,这 3.3% 的影响实在太大,不容忽视。我想强调一下未来值得关注的关键问题。首先,确定出口管制的范围和定量衡量出口管制的影响非常困难。例如,Hayakawa 等人(2023 年)的研究也显示了美国 FDPR 收紧的负面影响,但他们估计的影响规模(0.2%)要比 Ando 等人的估计(3.3%)小得多。虽然由于实证方法和时间段不同,无法直接比较这两个结果,但结果的差异可能部分反映了量化出口管制影响的难度。尽管如此,还是值得尝试调查其影响,积累经验结果将有助于我们更接近真实情况。出口管制可能会严重影响严重依赖受管制产品出口的特定企业。例如,据报道,由于日本于 2019 年 7 月 4 日开始收紧对韩国的化工产品出口管制,一些严重依赖向韩国出口氟化氢的日本企业的出口和利润大幅下降。这一经验表明,政策制定者应密切关注此类微观层面的影响。第三,韩国和中国台湾未来可能会受到美国收紧FDPR和各种半导体相关产品限制的更严重影响,因为根据贸易统计数据,韩国和中国台湾似乎比日本更依赖向中国出口集成电路产品。安藤等人的研究主要集中在美国 FDPR 对日本出口的影响上,而美国加强监管对韩国和台湾地区的量化影响则应仔细关注。正如 Ando 等人在结论中提到的,与贸易管制相关的巨额合规成本将抑制经济活动,而对于中小型企业来说,这种成本负担可能会更重。我非常同意 Ando 等人的观点,即东亚国家政府 "需要与美国政府进行良好的沟通,并帮助其私营部门避免巨额合规成本。"此外,我们应该意识到,正如有关中美贸易战和西方国家对俄罗斯制裁的研究表明的那样,收紧法规可能不仅会对目标国产生负面影响,也会对收紧法规的国家产生负面影响。还有一些轶事证据表明,监管并不总能产生预期效果。例如,20 世纪 80 年代缔结的《日美半导体协议》所带来的增长是韩国和台湾半导体产业的增长,而不是美国半导体产业的增长。此外,美国商务部的调查(2014 年)报告称,对太空相关产品和服务的出口管制对美国太空产业的健康和竞争力产生了不利影响。
{"title":"Comment on “Supply Chain Decoupling: Geopolitical Debates and Economic Dynamism in East Asia”","authors":"Keiko Ito","doi":"10.1111/aepr.12441","DOIUrl":"10.1111/aepr.12441","url":null,"abstract":"<p>Ando <i>et al</i>. (<span>2024</span>) examine how the tightening of export control regulations by the USA in recent years has affected the exports of three East Asian countries – Japan, South Korea, and Taiwan – to China. Given that China is the most important trading partner for these three countries, Ando <i>et al</i>.'s paper focuses on a very important issue for the region.</p><p>Ando <i>et al</i>. closely examine the impact of the US Foreign Direct Product Rule (FDPR) on Japan's exports. Many interesting results are presented, but I would like to highlight two in particular. First, Ando <i>et al</i>. find that the strengthening of the US FDPR significantly reduced Japan's exports of related products to China. Interestingly, their estimation results (Ando <i>et al</i>.'s table 2) imply that it is the more semiconductor-intensive, that is, more high-tech, products that are negatively affected, while exports of less high-tech products may have increased. Since the US FDPR specifically targets high-tech products, the finding suggests that the measure is having the intended effect.</p><p>Second, in terms of the size of the impact, Ando <i>et al</i>. estimate that the reduction of Japanese exports to China due to the FDPR amounted to 3.3% of the total value of Japanese exports to China in 2019. Accurately measuring the impact of export controls is very difficult, and the 3.3% estimate may be a slight overestimate. However, compared to the increase in exports from Japan to China (in Japanese yen terms) from 2014 to 2019 of about 10% over the 5-year period, this 3.3% impact is too large to ignore.</p><p>While Ando <i>et al</i>.'s attempt to quantitatively examine the impact of export controls is an important first step, there are still a large range of issues that have not yet been addressed. I would like to highlight key issues that warrant attention in the future. First, it is very difficult to identify the scope of export controls and quantitatively measure the impact of export controls. For example, Hayakawa <i>et al</i>. (<span>2023</span>) also show the negative impact of the tightening of the US FDPR, but their estimate of the size of the impact (0.2%) was considerably smaller than Ando <i>et al</i>.'s (3.3%). Although the two results cannot be compared directly because of the different empirical methods and time periods, this difference in the results may partly reflect the difficulty of quantifying the impact of export controls. Nevertheless, it is worth trying to investigate the impact, and accumulating empirical results will help us get closer to the true picture.</p><p>Second, I would like to highlight the importance of micro-level studies. Export controls may severely affect specific firms that heavily rely on exports of the products subject to the regulations. For example, it has been reported that some Japanese firms that had heavily relied on exports of hydrogen fluoride to Korea experienced a large decline in exports and profits","PeriodicalId":45430,"journal":{"name":"Asian Economic Policy Review","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":3.9,"publicationDate":"2023-08-29","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/aepr.12441","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"84240851","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"OA","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Supply Chain Decoupling: Geopolitical Debates and Economic Dynamism in East Asia 供应链脱钩:东亚地缘政治辩论与经济活力
IF 3.9 3区 经济学 Q1 Economics, Econometrics and Finance Pub Date : 2023-08-09 DOI: 10.1111/aepr.12439
Mitsuyo Ando, Kazunobu Hayakawa, Fukunari Kimura

Supply chain decoupling in the US–China confrontation has generated serious uncertainties for private businesses. This paper focuses on machinery international production networks in East Asia and tries to find quantitative evidence on supply chain decoupling by using international trade statistics, particularly from the viewpoint of middle powers such as Japan. While data on the sectoral level of trade do not show any clear evidence of supply chain decoupling, some specific US export controls indeed affect international transactions when examined at a finely disaggregated level. We econometrically measure the effect of some of the US policies on Japanese exports to China. The recent strengthening of US export controls related to supercomputers and advanced integrated circuits is likely to generate further effects. Nevertheless, the supply chain decoupling seems to end up as a partial one, and a large portion of International Production Networks (IPNs) may remain active. In conclusion, the paper briefly discusses the policy implications of the analysis.

中美对抗中的供应链脱钩给私营企业带来了严重的不确定性。本文重点关注东亚的机械国际生产网络,并试图利用国际贸易统计数据,特别是从日本等中等强国的视角,寻找供应链脱钩的量化证据。虽然贸易部门层面的数据并未显示出供应链脱钩的明确证据,但从细分层面来看,美国的一些特定出口管制确实影响了国际交易。我们用计量经济学方法测算了美国某些政策对日本对华出口的影响。最近,美国加强了对超级计算机和先进集成电路的出口管制,这可能会产生进一步的影响。尽管如此,供应链脱钩似乎只是局部的,大部分国际生产网络(IPNs)可能会继续保持活跃。最后,本文简要讨论了分析的政策影响。
{"title":"Supply Chain Decoupling: Geopolitical Debates and Economic Dynamism in East Asia","authors":"Mitsuyo Ando,&nbsp;Kazunobu Hayakawa,&nbsp;Fukunari Kimura","doi":"10.1111/aepr.12439","DOIUrl":"10.1111/aepr.12439","url":null,"abstract":"<p>Supply chain decoupling in the US–China confrontation has generated serious uncertainties for private businesses. This paper focuses on machinery international production networks in East Asia and tries to find quantitative evidence on supply chain decoupling by using international trade statistics, particularly from the viewpoint of middle powers such as Japan. While data on the sectoral level of trade do not show any clear evidence of supply chain decoupling, some specific US export controls indeed affect international transactions when examined at a finely disaggregated level. We econometrically measure the effect of some of the US policies on Japanese exports to China. The recent strengthening of US export controls related to supercomputers and advanced integrated circuits is likely to generate further effects. Nevertheless, the supply chain decoupling seems to end up as a partial one, and a large portion of International Production Networks (IPNs) may remain active. In conclusion, the paper briefly discusses the policy implications of the analysis.</p>","PeriodicalId":45430,"journal":{"name":"Asian Economic Policy Review","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":3.9,"publicationDate":"2023-08-09","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/aepr.12439","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"86387693","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"OA","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Japan Center for Economic Research 日本经济研究中心
IF 3.9 3区 经济学 Q1 Economics, Econometrics and Finance Pub Date : 2023-07-04 DOI: 10.1111/aepr.12438
{"title":"Japan Center for Economic Research","authors":"","doi":"10.1111/aepr.12438","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1111/aepr.12438","url":null,"abstract":"","PeriodicalId":45430,"journal":{"name":"Asian Economic Policy Review","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":3.9,"publicationDate":"2023-07-04","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/aepr.12438","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"50127859","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"OA","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
期刊
Asian Economic Policy Review
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1