{"title":"Japan Center for Economic Research","authors":"","doi":"10.1111/aepr.12460","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1111/aepr.12460","url":null,"abstract":"","PeriodicalId":45430,"journal":{"name":"Asian Economic Policy Review","volume":"19 1","pages":"152"},"PeriodicalIF":3.9,"publicationDate":"2024-01-16","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/aepr.12460","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"139473916","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"OA","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
<p>Meltzer (<span>2024</span>) discusses the key challenges and risks of artificial intelligence (AI)/ChatGPT, as well as the role of international trade agreements and other economic fora in addressing them. Meltzer also argues that the less formalized grouping such as the US-EU Trade and Technology Council (TTC), the Indo-Pacific Economic Framework for Prosperity (IPEF), and the Quad can do a better job in this, than traditional trade negotiating agreements.</p><p>I have three comments, each from trade policy, Schumpeterian, and geopolitics perspective, respectively.</p><p>First, Meltzer points out that IPEF and US-EU TTC are not for trade negotiations but for aligning approaches to technological issues involving opportunities and challenges of emerging technologies. For instance, IPEF addresses cooperation on regulation and standards related to AI, whereas the TTC discusses trustworthy and innovative AI as its key priority. This is an important interpretation, given the existing criticism that IPEF does not offer any new (US) market access to member economies, and so its impact will be limited. However, it makes sense for the USA as it now perceives free trade agreements (FTA) having benefited not the USA but China. Whereas FTA have resulted in losses of manufacturing jobs in the USA, IPEF might not do so but rather contribute to securing future high-tech markets and global value chains (GVC).</p><p>Second, a Schumpeterian comment is about ChatGPT (generative pre-trained transformers), which is pointed out as GPT (general purpose technologies). Meltzer discusses the results of an interesting research that with the spread of ChatGPT, global gross domestic product (GDP) may increase by 14% by 2030, creating additional incomes of $US 16 trillion. Such positive impacts are possible because many job tasks can be finished faster with the same quality. In the literature, GPT are defined as technologies that are pervasive, exhibit strong complementary abilities, and thus can be used in a multitude of applications (Bresnahan & Trajtenberg, <span>1995</span>). Some argue that the 4th Industrial Revolution (4IR) technologies might be GPT given their transformative potential involving digitization and automation. A similar term in Schumpeterian economics is “key factor inputs” which exhibit low and falling relative costs, with availability of supply over long periods and the potential for the use or incorporation in various products and processes throughout the economic system. Such inputs, once they appear, may correspond to a techno-economic paradigm shift (Dosi, <span>1982</span>) and thus bring in a new long wave of boom in economies. Examples of key factor inputs were microelectronics since 1970, or electricity in the 20th century.</p><p>There are ways to verify whether or not some technologies are GPT. Lee and Lee (<span>2021</span>) use three criteria: (i) “generality” (e.g. technologies with wider applications and impacts and thus cited widely
此外,还可能争夺第三市场,例如非洲或中东市场。
{"title":"Comment on “The Impact of Foundational AI on International Trade, Services and Supply Chains in Asia”","authors":"Keun Lee","doi":"10.1111/aepr.12455","DOIUrl":"10.1111/aepr.12455","url":null,"abstract":"<p>Meltzer (<span>2024</span>) discusses the key challenges and risks of artificial intelligence (AI)/ChatGPT, as well as the role of international trade agreements and other economic fora in addressing them. Meltzer also argues that the less formalized grouping such as the US-EU Trade and Technology Council (TTC), the Indo-Pacific Economic Framework for Prosperity (IPEF), and the Quad can do a better job in this, than traditional trade negotiating agreements.</p><p>I have three comments, each from trade policy, Schumpeterian, and geopolitics perspective, respectively.</p><p>First, Meltzer points out that IPEF and US-EU TTC are not for trade negotiations but for aligning approaches to technological issues involving opportunities and challenges of emerging technologies. For instance, IPEF addresses cooperation on regulation and standards related to AI, whereas the TTC discusses trustworthy and innovative AI as its key priority. This is an important interpretation, given the existing criticism that IPEF does not offer any new (US) market access to member economies, and so its impact will be limited. However, it makes sense for the USA as it now perceives free trade agreements (FTA) having benefited not the USA but China. Whereas FTA have resulted in losses of manufacturing jobs in the USA, IPEF might not do so but rather contribute to securing future high-tech markets and global value chains (GVC).</p><p>Second, a Schumpeterian comment is about ChatGPT (generative pre-trained transformers), which is pointed out as GPT (general purpose technologies). Meltzer discusses the results of an interesting research that with the spread of ChatGPT, global gross domestic product (GDP) may increase by 14% by 2030, creating additional incomes of $US 16 trillion. Such positive impacts are possible because many job tasks can be finished faster with the same quality. In the literature, GPT are defined as technologies that are pervasive, exhibit strong complementary abilities, and thus can be used in a multitude of applications (Bresnahan & Trajtenberg, <span>1995</span>). Some argue that the 4th Industrial Revolution (4IR) technologies might be GPT given their transformative potential involving digitization and automation. A similar term in Schumpeterian economics is “key factor inputs” which exhibit low and falling relative costs, with availability of supply over long periods and the potential for the use or incorporation in various products and processes throughout the economic system. Such inputs, once they appear, may correspond to a techno-economic paradigm shift (Dosi, <span>1982</span>) and thus bring in a new long wave of boom in economies. Examples of key factor inputs were microelectronics since 1970, or electricity in the 20th century.</p><p>There are ways to verify whether or not some technologies are GPT. Lee and Lee (<span>2021</span>) use three criteria: (i) “generality” (e.g. technologies with wider applications and impacts and thus cited widely","PeriodicalId":45430,"journal":{"name":"Asian Economic Policy Review","volume":"19 1","pages":"150-151"},"PeriodicalIF":3.9,"publicationDate":"2023-12-13","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/aepr.12455","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"139004879","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"OA","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
<p>Meltzer (<span>2024</span>) does an admirable job of mapping recent technological developments in AI to the current institutions of the international trading system. This is a useful taxonomy.</p><p>I raise two concerns. First, AI's net effects on employment and output are inextricably linked to the pace of AI's adoption by industry. Meltzer notes that recent leaps in the capabilities of AI models have been accompanied by exponential increases for the “AI compute” needed to train these models. However, it is still very uncertain whether the cost of AI compute in the twenty-first century is going to decline over time at a rate resembling that of general-purpose computing in the twentieth century, and, therefore, whether twenty-first century AI comes into widespread industrial use quickly.</p><p>In the twentieth century, “Moore's Law” was code for a cadence of technological innovation in semiconductors that produced 20% to 30% annual declines in (quality-adjusted) computer hardware cost, and impressive declines in the energy needed for computing, lasting decades. Continuing price declines for computing created economic incentives to use computing in all kinds of new applications, across all sectors of the economy, substituting for labor, other forms of capital, and raw materials, and increasing productivity and living standards. (Jorgenson, <span>2001</span>).</p><p>By the second decade of the twenty-first century, however, while some Moore's Law-style miniaturization of semiconductors continued at a slower pace, quality-adjusted semiconductor prices were no longer falling at earlier double-digit rates. (Flamm, <span>2017</span>, <span>2021</span>; Sawyer & So, <span>2018</span>) Slackening technological improvement in chip manufacturing means that some new engine is needed to drive AI compute costs lower. Absent steady declines in AI compute costs, a rapid uptake of AI across broad sectors of the economy is unlikely to materialize.</p><p>Second, national security is tightly linked to AI, and, therefore, likely to drive national policies and investments relevant to cutting edge AI technology. This was the case when military investments first kickstarted the computer and semiconductor industries seventy-five years ago (Flamm, <span>1987</span>). Militaries the world over are currently investigating incorporation of AI into autonomous military weapons systems platforms, and into security and disinformation systems that conduct information warfare operations in cyberspace. Use of the most advanced available semiconductor manufacturing technology is required to produce specialized AI compute capability in its fastest, densest (lowest weight and smallest size), and least energy intensive form factor, which translates into greater potential capability for a “smart” weapons system or an edge-connected network device, for any given weight, energy, and size budget.</p><p>As a result, responding to rising global political tensions and following the US
{"title":"Comment on “The Impact of Foundational AI on International Trade, Services and Supply Chains in Asia”","authors":"Kenneth Flamm","doi":"10.1111/aepr.12456","DOIUrl":"10.1111/aepr.12456","url":null,"abstract":"<p>Meltzer (<span>2024</span>) does an admirable job of mapping recent technological developments in AI to the current institutions of the international trading system. This is a useful taxonomy.</p><p>I raise two concerns. First, AI's net effects on employment and output are inextricably linked to the pace of AI's adoption by industry. Meltzer notes that recent leaps in the capabilities of AI models have been accompanied by exponential increases for the “AI compute” needed to train these models. However, it is still very uncertain whether the cost of AI compute in the twenty-first century is going to decline over time at a rate resembling that of general-purpose computing in the twentieth century, and, therefore, whether twenty-first century AI comes into widespread industrial use quickly.</p><p>In the twentieth century, “Moore's Law” was code for a cadence of technological innovation in semiconductors that produced 20% to 30% annual declines in (quality-adjusted) computer hardware cost, and impressive declines in the energy needed for computing, lasting decades. Continuing price declines for computing created economic incentives to use computing in all kinds of new applications, across all sectors of the economy, substituting for labor, other forms of capital, and raw materials, and increasing productivity and living standards. (Jorgenson, <span>2001</span>).</p><p>By the second decade of the twenty-first century, however, while some Moore's Law-style miniaturization of semiconductors continued at a slower pace, quality-adjusted semiconductor prices were no longer falling at earlier double-digit rates. (Flamm, <span>2017</span>, <span>2021</span>; Sawyer & So, <span>2018</span>) Slackening technological improvement in chip manufacturing means that some new engine is needed to drive AI compute costs lower. Absent steady declines in AI compute costs, a rapid uptake of AI across broad sectors of the economy is unlikely to materialize.</p><p>Second, national security is tightly linked to AI, and, therefore, likely to drive national policies and investments relevant to cutting edge AI technology. This was the case when military investments first kickstarted the computer and semiconductor industries seventy-five years ago (Flamm, <span>1987</span>). Militaries the world over are currently investigating incorporation of AI into autonomous military weapons systems platforms, and into security and disinformation systems that conduct information warfare operations in cyberspace. Use of the most advanced available semiconductor manufacturing technology is required to produce specialized AI compute capability in its fastest, densest (lowest weight and smallest size), and least energy intensive form factor, which translates into greater potential capability for a “smart” weapons system or an edge-connected network device, for any given weight, energy, and size budget.</p><p>As a result, responding to rising global political tensions and following the US","PeriodicalId":45430,"journal":{"name":"Asian Economic Policy Review","volume":"19 1","pages":"148-149"},"PeriodicalIF":3.9,"publicationDate":"2023-12-05","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/aepr.12456","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"138599100","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"OA","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
<p>Arimura and Sugino (<span>2024</span>) explain well how the volatility and high prices of fossil fuels due to the Russian invasion of Ukraine have caused a global crisis. In fact, Dr. Fatih Birol, Executive Director of the International Energy Agency (IEA) called it “the first truly global energy crisis”. Energy security is the first priority for many if not all governments. Responses to this crisis by REPower EU as well as the US Inflation Reduction Act accelerate the decarbonization of industries everywhere. The EU's Carbon Border Adjustment Mechanism (CBAM) and the US decouple-China policy further complicate the situation. In this crisis, there are winners and losers: the EU and US are winners. China can be a renewable energy superpower, while India may increase its wind and solar dependency. Saudi Arabia may avoid stranded-assetization of its natural resources by using carbon capture and storage (CCS) to export blue hydrogen. Russia is the least prepared because of a lack of technology transfers due to sanctions, investment withdrawals, the increase of war expenses, and a brain drain. Can the ASEAN countries become winners? What about Japan and Korea?</p><p>For ASEAN countries, the key issue is if they can secure affordable finance for transition. As Arimura and Sugino say, natural gas has an important transitional role in replacing coal but its high and volatile prices due to geopolitical reasons may jeopardize a smooth transition. Japan has introduced the Asian Energy Transition Initiative with JPY 2 trillion, but international financial institutions must put more money into natural gas development to facilitate the transition. To provide a clear advantage for gas over coal, carbon pricing is essential. ASEAN countries must be prepared to introduce a region-wide carbon pricing mechanism as the EU has done with its emissions trading system (ETS). To phase out coal gradually, co-firing clean ammonia or hydrogen is a practical approach. Technology transfers and supply chain development for green/blue hydrogen and ammonia with CCS are needed.</p><p>The challenge for global carbon neutrality is providing affordable financing to developing countries. Renewable energy costs will decline further but its deployment needs investment. Inter-regional grid connection should be seriously considered for ASEAN countries which facilitates an expansion in the use of renewables while increasing energy security. The Joint Crediting Mechanism (JCM) is a useful tool to increase investment. There are gaps in regional CO<sub>2</sub> prices, high in the North and low in the South, which could facilitate carbon credit transfer from the South in return for investment from the North. A global framework for carbon credit trading is needed.</p><p>Another group of winners is the Megatech firms. Apple, for example, will force its whole supply chain to be carbon neutral by 2030. Device providers to Apple must consider relocating their production operations to low-carbon
{"title":"Comment on “Implications of Deglobalization on Energy and Carbon Neutrality in Asia and the Pacific Region”","authors":"Nobuo Tanaka","doi":"10.1111/aepr.12454","DOIUrl":"10.1111/aepr.12454","url":null,"abstract":"<p>Arimura and Sugino (<span>2024</span>) explain well how the volatility and high prices of fossil fuels due to the Russian invasion of Ukraine have caused a global crisis. In fact, Dr. Fatih Birol, Executive Director of the International Energy Agency (IEA) called it “the first truly global energy crisis”. Energy security is the first priority for many if not all governments. Responses to this crisis by REPower EU as well as the US Inflation Reduction Act accelerate the decarbonization of industries everywhere. The EU's Carbon Border Adjustment Mechanism (CBAM) and the US decouple-China policy further complicate the situation. In this crisis, there are winners and losers: the EU and US are winners. China can be a renewable energy superpower, while India may increase its wind and solar dependency. Saudi Arabia may avoid stranded-assetization of its natural resources by using carbon capture and storage (CCS) to export blue hydrogen. Russia is the least prepared because of a lack of technology transfers due to sanctions, investment withdrawals, the increase of war expenses, and a brain drain. Can the ASEAN countries become winners? What about Japan and Korea?</p><p>For ASEAN countries, the key issue is if they can secure affordable finance for transition. As Arimura and Sugino say, natural gas has an important transitional role in replacing coal but its high and volatile prices due to geopolitical reasons may jeopardize a smooth transition. Japan has introduced the Asian Energy Transition Initiative with JPY 2 trillion, but international financial institutions must put more money into natural gas development to facilitate the transition. To provide a clear advantage for gas over coal, carbon pricing is essential. ASEAN countries must be prepared to introduce a region-wide carbon pricing mechanism as the EU has done with its emissions trading system (ETS). To phase out coal gradually, co-firing clean ammonia or hydrogen is a practical approach. Technology transfers and supply chain development for green/blue hydrogen and ammonia with CCS are needed.</p><p>The challenge for global carbon neutrality is providing affordable financing to developing countries. Renewable energy costs will decline further but its deployment needs investment. Inter-regional grid connection should be seriously considered for ASEAN countries which facilitates an expansion in the use of renewables while increasing energy security. The Joint Crediting Mechanism (JCM) is a useful tool to increase investment. There are gaps in regional CO<sub>2</sub> prices, high in the North and low in the South, which could facilitate carbon credit transfer from the South in return for investment from the North. A global framework for carbon credit trading is needed.</p><p>Another group of winners is the Megatech firms. Apple, for example, will force its whole supply chain to be carbon neutral by 2030. Device providers to Apple must consider relocating their production operations to low-carbon","PeriodicalId":45430,"journal":{"name":"Asian Economic Policy Review","volume":"19 1","pages":"127-128"},"PeriodicalIF":3.9,"publicationDate":"2023-11-20","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/aepr.12454","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"139258755","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"OA","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}