首页 > 最新文献

Manchester School最新文献

英文 中文
Successful Central Banks Can Afford to Pay Scant Attention to Money
IF 0.7 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-12-12 DOI: 10.1111/manc.12506
Papadia Francesco, Cadamuro Leonardo

In the last few decades, central bankers and economists have paid little attention to monetary aggregates, in contrast with the experience of the 1970s and the 1980s. Our evidence shows that monetary aggregates lose relevance when central banks maintain low and stable inflation, as has occurred in recent decades. However, to move from unstable to stable inflation, our findings also show that attention to monetary aggregates is needed. Our findings help resolve the long-standing controversy about the importance of monetary aggregates for the conduct of monetary policy: monetary aggregates are vital to move from unstable to stable inflation but lose relevance once a central bank has consistently reached price stability.

{"title":"Successful Central Banks Can Afford to Pay Scant Attention to Money","authors":"Papadia Francesco,&nbsp;Cadamuro Leonardo","doi":"10.1111/manc.12506","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1111/manc.12506","url":null,"abstract":"<p>In the last few decades, central bankers and economists have paid little attention to monetary aggregates, in contrast with the experience of the 1970s and the 1980s. Our evidence shows that monetary aggregates lose relevance when central banks maintain low and stable inflation, as has occurred in recent decades. However, to move from unstable to stable inflation, our findings also show that attention to monetary aggregates is needed. Our findings help resolve the long-standing controversy about the importance of monetary aggregates for the conduct of monetary policy: monetary aggregates are vital to move from unstable to stable inflation but lose relevance once a central bank has consistently reached price stability.</p>","PeriodicalId":47546,"journal":{"name":"Manchester School","volume":"93 2","pages":"199-215"},"PeriodicalIF":0.7,"publicationDate":"2024-12-12","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/manc.12506","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"143114327","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"OA","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Trade Policy in a Third-Country Model With Kantian Optimization
IF 0.7 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-12-12 DOI: 10.1111/manc.12503
Leonard F. S. Wang, Di Wu, Can Yang

We address the issue of trade policies in a Kantian equilibrium. We find that “in principle” at Kantian equilibrium between the exporting countries, the trade policy is export tax. A Kantian equilibrium between the exporting countries leads to the lowest importing countries' consumer surplus, exporting firms' profits and global welfare, while the social welfare of the exporting countries is the highest. On the contrary, A Kantian equilibrium between the exporting firms leads to the highest importing countries' consumer surplus, exporting firms' profits and global welfare. The stability analysis demonstrates the robustness of our findings within an oligopoly comprising multiple exporters.

{"title":"Trade Policy in a Third-Country Model With Kantian Optimization","authors":"Leonard F. S. Wang,&nbsp;Di Wu,&nbsp;Can Yang","doi":"10.1111/manc.12503","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1111/manc.12503","url":null,"abstract":"<div>\u0000 \u0000 <p>We address the issue of trade policies in a Kantian equilibrium. We find that “in principle” at Kantian equilibrium between the exporting countries, the trade policy is export tax. A Kantian equilibrium between the exporting countries leads to the lowest importing countries' consumer surplus, exporting firms' profits and global welfare, while the social welfare of the exporting countries is the highest. On the contrary, A Kantian equilibrium between the exporting firms leads to the highest importing countries' consumer surplus, exporting firms' profits and global welfare. The stability analysis demonstrates the robustness of our findings within an oligopoly comprising multiple exporters.</p>\u0000 </div>","PeriodicalId":47546,"journal":{"name":"Manchester School","volume":"93 2","pages":"191-198"},"PeriodicalIF":0.7,"publicationDate":"2024-12-12","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"143114325","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Oil Price Shocks and Macroeconomic Fluctuations: A GVAR Approach
IF 0.7 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-12-11 DOI: 10.1111/manc.12502
Luccas Assis Attílio, André Varella Mollick

We investigate the effects of oil price shocks on industrial and emerging market economies. We use a global vector autoregressive (GVAR) model with 19 economies from 1999M1 to 2022M3. Our sample evaluates output responses of each country to the same global shock, defined in several ways. While we find that domestic prices and interest rates in industrial economies respond to the WTI real oil price shock, the generalized impulse response functions (GIRF) tend to be not statistically significant in emerging economies. Stock markets increase in the first months for the oil producers but have negative values in the long-run. The oil price shock causes a generalized fall in industrial production and loses importance over time. We reinforce our results by identifying the oil shock using the structural GIRF (SGIRF) following a causal ordering from oil to real output. When we decompose WTI into either supply or demand shocks, industrial production declines in the short-run due to supply shocks but increases in response to oil demand shocks. Our results are very robust, especially in industrial economies when allowing for time-varying bilateral trade. Underscoring the importance of identifying oil price shocks, the oil price shock pushes inflation up, prompting the central bank's response in policy rates.

{"title":"Oil Price Shocks and Macroeconomic Fluctuations: A GVAR Approach","authors":"Luccas Assis Attílio,&nbsp;André Varella Mollick","doi":"10.1111/manc.12502","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1111/manc.12502","url":null,"abstract":"<div>\u0000 \u0000 <p>We investigate the effects of oil price shocks on industrial and emerging market economies. We use a global vector autoregressive (GVAR) model with 19 economies from 1999M1 to 2022M3. Our sample evaluates output responses of each country to the same global shock, defined in several ways. While we find that domestic prices and interest rates in industrial economies respond to the WTI real oil price shock, the generalized impulse response functions (GIRF) tend to be not statistically significant in emerging economies. Stock markets increase in the first months for the oil producers but have negative values in the long-run. The oil price shock causes a generalized fall in industrial production and loses importance over time. We reinforce our results by identifying the oil shock using the structural GIRF (SGIRF) following a causal ordering from oil to real output. When we decompose WTI into either supply or demand shocks, industrial production declines in the short-run due to supply shocks but increases in response to oil demand shocks. Our results are very robust, especially in industrial economies when allowing for time-varying bilateral trade. Underscoring the importance of identifying oil price shocks, the oil price shock pushes inflation up, prompting the central bank's response in policy rates.</p>\u0000 </div>","PeriodicalId":47546,"journal":{"name":"Manchester School","volume":"93 2","pages":"170-190"},"PeriodicalIF":0.7,"publicationDate":"2024-12-11","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"143113912","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
The impact of wealth inequality on inflation and unfair competition among consumers
IF 0.7 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-09-28 DOI: 10.1111/manc.12500
Esat Daşdemir

This study examines unfair competition among consumers according to wealth groups. The study hypothesizes that consumer groups with high income and wealth levels have a competitive advantage over consumer groups with low income and wealth levels, and therefore wealth inequality may create upward pressure on prices. Data from 37 Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development member countries covering 2000–2022 were used in the analysis. According to the results of the analysis, increases in the wealth of high-wealth groups increase the inflation rate more severely.

{"title":"The impact of wealth inequality on inflation and unfair competition among consumers","authors":"Esat Daşdemir","doi":"10.1111/manc.12500","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1111/manc.12500","url":null,"abstract":"<p>This study examines unfair competition among consumers according to wealth groups. The study hypothesizes that consumer groups with high income and wealth levels have a competitive advantage over consumer groups with low income and wealth levels, and therefore wealth inequality may create upward pressure on prices. Data from 37 Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development member countries covering 2000–2022 were used in the analysis. According to the results of the analysis, increases in the wealth of high-wealth groups increase the inflation rate more severely.</p>","PeriodicalId":47546,"journal":{"name":"Manchester School","volume":"93 2","pages":"149-169"},"PeriodicalIF":0.7,"publicationDate":"2024-09-28","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"143120342","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Job satisfaction and workplace representation in Europe 欧洲的工作满意度和工作场所代表性
IF 0.7 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-09-12 DOI: 10.1111/manc.12499
John T. Addison, Paulino Teixeira

The backdrop to this inquiry into the relationship between worker job satisfaction and workplace representation in European nations is twofold. The first is that the bulk of research has focused on union membership and job satisfaction in Anglophone nations with their very different industrial relations systems and bargaining arrangements. The second and more immediate context is the dramatic shift from negative to positive in the association between union membership and job satisfaction (inter al.) observed in the most recent literature. Using data on 28 European nations from the last two waves of the European Working Conditions Survey, however, we report that workers in establishments with formal workplace representation record lower job satisfaction than their counterparts in plants without such representation. These findings of conditional correlation are then upgraded by constructing a pseudo-panel with cohort fixed effects to take account of unobserved worker heterogeneity. First-difference estimates suggest that the negative relationship between worker representation and job satisfaction found in cross section continues to hold. Next, an endogenous treatment effects model is deployed to address the possible endogeneity of worker representation. The results are supportive of a causal negative relationship between job satisfaction and worker representation. One interpretation of our findings is that in the matter of the association between unions and job satisfaction the jury is still out.

对欧洲国家工人工作满意度与工作场所代表性之间关系的研究有两个背景。首先,大部分研究都集中于英语国家的工会会员资格和工作满意度,这些国家的劳资关系体系和谈判安排大相径庭。第二点也是更直接的背景是,在最新的文献中,工会会员资格与工作满意度之间的关系由负向正发生了巨大转变(inter al.)然而,我们利用最近两波欧洲工作条件调查(European Working Conditions Survey)中有关 28 个欧洲国家的数据,报告了在有正式工作场所代表的企业中,工人的工作满意度低于在没有正式工作场所代表的工厂中的工人。随后,我们通过构建一个具有同组固定效应的伪面板来考虑未观察到的工人异质性,从而提升了这些条件相关性的结论。一阶差分估计结果表明,横截面研究中发现的工人代表与工作满意度之间的负相关关系依然存在。接下来,我们采用内生处理效应模型来解决工人代表权可能存在的内生性问题。结果支持工作满意度与工人代表之间存在因果负相关关系。对我们研究结果的一种解释是,工会与工作满意度之间的关系还没有定论。
{"title":"Job satisfaction and workplace representation in Europe","authors":"John T. Addison,&nbsp;Paulino Teixeira","doi":"10.1111/manc.12499","DOIUrl":"10.1111/manc.12499","url":null,"abstract":"<p>The backdrop to this inquiry into the relationship between worker job satisfaction and workplace representation in European nations is twofold. The first is that the bulk of research has focused on union membership and job satisfaction in Anglophone nations with their very different industrial relations systems and bargaining arrangements. The second and more immediate context is the dramatic shift from negative to positive in the association between union membership and job satisfaction (inter al.) observed in the most recent literature. Using data on 28 European nations from the last two waves of the European Working Conditions Survey, however, we report that workers in establishments with <i>formal workplace representation</i> record lower job satisfaction than their counterparts in plants without such representation. These findings of conditional correlation are then upgraded by constructing a pseudo-panel with cohort fixed effects to take account of unobserved worker heterogeneity. First-difference estimates suggest that the negative relationship between worker representation and job satisfaction found in cross section continues to hold. Next, an endogenous treatment effects model is deployed to address the possible endogeneity of worker representation. The results are supportive of a causal negative relationship between job satisfaction and worker representation. One interpretation of our findings is that in the matter of the association between unions and job satisfaction the jury is still out.</p>","PeriodicalId":47546,"journal":{"name":"Manchester School","volume":"93 2","pages":"123-148"},"PeriodicalIF":0.7,"publicationDate":"2024-09-12","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"142198901","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Equilibrium vertical structure with a common supplier 有共同供应商的均衡垂直结构
IF 0.7 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-09-02 DOI: 10.1111/manc.12498
Kangsik Choi, Sangheon Han, DongJoon Lee

We consider a vertically related market, in which each downstream firm produces a differentiated product by assembling a key input produced by a common supplier and another input produced by a dedicated upstream firm. On the one hand, vertical integration has the advantage of inducing the common supplier to set a lower input price, but the disadvantage of reducing downstream firms' competitiveness in the downstream market. On the other hand, vertical separation has the advantage of increasing downstream firms' competitiveness in the downstream market but the disadvantage of inducing the common supplier to set a higher input price. Contrary to results of previous studies, we find that the existence of a common supplier can lead to vertical integration under Cournot competition, which emerges as a unique equilibrium when a common supplier adopts input discrimination. Although vertical integration is better for the individual firms, it reduces the total welfare. Even when the common supplier uses uniform input pricing, vertical integration also emerges in equilibrium.

我们考虑了一个纵向关联市场,在这个市场中,每家下游企业都通过组装由共同供应商生产的一种关键投入品和由专门的上游企业生产的另一种投入品来生产差异化产品。一方面,纵向一体化的优点是促使共同供应商制定较低的投入品价格,但缺点是削弱了下游企业在下游市场的竞争力。另一方面,纵向分离的优点是提高下游企业在下游市场的竞争力,缺点是诱使共同供应商制定更高的投入价格。与以往的研究结果相反,我们发现共同供应商的存在会导致库诺竞争下的纵向一体化,而当共同供应商采取投入歧视时,纵向一体化会成为一种独特的均衡。虽然纵向一体化对单个企业更有利,但却降低了总福利。即使共同供应商采用统一的投入定价,纵向一体化也会出现均衡。
{"title":"Equilibrium vertical structure with a common supplier","authors":"Kangsik Choi,&nbsp;Sangheon Han,&nbsp;DongJoon Lee","doi":"10.1111/manc.12498","DOIUrl":"10.1111/manc.12498","url":null,"abstract":"<p>We consider a vertically related market, in which each downstream firm produces a differentiated product by assembling a key input produced by a common supplier and another input produced by a dedicated upstream firm. On the one hand, vertical integration has the advantage of inducing the common supplier to set a lower input price, but the disadvantage of reducing downstream firms' competitiveness in the downstream market. On the other hand, vertical separation has the advantage of increasing downstream firms' competitiveness in the downstream market but the disadvantage of inducing the common supplier to set a higher input price. Contrary to results of previous studies, we find that the existence of a common supplier can lead to vertical integration under Cournot competition, which emerges as a unique equilibrium when a common supplier adopts input discrimination. Although vertical integration is better for the individual firms, it reduces the total welfare. Even when the common supplier uses uniform input pricing, vertical integration also emerges in equilibrium.</p>","PeriodicalId":47546,"journal":{"name":"Manchester School","volume":"93 2","pages":"103-122"},"PeriodicalIF":0.7,"publicationDate":"2024-09-02","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"142225451","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Did 2004 EU expansion matter to new migrants' housing tenure and settlement choices in England? 2004 年欧盟扩张对新移民在英格兰的住房保有权和定居选择有影响吗?
IF 0.7 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-07-20 DOI: 10.1111/manc.12496
Sarah Jewell, Anupam Nanda, Olayiwola Oladiran

This paper analyses how migration policy changes affect the housing and location patterns of immigrants in the UK. Using the UK Longitudinal Household Survey, we examine the relationship between the 2004 EU accession as a migration policy change and housing and locational patterns. In addition to confirming the importance of migration policy frameworks, we find that liberalised migration can create a wave of immigrants with a lower propensity for homeownership and may cause the dispersion of new immigrants to locations away from the gateway cities and primary immigrant clusters such as London. The results are robust to several sensitivity tests.

本文分析了移民政策变化如何影响英国移民的住房和地点模式。通过英国纵向住户调查,我们研究了 2004 年加入欧盟这一移民政策变化与住房和地点模式之间的关系。除了证实移民政策框架的重要性外,我们还发现,自由化的移民政策可能会带来一波拥有住房倾向较低的移民潮,并可能导致新移民分散到远离门户城市和伦敦等主要移民集群的地区。这些结果在多个敏感性测试中都是稳健的。
{"title":"Did 2004 EU expansion matter to new migrants' housing tenure and settlement choices in England?","authors":"Sarah Jewell,&nbsp;Anupam Nanda,&nbsp;Olayiwola Oladiran","doi":"10.1111/manc.12496","DOIUrl":"10.1111/manc.12496","url":null,"abstract":"<p>This paper analyses how migration policy changes affect the housing and location patterns of immigrants in the UK. Using the UK Longitudinal Household Survey, we examine the relationship between the 2004 EU accession as a migration policy change and housing and locational patterns. In addition to confirming the importance of migration policy frameworks, we find that liberalised migration can create a wave of immigrants with a lower propensity for homeownership and may cause the dispersion of new immigrants to locations away from the gateway cities and primary immigrant clusters such as London. The results are robust to several sensitivity tests.</p>","PeriodicalId":47546,"journal":{"name":"Manchester School","volume":"93 1","pages":"83-102"},"PeriodicalIF":0.7,"publicationDate":"2024-07-20","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/manc.12496","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"141741080","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"OA","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Online shopping and rural-urban wage inequality 网上购物与城乡工资不平等
IF 0.7 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-07-19 DOI: 10.1111/manc.12497
Jiancai Pi, Xinyi Liu

This paper takes online shopping into consideration, and constructs general equilibrium models to analyze how consumers' dependence on online shopping affects rural-urban skilled-unskilled wage inequality. We find that when consumers' dependence on online shopping increases, wage inequality can be conditionally narrowed down, depending on the unskilled labor intensity in the urban manufacturing sector and the possible elasticity of the contract price.

本文将网购纳入考虑范围,构建一般均衡模型,分析消费者对网购的依赖如何影响城乡技术-非技术工资不平等。我们发现,当消费者对网购的依赖性增加时,工资不平等会有条件地缩小,这取决于城市制造业的非技术劳动密集程度和合同价格的可能弹性。
{"title":"Online shopping and rural-urban wage inequality","authors":"Jiancai Pi,&nbsp;Xinyi Liu","doi":"10.1111/manc.12497","DOIUrl":"10.1111/manc.12497","url":null,"abstract":"<p>This paper takes online shopping into consideration, and constructs general equilibrium models to analyze how consumers' dependence on online shopping affects rural-urban skilled-unskilled wage inequality. We find that when consumers' dependence on online shopping increases, wage inequality can be conditionally narrowed down, depending on the unskilled labor intensity in the urban manufacturing sector and the possible elasticity of the contract price.</p>","PeriodicalId":47546,"journal":{"name":"Manchester School","volume":"93 1","pages":"70-82"},"PeriodicalIF":0.7,"publicationDate":"2024-07-19","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"141741081","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Consumption response to aggregate shocks and the role of leverage 消费对总体冲击的反应及杠杆作用
IF 0.7 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-07-12 DOI: 10.1111/manc.12495
Agnes Kovacs, May Rostom, Philip Bunn

This paper investigates the relationship between mortgage leverage and consumption around the 2008 financial crisis. Using data from the UK's Family Expenditure Survey and Wealth and Asset Survey, we first show that high-leveraged households made larger cuts to consumption following the financial crisis, and this was largely driven by young households. Second, using a life-cycle framework, we qualitatively evaluate four possible channels that could explain the observed positive relationship between consumption and leverage: income, uncertainty, credit supply and house price channels. Our key finding is that credit supply tightening is the main driver of the empirical co-movement between pre-crisis leverage and consumption growth after 2008.

本文研究了 2008 年金融危机前后抵押贷款杠杆与消费之间的关系。利用英国家庭支出调查和财富与资产调查的数据,我们首先表明高杠杆家庭在金融危机后更大幅度地削减了消费,而这主要是由年轻家庭驱动的。其次,我们利用生命周期框架,定性评估了四种可能的渠道,这些渠道可以解释观察到的消费与杠杆之间的正相关关系:收入渠道、不确定性渠道、信贷供应渠道和房价渠道。我们的主要发现是,信贷供应紧缩是 2008 年后危机前杠杆率与消费增长之间经验性共同变动的主要驱动因素。
{"title":"Consumption response to aggregate shocks and the role of leverage","authors":"Agnes Kovacs,&nbsp;May Rostom,&nbsp;Philip Bunn","doi":"10.1111/manc.12495","DOIUrl":"10.1111/manc.12495","url":null,"abstract":"<p>This paper investigates the relationship between mortgage leverage and consumption around the 2008 financial crisis. Using data from the UK's Family Expenditure Survey and Wealth and Asset Survey, we first show that high-leveraged households made larger cuts to consumption following the financial crisis, and this was largely driven by young households. Second, using a life-cycle framework, we qualitatively evaluate four possible channels that could explain the observed positive relationship between consumption and leverage: income, uncertainty, credit supply and house price channels. Our key finding is that credit supply tightening is the main driver of the empirical co-movement between pre-crisis leverage and consumption growth after 2008.</p>","PeriodicalId":47546,"journal":{"name":"Manchester School","volume":"93 1","pages":"30-69"},"PeriodicalIF":0.7,"publicationDate":"2024-07-12","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/manc.12495","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"141609791","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"OA","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
The impacts of exchange rate on US adjusted bilateral trade balance with Germany under Brexit: A comparative analysis 英国脱欧下汇率对美国与德国调整后双边贸易平衡的影响:比较分析
IF 0.7 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-06-12 DOI: 10.1111/manc.12494
Serdar Ongan, Ismet Gocer, Huseyin Karamelikli

This study reveals the hidden dynamics of USA-Germany international trade through a revised J-curve hypothesis. It emphasizes the inadequacy of the traditional Bilateral Trade Balance (BTB) ratio based on total exports. To this aim, it introduces two new testing approaches based on adjusted BTB: the GDP-driven-BTB-based J-curve hypothesis (GDPJ) and the Non-GDP-driven-BTB-based J-curve hypothesis (NGDPJ). The empirical findings advocate the necessity of these alternative tests, offering policymakers more informative results than the traditional approach. GDPJ is validated for 13 goods, while NGDPJ and traditional methods are validated for 10 and 8 goods. These results underscore the risks of solely relying on the traditional approach. By embracing the revised J-curve hypothesis and alternative BTBs, policymakers can gain deeper insights into the USA-Germany trade relationship. One interpretation is that, under Brexit, German consumers reduce their purchases of re-exported goods more than domestically produced goods from the US.

本研究通过修正的 J 曲线假说揭示了美国-德国国际贸易的隐性动态。它强调了基于出口总额的传统双边贸易平衡(BTB)比率的不足之处。为此,它引入了两种基于调整后双边贸易差额的新测试方法:基于 GDP 驱动的双边贸易差额 J 曲线假说(GDPJ)和基于非 GDP 驱动的双边贸易差额 J 曲线假说(NGDPJ)。实证研究结果证明了这些替代测试的必要性,与传统方法相比,它们能为政策制定者提供更有参考价值的结果。GDPJ 在 13 种商品上得到验证,而 NGDPJ 和传统方法分别在 10 种和 8 种商品上得到验证。这些结果凸显了单纯依赖传统方法的风险。通过采用修订后的 J 曲线假说和替代性 BTB,政策制定者可以更深入地了解美德贸易关系。一种解释是,在英国脱欧的情况下,德国消费者减少购买的转口贸易商品多于从美国本土生产的商品。
{"title":"The impacts of exchange rate on US adjusted bilateral trade balance with Germany under Brexit: A comparative analysis","authors":"Serdar Ongan,&nbsp;Ismet Gocer,&nbsp;Huseyin Karamelikli","doi":"10.1111/manc.12494","DOIUrl":"10.1111/manc.12494","url":null,"abstract":"<p>This study reveals the hidden dynamics of USA-Germany international trade through a revised J-curve hypothesis. It emphasizes the inadequacy of the traditional Bilateral Trade Balance (BTB) ratio based on total exports. To this aim, it introduces two new testing approaches based on adjusted BTB: the GDP-driven-BTB-based J-curve hypothesis (GDPJ) and the Non-GDP-driven-BTB-based J-curve hypothesis (NGDPJ). The empirical findings advocate the necessity of these alternative tests, offering policymakers more informative results than the traditional approach. GDPJ is validated for 13 goods, while NGDPJ and traditional methods are validated for 10 and 8 goods. These results underscore the risks of solely relying on the traditional approach. By embracing the revised J-curve hypothesis and alternative BTBs, policymakers can gain deeper insights into the USA-Germany trade relationship. One interpretation is that, under Brexit, German consumers reduce their purchases of re-exported goods more than domestically produced goods from the US.</p>","PeriodicalId":47546,"journal":{"name":"Manchester School","volume":"93 1","pages":"1-29"},"PeriodicalIF":0.7,"publicationDate":"2024-06-12","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"141352135","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
期刊
Manchester School
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1