首页 > 最新文献

Manchester School最新文献

英文 中文
Robots at work: New evidence with recent data 工作中的机器人最新数据提供的新证据
IF 0.7 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-06-06 DOI: 10.1111/manc.12493
Derick Almeida, Tiago Neves Sequeira

We reassess the relationship between robotization and the growth in labor productivity with more recent data. We discover that the effect of robot density in the growth productivity substantially decreased in the post-2008 period. In this period, the lower positive effect of robot density in the growth of labor productivity is less dependent on the increase in value added. The data analysis dismisses any positive effect of robotization on hours worked. Results are confirmed by several robustness checks, cross-sectional (and panel-data) Instrumental Variable and quantile regression analysis. By means of the quantile regression analysis, we learn that the effect of robots on labor productivity is stronger for low productivity sectors and that in the most recent period, the effect of robotization felt significantly throughout the distribution. This highlights one of the possible sources of stagnation in the era of robotization and have implication both for labor market and R&D policies.

我们利用最新数据重新评估了机器人化与劳动生产率增长之间的关系。我们发现,机器人密度对生产率增长的影响在 2008 年后大幅下降。在这一时期,机器人密度对劳动生产率增长的正效应降低,对附加值增长的依赖性降低。数据分析否定了机器人化对工作时间的积极影响。一些稳健性检验、横截面(和面板数据)工具变量和量位回归分析证实了这一结果。通过量子回归分析,我们了解到机器人对低生产率部门劳动生产率的影响更大,而且在最近一段时期,机器人化的影响在整个分布中都很明显。这凸显了机器人时代停滞不前的可能原因之一,对劳动力市场和研发政策都有影响。
{"title":"Robots at work: New evidence with recent data","authors":"Derick Almeida,&nbsp;Tiago Neves Sequeira","doi":"10.1111/manc.12493","DOIUrl":"10.1111/manc.12493","url":null,"abstract":"<p>We reassess the relationship between robotization and the growth in labor productivity with more recent data. We discover that the effect of robot density in the growth productivity substantially decreased in the post-2008 period. In this period, the lower positive effect of robot density in the growth of labor productivity is less dependent on the increase in value added. The data analysis dismisses any positive effect of robotization on hours worked. Results are confirmed by several robustness checks, cross-sectional (and panel-data) Instrumental Variable and quantile regression analysis. By means of the quantile regression analysis, we learn that the effect of robots on labor productivity is stronger for low productivity sectors and that in the most recent period, the effect of robotization felt significantly throughout the distribution. This highlights one of the possible sources of stagnation in the era of robotization and have implication both for labor market and R&amp;D policies.</p>","PeriodicalId":47546,"journal":{"name":"Manchester School","volume":"92 6","pages":"700-722"},"PeriodicalIF":0.7,"publicationDate":"2024-06-06","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"141378170","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Strategic advertising in the aftermath of a corporate scandal 企业丑闻后的战略广告
IF 0.7 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-05-30 DOI: 10.1111/manc.12492
Ascensión Andina-Díaz, Javier Campos, Juan-Luis Jiménez, Jordi Perdiguero

This paper contributes to the literature on how firms change their advertising strategies after a corporate scandal by providing both a theoretical model and an empirical evaluation based on the idea that advertising acts as a signal of the product quality that is modulated by the number of competing substitutes in the market. This result is new to the literature and helps to explain cases in which, possibly counter-intuitively, a firm affected by a corporate scandal may optimally decide to reduce its advertising expenditures, rather than increase it, in an attempt to restore its reputation as quickly as possible. We find empirical support for this result in the Volkswagen Group's response to the Dieselgate scandal.

本文提供了一个理论模型和一个经验评估,认为广告是产品质量的信号,受市场上竞争替代品数量的调节,从而为有关企业丑闻后如何改变广告策略的文献做出了贡献。这一结果是文献中的新发现,有助于解释以下情况:受企业丑闻影响的企业为了尽快恢复声誉,可能会做出减少广告支出而不是增加广告支出的最佳决定,这可能与直觉相反。我们在大众汽车集团对柴油门丑闻的回应中找到了这一结果的经验支持。
{"title":"Strategic advertising in the aftermath of a corporate scandal","authors":"Ascensión Andina-Díaz,&nbsp;Javier Campos,&nbsp;Juan-Luis Jiménez,&nbsp;Jordi Perdiguero","doi":"10.1111/manc.12492","DOIUrl":"10.1111/manc.12492","url":null,"abstract":"<p>This paper contributes to the literature on how firms change their advertising strategies after a corporate scandal by providing both a theoretical model and an empirical evaluation based on the idea that advertising acts as a signal of the product quality that is modulated by the number of competing substitutes in the market. This result is new to the literature and helps to explain cases in which, possibly counter-intuitively, a firm affected by a corporate scandal may optimally decide to reduce its advertising expenditures, rather than increase it, in an attempt to restore its reputation as quickly as possible. We find empirical support for this result in the <i>Volkswagen Group's</i> response to the <i>Dieselgate</i> scandal.</p>","PeriodicalId":47546,"journal":{"name":"Manchester School","volume":"92 6","pages":"663-699"},"PeriodicalIF":0.7,"publicationDate":"2024-05-30","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/manc.12492","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"141194301","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"OA","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Premature agglomeration?: Two phases of development with spatial sorting 过早聚集?空间分类的两个发展阶段
IF 0.7 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-05-23 DOI: 10.1111/manc.12484
Rikard Forslid, Toshihiro Okubo

Clusters in the developing world do, to a large extent, attract low-educated individuals, and these clusters are in some cases, characterized by urbanization without industrialization. This contrasts starkly to clusters in advanced economies that attract high-skilled individuals and entrepreneurs. In this paper, we develop a model of agglomeration and spatial sorting that is consistent with these two types of different agglomeration processes in developed and developing countries. We show that a poor country that has an agglomeration with low skilled individuals, may get stuck in this equilibrium, but that free mobility of human capital from the outset nevertheless is superior from the perspective of total social welfare.

发展中世界的产业集群在很大程度上吸引的是低学历者,在某些情况下,这些产业集群的特点是城市化而非工业化。这与发达经济体吸引高技能人才和企业家的产业集群形成了鲜明对比。在本文中,我们建立了一个与发达国家和发展中国家这两类不同集聚过程相一致的集聚和空间排序模型。我们的研究表明,一个穷国如果聚集了低技能人才,可能会陷入这种均衡状态,但从社会总福利的角度来看,人力资本从一开始就自由流动是更优越的。
{"title":"Premature agglomeration?: Two phases of development with spatial sorting","authors":"Rikard Forslid,&nbsp;Toshihiro Okubo","doi":"10.1111/manc.12484","DOIUrl":"10.1111/manc.12484","url":null,"abstract":"<p>Clusters in the developing world do, to a large extent, attract low-educated individuals, and these clusters are in some cases, characterized by urbanization without industrialization. This contrasts starkly to clusters in advanced economies that attract high-skilled individuals and entrepreneurs. In this paper, we develop a model of agglomeration and spatial sorting that is consistent with these two types of different agglomeration processes in developed and developing countries. We show that a poor country that has an agglomeration with low skilled individuals, may get stuck in this equilibrium, but that free mobility of human capital from the outset nevertheless is superior from the perspective of total social welfare.</p>","PeriodicalId":47546,"journal":{"name":"Manchester School","volume":"92 6","pages":"636-662"},"PeriodicalIF":0.7,"publicationDate":"2024-05-23","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/manc.12484","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"141107063","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"OA","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Introduction to the special issue “Productivity revolutions: Past and future” 特刊 "生产力革命:过去与未来
IF 0.7 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-05-23 DOI: 10.1111/manc.12482
Nuno Palma

We may be living at the dawn of a productivity revolution era brought about by modern science and technological improvements. The six research papers published in this special issue of The Manchester School, titled “Productivity Revolutions: Past and Future,” provide us with lessons on how economies and societies have dealt with the challenges posed by such revolutions.

我们可能正生活在现代科学和技术进步所带来的生产力革命时代的黎明。本期《曼彻斯特学派》特刊以 "生产力革命:过去与未来 "为题,刊登了六篇研究论文:过去与未来 "的特刊上发表的六篇研究论文为我们提供了经济和社会如何应对此类革命所带来的挑战的经验。
{"title":"Introduction to the special issue “Productivity revolutions: Past and future”","authors":"Nuno Palma","doi":"10.1111/manc.12482","DOIUrl":"10.1111/manc.12482","url":null,"abstract":"<p>We may be living at the dawn of a productivity revolution era brought about by modern science and technological improvements. The six research papers published in this special issue of The Manchester School, titled “Productivity Revolutions: Past and Future,” provide us with lessons on how economies and societies have dealt with the challenges posed by such revolutions.</p>","PeriodicalId":47546,"journal":{"name":"Manchester School","volume":"92 6","pages":"613-614"},"PeriodicalIF":0.7,"publicationDate":"2024-05-23","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/manc.12482","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"141105175","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"OA","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Rules, organizations, and the institutional origins of the great productivity revolution 规则、组织和伟大生产力革命的制度起源
IF 0.7 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-05-23 DOI: 10.1111/manc.12483
John Joseph Wallis

Human productivity began increasing in the mid-19th century in a group of societies whose institutional structures simultaneously transformed. This paper develops a general way of thinking about institutional structures and identifies how specific institutional changes that occurred in the mid-19th century could have caused an increase in productivity across many of the organizations in a society. External rules enforced by one organization but used by other organizations, are central to the argument, as is the emergence of impersonal rules that apply equally to all citizens. The productivity revolution of the late 19th century occurred in an era when a few societies adopted impersonal rules on a broad scale for the first time in human history.

19 世纪中叶,人类生产力开始在一些社会中提高,这些社会的制度结构也同时发生了变化。本文提出了一种关于制度结构的一般思维方式,并指出了 19 世纪中叶发生的具体制度变革是如何导致社会中许多组织的生产力提高的。由一个组织执行但被其他组织使用的外部规则,以及平等适用于所有公民的非个人规则的出现,是这一论点的核心。19 世纪末的生产力革命发生在少数几个社会在人类历史上首次广泛采用非个人规则的时代。
{"title":"Rules, organizations, and the institutional origins of the great productivity revolution","authors":"John Joseph Wallis","doi":"10.1111/manc.12483","DOIUrl":"10.1111/manc.12483","url":null,"abstract":"<p>Human productivity began increasing in the mid-19th century in a group of societies whose institutional structures simultaneously transformed. This paper develops a general way of thinking about institutional structures and identifies how specific institutional changes that occurred in the mid-19th century could have caused an increase in productivity across many of the organizations in a society. External rules enforced by one organization but used by other organizations, are central to the argument, as is the emergence of impersonal rules that apply equally to all citizens. The productivity revolution of the late 19th century occurred in an era when a few societies adopted impersonal rules on a broad scale for the first time in human history.</p>","PeriodicalId":47546,"journal":{"name":"Manchester School","volume":"92 6","pages":"615-635"},"PeriodicalIF":0.7,"publicationDate":"2024-05-23","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/manc.12483","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"141106166","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"OA","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Complementary inputs, outsourcing and vertical integration: Price versus quantity competition 互补投入、外包和纵向一体化:价格竞争与数量竞争
IF 0.7 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-05-18 DOI: 10.1111/manc.12480
Arijit Mukherjee, Burcu Senalp

We compare the effects of price and quantity competition in an industry with complementary inputs, outsourcing and a vertically integrated firm where vertical integration occurs between a final goods producer and a subset of input suppliers. The profit of the integrated firm and the industry profit are higher under Bertrand competition, the profit of the non-integrated firm is higher under Bertrand competition for high product differentiation, and consumer surplus and welfare are higher under Bertrand competition for low product differentiation. Further, no market foreclosure can be the preferred choice of the vertically integrated firm for any degree of product differentiation.

我们比较了具有互补性投入的行业中价格和数量竞争、外包和纵向一体化企业的影响,其中纵向一体化发生在最终产品生产商和投入品供应商之间。在伯特兰竞争下,一体化企业的利润和行业利润更高;在伯特兰竞争下,产品差异化程度高的非一体化企业的利润更高;在伯特兰竞争下,产品差异化程度低的企业的消费者剩余和福利更高。此外,对于任何程度的产品差异化,纵向一体化企业都不会优先选择取消市场赎回权。
{"title":"Complementary inputs, outsourcing and vertical integration: Price versus quantity competition","authors":"Arijit Mukherjee,&nbsp;Burcu Senalp","doi":"10.1111/manc.12480","DOIUrl":"10.1111/manc.12480","url":null,"abstract":"<p>We compare the effects of price and quantity competition in an industry with complementary inputs, outsourcing and a vertically integrated firm where vertical integration occurs between a final goods producer and a subset of input suppliers. The profit of the integrated firm and the industry profit are higher under Bertrand competition, the profit of the non-integrated firm is higher under Bertrand competition for high product differentiation, and consumer surplus and welfare are higher under Bertrand competition for low product differentiation. Further, no market foreclosure can be the preferred choice of the vertically integrated firm for any degree of product differentiation.</p>","PeriodicalId":47546,"journal":{"name":"Manchester School","volume":"92 5","pages":"578-611"},"PeriodicalIF":0.7,"publicationDate":"2024-05-18","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/manc.12480","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"141064140","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"OA","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Childcare, work from home and the evolution of mental health in times of COVID-19: Evidence from the Netherlands 儿童保育、在家工作和 COVID-19 时代心理健康的演变:来自荷兰的证据
IF 0.7 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-05-17 DOI: 10.1111/manc.12485
Bettina Siflinger, Michaela Paffenholz, Sebastian Seitz, Moritz Mendel, Hans-Martin von Gaudecker

We study the co-evolution of mental health with the most prominent risk factors associated with the COVID-19 pandemic for the Dutch working population. We exploit data from the Longitudinal Internet Studies for the Social Sciences panel from before the pandemic and five questionnaires in its first year. We find mental health decreased sharply with the onset of the first lockdown but recovered quickly, reaching levels comparable to those a year earlier. Labor market uncertainty, perceived infection risk, and loneliness are all associated with worsening mental health. Moreover, parents of children younger than 12 experience a significant drop in mental health.

我们研究了荷兰劳动人口的心理健康与 COVID-19 大流行相关的最主要风险因素的共同演变。我们利用了社会科学纵向互联网研究小组在大流行之前的数据和大流行第一年的五次问卷调查数据。我们发现,随着第一次封锁的开始,心理健康水平急剧下降,但很快就恢复了,达到了与一年前相当的水平。劳动力市场的不确定性、感知到的感染风险和孤独感都与心理健康状况的恶化有关。此外,12 岁以下儿童的父母的心理健康状况也显著下降。
{"title":"Childcare, work from home and the evolution of mental health in times of COVID-19: Evidence from the Netherlands","authors":"Bettina Siflinger,&nbsp;Michaela Paffenholz,&nbsp;Sebastian Seitz,&nbsp;Moritz Mendel,&nbsp;Hans-Martin von Gaudecker","doi":"10.1111/manc.12485","DOIUrl":"10.1111/manc.12485","url":null,"abstract":"<p>We study the co-evolution of mental health with the most prominent risk factors associated with the COVID-19 pandemic for the Dutch working population. We exploit data from the Longitudinal Internet Studies for the Social Sciences panel from before the pandemic and five questionnaires in its first year. We find mental health decreased sharply with the onset of the first lockdown but recovered quickly, reaching levels comparable to those a year earlier. Labor market uncertainty, perceived infection risk, and loneliness are all associated with worsening mental health. Moreover, parents of children younger than 12 experience a significant drop in mental health.</p>","PeriodicalId":47546,"journal":{"name":"Manchester School","volume":"92 5","pages":"443-465"},"PeriodicalIF":0.7,"publicationDate":"2024-05-17","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/manc.12485","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"140966257","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"OA","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Structural change and productivity revolutions: Some hints from the Italian case, 1979–2016 结构变化和生产力革命:意大利案例的一些提示(1979-2016 年
IF 0.7 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-05-09 DOI: 10.1111/manc.12479
Carlo Brambilla, Fabio Lavista

The reallocation of resources between sectors is classically regarded as the engine of long-term growth. The different technological opportunities and the inherent levels of productivity that characterise each sector explain why changes in sectoral composition trigger development processes. Conversely, in the short run, productivity growth is associated with differentiation processes among firms operating in the same industry. The recent debate on the decline in Italian productivity has mainly focussed on short-term interpretations. Using a new dataset on the largest Italian companies between the 1970s and the 2010s period, the paper examines the role of structural change in determining productivity changes.

各部门之间的资源重新配置历来被视为长期增长的动力。不同的技术机遇和每个部门固有的生产力水平,解释了为什么部门构成的变化会引发发展进程。相反,在短期内,生产率的增长与同一行业内企业的分化过程有关。最近关于意大利生产率下降的争论主要集中在短期解释上。本文利用 20 世纪 70 年代至 2010 年代期间意大利最大公司的新数据集,研究了结构变化在决定生产率变化中的作用。
{"title":"Structural change and productivity revolutions: Some hints from the Italian case, 1979–2016","authors":"Carlo Brambilla,&nbsp;Fabio Lavista","doi":"10.1111/manc.12479","DOIUrl":"10.1111/manc.12479","url":null,"abstract":"<p>The reallocation of resources between sectors is classically regarded as the engine of long-term growth. The different technological opportunities and the inherent levels of productivity that characterise each sector explain why changes in sectoral composition trigger development processes. Conversely, in the short run, productivity growth is associated with differentiation processes among firms operating in the same industry. The recent debate on the decline in Italian productivity has mainly focussed on short-term interpretations. Using a new dataset on the largest Italian companies between the 1970s and the 2010s period, the paper examines the role of structural change in determining productivity changes.</p>","PeriodicalId":47546,"journal":{"name":"Manchester School","volume":"92 5","pages":"556-577"},"PeriodicalIF":0.7,"publicationDate":"2024-05-09","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"140997304","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Less work and higher tax can raise wellbeing 减少工作和增加税收可以提高福利
IF 0.7 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-05-08 DOI: 10.1111/manc.12481
Felix FitzRoy, Jim Jin

Worktime has been falling slowly though real wages have risen dramatically. We show that in a general equilibrium model with CES utility and production functions, worktime falls with real wages if and only if the elasticity of substitution between consumption and leisure is less than that between capital and labour, but always rises with labour's income share and concerns with relative income. While a falling labour share may not reduce worktime due to market inflexibility, stronger income comparison increases inefficient overwork. Hence, more flexibility, higher income taxes and a basic income are needed to reduce working hours and raise social welfare.

虽然实际工资大幅上涨,但工作时间却在缓慢减少。我们的研究表明,在一个具有 CES 效用函数和生产函数的一般均衡模型中,只有当且仅当消费与闲暇之间的替代弹性小于资本与劳动之间的替代弹性时,工作时间才会随着实际工资的下降而下降,但工作时间总是随着劳动力收入份额的增加而增加,并与相对收入有关。虽然由于市场缺乏灵活性,劳动份额的下降可能不会减少工作时间,但更强的收入比较会增加无效率的过度工作。因此,需要更多的灵活性、更高的所得税和基本收入来减少工作时间和提高社会福利。
{"title":"Less work and higher tax can raise wellbeing","authors":"Felix FitzRoy,&nbsp;Jim Jin","doi":"10.1111/manc.12481","DOIUrl":"10.1111/manc.12481","url":null,"abstract":"<p>Worktime has been falling slowly though real wages have risen dramatically. We show that in a general equilibrium model with CES utility and production functions, worktime falls with real wages if and only if the elasticity of substitution between consumption and leisure is less than that between capital and labour, but always rises with labour's income share and concerns with relative income. While a falling labour share may not reduce worktime due to market inflexibility, stronger income comparison increases inefficient overwork. Hence, more flexibility, higher income taxes and a basic income are needed to reduce working hours and raise social welfare.</p>","PeriodicalId":47546,"journal":{"name":"Manchester School","volume":"92 5","pages":"539-555"},"PeriodicalIF":0.7,"publicationDate":"2024-05-08","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/manc.12481","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"140938655","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"OA","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Population dynamics, intergenerational mobility, and the process of economic development 人口动态、代际流动和经济发展进程
IF 0.7 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-04-25 DOI: 10.1111/manc.12478
Hiroki Aso

This study analyzes the interactions between population dynamics with differential fertility the intergenerational mobility and economic development. Population dynamics with differential fertility exerts the following two effects on the economy: (i) the change in the population size of the entire economy influences the mobility through changing in the composition of workers and (ii) the decreasing/increasing transfer per child influences the mobility. A sufficient increase in the population growth increases the population size and leads to a significant decline in the transfers per child; this phenomenon contributes toward the cyclical behavior of mobility and income inequality. On the other hand, when a population growth decreases, the mobility monotonically approaches toward steady state. These results are consistent with some empirical evidence. Hence, this study demonstrates that the population dynamics with differential fertility leads to a difference in transitional dynamics of intergenerational mobility and the process of economic development.

本研究分析了不同生育率的人口动态与代际流动性和经济发展之间的相互作用。不同生育率的人口动态对经济产生以下两种影响:(i) 整个经济中人口规模的变化通过工人构成的变化影响流动性;(ii) 每名儿童转移支付的减少/增加影响流动性。人口增长的充分增长会增加人口规模,并导致每个儿童的转移支付显著下降;这一现象导致了流动性和收入不平等的周期性行为。另一方面,当人口增长下降时,流动性会单调地趋于稳定状态。这些结果与一些经验证据相吻合。因此,本研究表明,不同生育率的人口动态会导致代际流动的过渡动态和经济发展进程的差异。
{"title":"Population dynamics, intergenerational mobility, and the process of economic development","authors":"Hiroki Aso","doi":"10.1111/manc.12478","DOIUrl":"10.1111/manc.12478","url":null,"abstract":"<p>This study analyzes the interactions between population dynamics with differential fertility the intergenerational mobility and economic development. Population dynamics with differential fertility exerts the following two effects on the economy: (i) the change in the population size of the entire economy influences the mobility through changing in the composition of workers and (ii) the decreasing/increasing transfer per child influences the mobility. A sufficient increase in the population growth increases the population size and leads to a significant decline in the transfers per child; this phenomenon contributes toward the cyclical behavior of mobility and income inequality. On the other hand, when a population growth decreases, the mobility monotonically approaches toward steady state. These results are consistent with some empirical evidence. Hence, this study demonstrates that the population dynamics with differential fertility leads to a difference in transitional dynamics of intergenerational mobility and the process of economic development.</p>","PeriodicalId":47546,"journal":{"name":"Manchester School","volume":"92 5","pages":"507-538"},"PeriodicalIF":0.7,"publicationDate":"2024-04-25","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"140655904","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
期刊
Manchester School
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1