首页 > 最新文献

Manchester School最新文献

英文 中文
Total factor productivity and state ownership: Evidence from China's 2008 stimulus package 全要素生产率与国有制:来自中国 2008 年经济刺激计划的证据
IF 1.1 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-01-03 DOI: 10.1111/manc.12466
Shi-zhuan Han, Taotao Duan, Han Gao, Tianhang Zhou, Jie Li

We examine the impact of China's economic stimulus plan in 2008 on the total factor productivity (TFP) of China's listed firms. We hypothesize that firms operating in regions characterized by greater resource misallocation would experience a more pronounced decline in TFP following the implementation of the stimulus plan. To gauge the extent of resource misallocation, we employ the proportion of state-owned enterprises (SOEs) as a measure. Our findings reveal a substantial decrease in TFP for firms located in provinces with higher SOE shares compared to those in provinces with lower SOE shares, amounting to approximately 9.2%. These results highlight the unintended policy consequence of the stimulus plan for firm-level productivity in China.

我们研究了 2008 年中国经济刺激计划对中国上市公司全要素生产率(TFP)的影响。我们假设,在经济刺激计划实施后,资源错配程度较高地区的企业全要素生产率会出现更明显的下降。为了衡量资源错配的程度,我们采用国有企业的比例作为衡量标准。我们的研究结果显示,与国有企业比例较低的省份相比,国有企业比例较高省份的企业全要素生产率大幅下降,降幅约为 9.2%。这些结果凸显了经济刺激计划对中国企业生产率的意外政策后果。
{"title":"Total factor productivity and state ownership: Evidence from China's 2008 stimulus package","authors":"Shi-zhuan Han,&nbsp;Taotao Duan,&nbsp;Han Gao,&nbsp;Tianhang Zhou,&nbsp;Jie Li","doi":"10.1111/manc.12466","DOIUrl":"10.1111/manc.12466","url":null,"abstract":"<p>We examine the impact of China's economic stimulus plan in 2008 on the total factor productivity (TFP) of China's listed firms. We hypothesize that firms operating in regions characterized by greater resource misallocation would experience a more pronounced decline in TFP following the implementation of the stimulus plan. To gauge the extent of resource misallocation, we employ the proportion of state-owned enterprises (SOEs) as a measure. Our findings reveal a substantial decrease in TFP for firms located in provinces with higher SOE shares compared to those in provinces with lower SOE shares, amounting to approximately 9.2%. These results highlight the unintended policy consequence of the stimulus plan for firm-level productivity in China.</p>","PeriodicalId":47546,"journal":{"name":"Manchester School","volume":"92 3","pages":"246-280"},"PeriodicalIF":1.1,"publicationDate":"2024-01-03","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"139388544","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Euro area inflation in the era of COVID-19: A permanent or a transitory phenomenon? COVID-19 时代的欧元区通货膨胀:是永久现象还是暂时现象?
IF 1.1 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-01-03 DOI: 10.1111/manc.12470
Nicholas Apergis

The goal of this paper is to test the mean reversion process of the inflation rate in the Eurozone during the COVID-19 pandemic crisis. The study uses weekly data on consumer prices (measured through the Harmonized Consumer Price Index), spanning the period from 2020 to the mid of 2022. The findings document that euro area inflation follows a mean non-reverting process, with most of its components following a similar pattern. Moreover, sub-period analysis illustrates that the vaccination process against the pandemic gives a transitory character to euro area inflation, which, however, is dominated by the lockdown and the Omicron mutation periods. Finally, comparative analysis illustrated the differences of inflation persistence during the Global Financial Crisis of 2007–2009.

本文旨在检验 COVID-19 大流行危机期间欧元区通货膨胀率的均值回归过程。研究使用了 2020 年至 2022 年中期的每周消费价格数据(通过协调消费价格指数衡量)。研究结果表明,欧元区的通胀遵循一个均值非回归的过程,其大多数组成部分都遵循类似的模式。此外,分时期分析表明,针对大流行病的疫苗接种过程使欧元区通货膨胀具有过渡性特征,然而,锁定期和奥密克龙突变期占据主导地位。最后,比较分析表明了 2007-2009 年全球金融危机期间通货膨胀持续性的差异。
{"title":"Euro area inflation in the era of COVID-19: A permanent or a transitory phenomenon?","authors":"Nicholas Apergis","doi":"10.1111/manc.12470","DOIUrl":"10.1111/manc.12470","url":null,"abstract":"<p>The goal of this paper is to test the mean reversion process of the inflation rate in the Eurozone during the COVID-19 pandemic crisis. The study uses weekly data on consumer prices (measured through the Harmonized Consumer Price Index), spanning the period from 2020 to the mid of 2022. The findings document that euro area inflation follows a mean non-reverting process, with most of its components following a similar pattern. Moreover, sub-period analysis illustrates that the vaccination process against the pandemic gives a transitory character to euro area inflation, which, however, is dominated by the lockdown and the Omicron mutation periods. Finally, comparative analysis illustrated the differences of inflation persistence during the Global Financial Crisis of 2007–2009.</p>","PeriodicalId":47546,"journal":{"name":"Manchester School","volume":"92 3","pages":"231-245"},"PeriodicalIF":1.1,"publicationDate":"2024-01-03","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"139420553","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Will automation and robotics lead to more inequality? 自动化和机器人技术会导致更多的不平等吗?
IF 1.1 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2023-12-02 DOI: 10.1111/manc.12465
Elise S. Brezis, Amir Rubin

This paper presents a new framework for analyzing automation, robotics, and high-tech, which differs from the canonical model of technological progress by incorporating the higher education system. The main difference is that there is not just one type of skilled workers, but two types, and there is not one type of education but two - elite universities and standard ones. The gap between these two types of education is called ‘elitism gap’. The ‘elitism gap’ in the higher-education sector enables a separation of individuals by their abilities. Since the economy is divided between low-tech and high-tech sectors, the elitism gap leads to a separating equilibrium in which, high-ability workers graduating from top universities work in the high-tech sector, while low-ability workers, graduate from standard universities and work in the low-tech industries. In consequence, human capital in both industries is different, which leads to wage inequality. We then analyze the effects of an increased use of robotics on inequality. We show that robots affect the “matching effect” between abilities and education, and in consequence, inequality increases. We also show that wages and productivity gaps between high-tech and low-tech sectors are fueled by the elitism gap in higher education. This leads to heterogeneity in human capital, and therefore to an increase in wage inequality. We develop an index of the elitism gap, and show a positive correlation between the index of elitism gap and inequality in OECD countries.

本文提出了一个新的分析自动化、机器人和高科技的框架,它通过纳入高等教育系统而不同于规范的技术进步模型。主要区别在于,技术工人不是一种,而是两种;教育不是一种,而是两种——精英大学和普通大学。这两种教育之间的差距被称为“精英主义差距”。高等教育领域的“精英主义差距”使得个人的能力被分开。由于经济被划分为低技术部门和高技术部门,精英主义差距导致了一种分离均衡,即从顶尖大学毕业的高能力工人在高技术部门工作,而从普通大学毕业的低能力工人在低技术行业工作。因此,这两个行业的人力资本是不同的,这就导致了工资不平等。然后,我们分析了越来越多地使用机器人对不平等的影响。我们的研究表明,机器人影响了能力和教育之间的“匹配效应”,因此,不平等加剧了。我们还表明,高等教育中的精英主义差距加剧了高科技和低技术部门之间的工资和生产率差距。这导致了人力资本的异质性,从而加剧了工资不平等。我们开发了一个精英主义差距指数,并显示了经合组织国家精英主义差距指数与不平等之间的正相关关系。
{"title":"Will automation and robotics lead to more inequality?","authors":"Elise S. Brezis,&nbsp;Amir Rubin","doi":"10.1111/manc.12465","DOIUrl":"10.1111/manc.12465","url":null,"abstract":"<p>This paper presents a new framework for analyzing automation, robotics, and high-tech, which differs from the canonical model of technological progress by incorporating the higher education system. The main difference is that there is not just one type of skilled workers, but two types, and there is not one type of education but two - elite universities and standard ones. The gap between these two types of education is called ‘elitism gap’. The ‘elitism gap’ in the higher-education sector enables a separation of individuals by their abilities. Since the economy is divided between low-tech and high-tech sectors, the elitism gap leads to a separating equilibrium in which, high-ability workers graduating from top universities work in the high-tech sector, while low-ability workers, graduate from standard universities and work in the low-tech industries. In consequence, human capital in both industries is different, which leads to wage inequality. We then analyze the effects of an increased use of robotics on inequality. We show that robots affect the “matching effect” between abilities and education, and in consequence, inequality increases. We also show that wages and productivity gaps between high-tech and low-tech sectors are fueled by the elitism gap in higher education. This leads to heterogeneity in human capital, and therefore to an increase in wage inequality. We develop an index of the elitism gap, and show a positive correlation between the index of elitism gap and inequality in OECD countries.</p>","PeriodicalId":47546,"journal":{"name":"Manchester School","volume":"92 3","pages":"209-230"},"PeriodicalIF":1.1,"publicationDate":"2023-12-02","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/manc.12465","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"138494204","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"OA","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Are pro-productivity policies fit for purpose? 提高生产力的政策是否符合目的?
IF 1.1 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2023-11-30 DOI: 10.1111/manc.12464
Bart van Ark, Klaas de Vries, Dirk Pilat

In this paper we examine productivity trends, drivers of productivity growth and pro-productivity policies across the G-20 economies since 1970. While we find distinctly different productivity growth dynamics between G-20 economies and over time, one common observation is a widely shared slowdown in labour productivity growth since the 2010s underpinned by lower (or even negative) total factor productivity growth. Moreover, the growth in capital per worker hour has also begun to level off. We develop a typology of pro-productivity policies and argue that policies for investment and technological change need strengthening to support a revival of productivity growth. Such policies should include a balanced approach to stronger technological progress and more rapid diffusion; a strengthening of investment, especially in intangibles and public services; and greater attention for human capital. We also argue for stronger institutions and capabilities that allow for dynamic learning about pro-productivity policies across countries and over time.

在本文中,我们研究了1970年以来g20经济体的生产率趋势、生产率增长的驱动因素和促进生产率的政策。虽然我们发现20国集团经济体之间以及不同时期的生产率增长动态存在明显差异,但一个共同的观察结果是,自2010年代以来,全要素生产率增长放缓(甚至为负),这是普遍存在的。此外,每工人小时资本的增长也开始趋于平稳。我们制定了一种促进生产力的政策类型,并认为需要加强投资和技术变革政策,以支持生产率增长的复苏。这种政策应包括以平衡的方式促进技术进步和更迅速的扩散;加强投资,特别是无形资产和公共服务方面的投资;更多地关注人力资本。我们还主张加强制度和能力,以便在各国和不同时期动态学习促进生产力的政策。
{"title":"Are pro-productivity policies fit for purpose?","authors":"Bart van Ark,&nbsp;Klaas de Vries,&nbsp;Dirk Pilat","doi":"10.1111/manc.12464","DOIUrl":"10.1111/manc.12464","url":null,"abstract":"<p>In this paper we examine productivity trends, drivers of productivity growth and pro-productivity policies across the G-20 economies since 1970. While we find distinctly different productivity growth dynamics between G-20 economies and over time, one common observation is a widely shared slowdown in labour productivity growth since the 2010s underpinned by lower (or even negative) total factor productivity growth. Moreover, the growth in capital per worker hour has also begun to level off. We develop a typology of pro-productivity policies and argue that policies for investment and technological change need strengthening to support a revival of productivity growth. Such policies should include a balanced approach to stronger technological progress and more rapid diffusion; a strengthening of investment, especially in intangibles and public services; and greater attention for human capital. We also argue for stronger institutions and capabilities that allow for dynamic learning about pro-productivity policies across countries and over time.</p>","PeriodicalId":47546,"journal":{"name":"Manchester School","volume":"92 2","pages":"191-208"},"PeriodicalIF":1.1,"publicationDate":"2023-11-30","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/manc.12464","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"138504597","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"OA","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Current account dynamics: A SVAR analysis when the country-specific shocks are correlated at leads 经常账户动态:当特定国家的冲击在先导时相互关联时的 SVAR 分析
IF 1.1 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2023-11-01 DOI: 10.1111/manc.12462
César R. Sobrino, Ellis Heath

The assumption of no correlation of the structural shocks as Blanchard and Quah's identification (BQ) assumes is not suitable when central banks, through discretionary policies or inflation targeting regimes, affect the output growth among other goals. In this study, we analyze the present value model of the current account (PVM) using a three-SVAR specification and a modified BQ to identify three structural shocks: country-specific permanent, country-specific temporary, and global, but allowing the correlation of the domestic ones. Using Australia, Canada, Norway, and the UK, we find that those shocks are correlated and are less volatile than BQ would assume they are. The PVM predictions that hold are: (i) a positive (no) response in the current account to a country-specific temporary (global) shock; and (ii) with the exception of Australia, there is no response in the current account to a country-specific permanent shock. In addition, for all countries, the country-specific temporary shock dominates current account changes but does not dominate net output growth fluctuations, which was a puzzle identified by a prior study. The role of the shock is enhanced by the modified BQ, but even with this enhancement, it still does not hold the most significant role in output variations, as indicated by PVM.

当中央银行通过自由裁量政策或通胀目标制度影响产出增长等目标时,布兰查德和夸的识别(BQ)所假设的结构性冲击不相关的假设就不适用了。在本研究中,我们分析了经常账户的现值模型(PVM),使用了三SVAR规范和修正的BQ来识别三种结构性冲击:特定国家的永久性冲击、特定国家的暂时性冲击和全球性冲击,但允许国内冲击的相关性。通过使用澳大利亚、加拿大、挪威和英国的数据,我们发现这些冲击是相互关联的,而且波动性比 BQ 假设的要小。PVM 预测成立:(i) 经常账户对特定国家的临时(全球)冲击有正反应(无反应);(ii) 除澳大利亚外,经常账户对特定国家的永久冲击无反应。此外,对所有国家而言,特定国家的临时冲击主导了经常账户的变化,但并不主导净产出增长的波动,而这正是之前研究发现的一个难题。修正后的 BQ 增强了冲击的作用,但即使增强了冲击的作用,它在产出变化中的作用仍然不是最重要的,正如 PVM 所显示的那样。
{"title":"Current account dynamics: A SVAR analysis when the country-specific shocks are correlated at leads","authors":"César R. Sobrino,&nbsp;Ellis Heath","doi":"10.1111/manc.12462","DOIUrl":"10.1111/manc.12462","url":null,"abstract":"<p>The assumption of no correlation of the structural shocks as Blanchard and Quah's identification (BQ) assumes is not suitable when central banks, through discretionary policies or inflation targeting regimes, affect the output growth among other goals. In this study, we analyze the present value model of the current account (PVM) using a three-SVAR specification and a modified BQ to identify three structural shocks: country-specific permanent, country-specific temporary, and global, but allowing the correlation of the domestic ones. Using Australia, Canada, Norway, and the UK, we find that those shocks are correlated and are less volatile than BQ would assume they are. The PVM predictions that hold are: (i) a positive (no) response in the current account to a country-specific temporary (global) shock; and (ii) with the exception of Australia, there is no response in the current account to a country-specific permanent shock. In addition, for all countries, the country-specific temporary shock dominates current account changes but does not dominate net output growth fluctuations, which was a puzzle identified by a prior study. The role of the shock is enhanced by the modified BQ, but even with this enhancement, it still does not hold the most significant role in output variations, as indicated by PVM.</p>","PeriodicalId":47546,"journal":{"name":"Manchester School","volume":"92 2","pages":"171-190"},"PeriodicalIF":1.1,"publicationDate":"2023-11-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"135373087","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Frictions and the diffusion of automation 摩擦与自动化的普及
IF 1.1 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2023-10-30 DOI: 10.1111/manc.12461
Nikolaos Charalampidis

This paper studies the implications of business cycle frictions for the diffusion of permanent changes in automation. Incorporating task-based production in different versions of the New Keynesian model reveals considerable short-run implications. Price-distorting nominal rigidities amplify the labor displacement and attenuate the productivity and welfare gains of automation during the transition to the new equilibrium. They exacerbate the falls in the labor income share, the job finding probability, the value of long-term contracts, and labor market tightness. The inflation response follows a J-curve. Frictions in capital supply and wage rigidities amplify the labor displacement and attenuate the productivity gains too.

本文研究了商业周期摩擦对自动化永久性变革扩散的影响。将基于任务的生产纳入不同版本的新凯恩斯主义模型会产生相当大的短期影响。在向新均衡过渡的过程中,价格扭曲的名义刚性扩大了劳动力转移,削弱了自动化带来的生产率和福利收益。它们加剧了劳动收入份额、就业概率、长期合同价值和劳动力市场紧张程度的下降。通胀反应呈现 J 曲线。资本供应限制和工资刚性也会放大劳动力转移,并削弱生产率的提高。
{"title":"Frictions and the diffusion of automation","authors":"Nikolaos Charalampidis","doi":"10.1111/manc.12461","DOIUrl":"10.1111/manc.12461","url":null,"abstract":"<p>This paper studies the implications of business cycle frictions for the diffusion of permanent changes in automation. Incorporating task-based production in different versions of the New Keynesian model reveals considerable short-run implications. Price-distorting nominal rigidities amplify the labor displacement and attenuate the productivity and welfare gains of automation during the transition to the new equilibrium. They exacerbate the falls in the labor income share, the job finding probability, the value of long-term contracts, and labor market tightness. The inflation response follows a J-curve. Frictions in capital supply and wage rigidities amplify the labor displacement and attenuate the productivity gains too.</p>","PeriodicalId":47546,"journal":{"name":"Manchester School","volume":"92 2","pages":"148-170"},"PeriodicalIF":1.1,"publicationDate":"2023-10-30","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/manc.12461","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"136067986","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"OA","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Total factor productivity and structural reforms: Evidence from advanced economies sector-level data 全要素生产率与结构改革:来自发达经济体部门层面数据的证据
IF 1.1 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2023-10-27 DOI: 10.1111/manc.12463
João Tovar Jalles

This paper computes a new measure of capacity utilization-adjusted Total Factor Productivity (TFP) using sector-level data from a sample of 18 Advanced Economies and 24 industries between 1970 and 2014. We then empirically examine the impact of structural reforms (labor and product market) on TFP by means of the local projection method. Structural reforms follow a narrative-base construction which have several advantages in our context. Results show that structural reforms positively impact TFP, particularly the liberalization of employment protection legislation for regular workers. The effect of reforms affects both changes in resource misallocation across sectors (the between effect) and within sectors (the within effect). The TFP-effect of both types of reforms varies depending on the phase of the business cycle prevailing at the time the reform is implemented. Finally, our findings are robust to a wide range sensitivity checks.

本文利用 1970 年至 2014 年间 18 个发达经济体和 24 个行业的行业级样本数据,计算了经产能利用率调整的全要素生产率(TFP)的新指标。然后,我们通过本地预测法实证检验了结构改革(劳动力和产品市场)对全要素生产率的影响。结构改革采用叙述式结构,这在我们的研究中具有一些优势。结果表明,结构改革对全要素生产率产生了积极影响,尤其是针对正式工人的就业保护立法的自由化。改革效应既影响跨部门资源配置不当的变化(部门间效应),也影响部门内部资源配置不当的变化(部门内效应)。这两类改革对全要素生产率的影响因改革实施时商业周期所处的阶段而异。最后,我们的研究结果经得起各种敏感性检验。
{"title":"Total factor productivity and structural reforms: Evidence from advanced economies sector-level data","authors":"João Tovar Jalles","doi":"10.1111/manc.12463","DOIUrl":"10.1111/manc.12463","url":null,"abstract":"<p>This paper computes a new measure of capacity utilization-adjusted Total Factor Productivity (TFP) using sector-level data from a sample of 18 Advanced Economies and 24 industries between 1970 and 2014. We then empirically examine the impact of structural reforms (labor and product market) on TFP by means of the local projection method. Structural reforms follow a narrative-base construction which have several advantages in our context. Results show that structural reforms positively impact TFP, particularly the liberalization of employment protection legislation for regular workers. The effect of reforms affects both changes in resource misallocation across sectors (the between effect) and within sectors (the within effect). The TFP-effect of both types of reforms varies depending on the phase of the business cycle prevailing at the time the reform is implemented. Finally, our findings are robust to a wide range sensitivity checks.</p>","PeriodicalId":47546,"journal":{"name":"Manchester School","volume":"92 2","pages":"122-147"},"PeriodicalIF":1.1,"publicationDate":"2023-10-27","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"136263473","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Payment delay in workfare programmes and household welfare: Theory and some evidence from India 工作福利计划和家庭福利中的延迟支付:印度的理论和一些证据
IF 1.1 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2023-10-18 DOI: 10.1111/manc.12460
Parantap Basu, Rajesh Raj S. N, Kunal Sen

Using the lens of a life cycle model, we argue that an administrative failure of a wage payment delay in a workfare programme could adversely affect the welfare of the poor through two channels. First, it imposes an implicit consumption tax on the household. Second, it changes the status of labour from a “cash” to a credit” good and encourages workers with negative net worth to work harder to clear off the debt. The loss of welfare persists even when the worker has outside employment options. The model's prediction accords well with India's flagship National Rural Employment Guarantee Act (MGNREGA), where payment delay to workers participating in the programme has been endemic. Our empirical evidence suggests that, contrary to conventional wisdom, worker participation in the MGNREGA programme is positively associated with a wage payment delay. However, such increased worker participation instead of signalling success of the programme points to a deeper problem of this workfare programme because of the welfare loss suffered by asset-poor households.

利用生命周期模型的视角,我们认为,工作福利计划中延迟支付工资的行政失误会通过两种渠道对穷人的福利产生不利影响。首先,它会对家庭征收隐性消费税。其次,它将劳动力的地位从 "现金 "商品变为 "信贷 "商品,并鼓励净资产为负的工人更加努力地工作以偿还债务。即使工人有外部就业选择,福利损失也会持续存在。该模型的预测与印度的旗舰项目《国家农村就业保障法》(MGNREGA)十分吻合,在该项目中,拖欠参与工人工资的现象十分普遍。我们的经验证据表明,与传统观点相反,工人参与 MGNREGA 计划与工资支付延迟呈正相关。然而,工人参与度的提高并不意味着该计划的成功,而是表明了这一工作福利计划存在更深层次的问题,因为资产匮乏的家庭遭受了福利损失。
{"title":"Payment delay in workfare programmes and household welfare: Theory and some evidence from India","authors":"Parantap Basu,&nbsp;Rajesh Raj S. N,&nbsp;Kunal Sen","doi":"10.1111/manc.12460","DOIUrl":"10.1111/manc.12460","url":null,"abstract":"<p>Using the lens of a life cycle model, we argue that an administrative failure of a wage payment delay in a workfare programme could adversely affect the welfare of the poor through two channels. First, it imposes an implicit consumption tax on the household. Second, it changes the status of labour from a “cash” to a credit” good and encourages workers with negative net worth to work harder to clear off the debt. The loss of welfare persists even when the worker has outside employment options. The model's prediction accords well with India's flagship National Rural Employment Guarantee Act (MGNREGA), where payment delay to workers participating in the programme has been endemic. Our empirical evidence suggests that, contrary to conventional wisdom, worker participation in the MGNREGA programme is positively associated with a wage payment delay. However, such increased worker participation instead of signalling success of the programme points to a deeper problem of this workfare programme because of the welfare loss suffered by asset-poor households.</p>","PeriodicalId":47546,"journal":{"name":"Manchester School","volume":"92 2","pages":"93-121"},"PeriodicalIF":1.1,"publicationDate":"2023-10-18","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/manc.12460","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"135889917","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"OA","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Correction to Fixed-fee vs. royalty licensing under asymmetric demand information 非对称需求信息下固定费用与特许权使用费许可的修正
IF 1.1 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2023-09-07 DOI: 10.1111/manc.12459

In Li & Yanagawa (2021), the name and number of the funding project was omitted. This should be as follows:

Funding: This work was supported by Guangdong Office of Philosophy and Social Science Grant Number GD19CYJ08.

在李&;Yanagawa(2021),省略了资助项目的名称和编号。本研究得到广东省哲学社会科学厅GD19CYJ08号资助。
{"title":"Correction to Fixed-fee vs. royalty licensing under asymmetric demand information","authors":"","doi":"10.1111/manc.12459","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1111/manc.12459","url":null,"abstract":"<p>In Li &amp; Yanagawa (<span>2021</span>), the name and number of the funding project was omitted. This should be as follows:</p><p>Funding: This work was supported by Guangdong Office of Philosophy and Social Science Grant Number GD19CYJ08.</p>","PeriodicalId":47546,"journal":{"name":"Manchester School","volume":"91 6","pages":"642"},"PeriodicalIF":1.1,"publicationDate":"2023-09-07","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/manc.12459","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"50134901","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"OA","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
International trade: Smarten up to talk the talk 国际贸易:聪明起来说话
IF 1.1 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2023-09-05 DOI: 10.1111/manc.12458
Levi Haas, Klaus R. Schenk-Hoppé

International trade is currently under fire from many sides. Protectionist trade policies are on the rise, putting an end to the decade-long March of free trade. Making sense of the daily headlines and having an informed opinion on your own has rarely been more important than it is now. Our work aims to explain the driving forces behind international trade, its history, how it shaped the world, its economic models, issues ranging from job losses to the environment and why buying local often makes no sense. We summarize the most important academic literature on these topics in a non-technical, educational manner. If the reader feels enabled to form their own views on the pros and cons of international trade and that they can ‘talk the talk’, our effort has been fruitful.

国际贸易目前受到来自多方面的抨击。保护主义贸易政策正在兴起,结束了长达十年的自由贸易大游行。理解每天的头条新闻,并对自己有一个知情的意见,这从未像现在这样重要。我们的工作旨在解释国际贸易背后的驱动力、它的历史、它如何塑造世界、它的经济模式、从失业到环境等问题,以及为什么购买当地产品往往毫无意义。我们以非技术性、教育性的方式总结了关于这些主题的最重要的学术文献。如果读者能够对国际贸易的利弊形成自己的看法,并且能够“畅所欲言”,那么我们的努力是卓有成效的。
{"title":"International trade: Smarten up to talk the talk","authors":"Levi Haas,&nbsp;Klaus R. Schenk-Hoppé","doi":"10.1111/manc.12458","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1111/manc.12458","url":null,"abstract":"<p>International trade is currently under fire from many sides. Protectionist trade policies are on the rise, putting an end to the decade-long March of free trade. Making sense of the daily headlines and having an informed opinion on your own has rarely been more important than it is now. Our work aims to explain the driving forces behind international trade, its history, how it shaped the world, its economic models, issues ranging from job losses to the environment and why buying local often makes no sense. We summarize the most important academic literature on these topics in a non-technical, educational manner. If the reader feels enabled to form their own views on the pros and cons of international trade and that they can ‘talk the talk’, our effort has been fruitful.</p>","PeriodicalId":47546,"journal":{"name":"Manchester School","volume":"91 6","pages":"521-569"},"PeriodicalIF":1.1,"publicationDate":"2023-09-05","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/manc.12458","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"50122345","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"OA","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
期刊
Manchester School
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1