首页 > 最新文献

Columbia Law Review最新文献

英文 中文
The Purpose Driven Rule: Drew Peterson, Giles v. California, and the Transferred Intent Doctrine of Forfeiture by Wrongdoing 目的驱动规则:德鲁·彼得森,贾尔斯诉加州案,以及因不法行为而被没收的转让意图原则
IF 2.9 2区 社会学 Pub Date : 2012-09-13 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.2145928
Colin Miller
On September 6, 2012, a jury convicted Drew Peterson of the murder of his third wife, Kathleen Savio. Media accounts of the verdict indicated that jurors were primarily swayed by the admission of hearsay statements by Savio as well as Peterson’s third wife, Stacy Peterson. Numerous stories reported that the prosecution admitted these hearsay statements pursuant to “Drew’s Law,” a statutory codification of the common law doctrine of forfeiture by wrongdoing that the Illinois legislature enacted solely for purposes of the Peterson prosecution. In fact, these statements were admitted under the common law doctrine of forfeiture by wrongdoing, and the viability of Peterson’s appeal hinges upon the constitutionality of the transferred intent doctrine of forfeiture by wrongdoing.The doctrine of forfeiture by wrongdoing typically applies in the witness tampering context: When a defendant on trial for some crime (e.g., robbery) intends to and does procure the unavailability of a prospective witness against him at that trial, the prosecution can admit the witness’s hearsay statements at that same trial (the robbery trial). But does the doctrine also apply at the defendant’s trial for murdering the prospective witness, with the defendant’s intent to render the witness unavailable at the first trial transferring to the second trial? This essay contends that the Supreme Court’s opinion in Giles v. California endorsed a transferred intent doctrine of forfeiture by wrongdoing by making the operation of the doctrine dependent upon causation and intent rather than causation and benefit.
2012年9月6日,陪审团判定德鲁·彼得森谋杀第三任妻子凯瑟琳·萨维奥的罪名成立。媒体对判决的报道表明,陪审团主要是被萨维奥和彼得森的第三任妻子斯泰西·彼得森(Stacy Peterson)承认的道听途说所左右。许多报道称,检方根据“德鲁法”(Drew’s Law)承认了这些道听途说。“德鲁法”是对普通法中因不法行为而没收财产原则的法定编纂,伊利诺伊州立法机关仅为彼得森一案的起诉而制定了这一法律。事实上,这些陈述在普通法中因不法行为而没收财产的原则下是被承认的,而彼得森上诉的可行性取决于因不法行为而没收财产的意图转移原则的合宪性。不法行为没收的原则通常适用于篡改证人的情况:当因某些罪行(例如抢劫)受审的被告有意并且确实在审判中使可能对他不利的证人无法出庭时,控方可以在同一审判(抢劫审判)中承认证人的道听途说。但是,这一原则是否也适用于被告谋杀潜在证人的审判,而被告的意图是使证人无法在一审中被转移到二审中?本文认为,最高法院在Giles诉加州案中的意见通过使该原则的运作依赖于因果关系和意图而不是因果关系和利益,从而支持了因不法行为而没收财产的转移意图原则。
{"title":"The Purpose Driven Rule: Drew Peterson, Giles v. California, and the Transferred Intent Doctrine of Forfeiture by Wrongdoing","authors":"Colin Miller","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.2145928","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.2145928","url":null,"abstract":"On September 6, 2012, a jury convicted Drew Peterson of the murder of his third wife, Kathleen Savio. Media accounts of the verdict indicated that jurors were primarily swayed by the admission of hearsay statements by Savio as well as Peterson’s third wife, Stacy Peterson. Numerous stories reported that the prosecution admitted these hearsay statements pursuant to “Drew’s Law,” a statutory codification of the common law doctrine of forfeiture by wrongdoing that the Illinois legislature enacted solely for purposes of the Peterson prosecution. In fact, these statements were admitted under the common law doctrine of forfeiture by wrongdoing, and the viability of Peterson’s appeal hinges upon the constitutionality of the transferred intent doctrine of forfeiture by wrongdoing.The doctrine of forfeiture by wrongdoing typically applies in the witness tampering context: When a defendant on trial for some crime (e.g., robbery) intends to and does procure the unavailability of a prospective witness against him at that trial, the prosecution can admit the witness’s hearsay statements at that same trial (the robbery trial). But does the doctrine also apply at the defendant’s trial for murdering the prospective witness, with the defendant’s intent to render the witness unavailable at the first trial transferring to the second trial? This essay contends that the Supreme Court’s opinion in Giles v. California endorsed a transferred intent doctrine of forfeiture by wrongdoing by making the operation of the doctrine dependent upon causation and intent rather than causation and benefit.","PeriodicalId":51408,"journal":{"name":"Columbia Law Review","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":2.9,"publicationDate":"2012-09-13","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"67950315","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":2,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Malpractice Mobs: Medical Dispute Resolution in China 医疗事故暴民:中国医疗纠纷解决
IF 2.9 2区 社会学 Pub Date : 2012-07-12 DOI: 10.7916/D8445M3B
B. Liebman
China has experienced a surge in medical disputes in recent years, on the streets and in the courts. Many disputes result in violence. Quantitative and qualitative empirical evidence of medical malpractice litigation and medical disputes in China reveals a dynamic in which the formal legal system operates in the shadow of protest and violence. The threat of violence leads hospitals to settle claims for more than would be available in court and also influences how judges handle cases that do wind up in court. The detailed evidence regarding medical disputes presented in this article adds depth to existing understanding of institutional development in China, showing that increased innovation and competence are not resulting in greater authority for the courts. Despite thirty-four years of legal reforms and significant strengthening of legal institutions, the shadow of the law remains weak. Medical cases highlight largely unobserved trends in both law and governance in China, in particular state over-responsiveness to individual grievances. The findings presented here suggest limitations to contemporary understanding of both the functioning of the Chinese state and of the role of law in China, and add to existing literature on the non-convergence of the Chinese system to existing models of legal and political development.
近年来,中国在街头和法庭上经历了医疗纠纷的激增。许多争端导致暴力。中国医疗事故诉讼和医疗纠纷的定量和定性经验证据揭示了正式法律制度在抗议和暴力阴影下运作的动态。暴力威胁导致医院解决的索赔金额超过了法庭上的金额,也影响了法官如何处理最终上法庭的案件。本文中提出的关于医疗纠纷的详细证据加深了对中国制度发展的现有理解,表明创新和能力的提高并没有导致法院拥有更大的权力。尽管经过了34年的法律改革和法律机构的大力加强,但法律的影子仍然很弱。医疗案件凸显了中国法律和治理方面基本上未被观察到的趋势,特别是国家对个人不满的过度回应。本文提出的研究结果表明,当代对中国国家职能和法律在中国的作用的理解存在局限性,并补充了有关中国制度与现有法律和政治发展模式不趋同的现有文献。
{"title":"Malpractice Mobs: Medical Dispute Resolution in China","authors":"B. Liebman","doi":"10.7916/D8445M3B","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.7916/D8445M3B","url":null,"abstract":"China has experienced a surge in medical disputes in recent years, on the streets and in the courts. Many disputes result in violence. Quantitative and qualitative empirical evidence of medical malpractice litigation and medical disputes in China reveals a dynamic in which the formal legal system operates in the shadow of protest and violence. The threat of violence leads hospitals to settle claims for more than would be available in court and also influences how judges handle cases that do wind up in court. The detailed evidence regarding medical disputes presented in this article adds depth to existing understanding of institutional development in China, showing that increased innovation and competence are not resulting in greater authority for the courts. Despite thirty-four years of legal reforms and significant strengthening of legal institutions, the shadow of the law remains weak. Medical cases highlight largely unobserved trends in both law and governance in China, in particular state over-responsiveness to individual grievances. The findings presented here suggest limitations to contemporary understanding of both the functioning of the Chinese state and of the role of law in China, and add to existing literature on the non-convergence of the Chinese system to existing models of legal and political development.","PeriodicalId":51408,"journal":{"name":"Columbia Law Review","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":2.9,"publicationDate":"2012-07-12","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"71364590","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":2,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 84
Conventions of Agency Independence 机构独立公约
IF 2.9 2区 社会学 Pub Date : 2012-07-10 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.2103338
Adrian Vermeule
It is often said that the legal touchstone of agency independence is whether the agency head or heads are removable at will, or only for cause. Yet this test does not adequately describe the landscape of agency independence. There are many important agencies who are conventionally treated as independent, yet whose heads lack for-cause tenure protection. Conversely, there are agencies whose heads enjoy for-cause tenure protection, yet are by all accounts thoroughly dependent upon organized interest groups, the White House, legislators and legislative committees, or all of these. Legally enforceable for-cause tenure protection is neither necessary nor sufficient for operational independence. The crucial consideration, largely neglected in the literature, is the role of what Commonwealth lawyers call conventions. Agencies that lack for-cause tenure yet enjoy operative independence are protected by unwritten conventions that constrain political actors from attempting to remove their members, to direct their exercise of discretion, or both. Such conventions may be generated by a variety of mechanisms; the common feature is that norms arising within relevant legal and political communities impose sanctions for violations of agency independence or create beliefs or internalized moral strictures protecting that independence. Conversely, where agencies enjoy statutory independence yet lack operative independence, the reason is that the interaction among relevant political actors has failed to generate any such set of protective conventions. The lens of convention helps resolve a range of puzzles about the behavior of Presidents, legislators, judges and other actors with respect to agency independence – including the Supreme Court’s puzzling treatment of SEC independence in Free Enterprise Fund v. PCAOB.By bringing the conventional character of agency independence to the surface, U.S. courts may begin to incorporate ideas from the courts of Commonwealth legal systems – such as the United Kingdom and Canada – that are familiar with the promise and problems of conventions and with the methods for harmonizing conventions with written rules of law. My principal suggestion is that U.S. courts interpreting statutes and constitutional rules that bear on agency independence should adopt the leading Commonwealth approach, according to which judges may indirectly “recognize” conventions and incorporate them into their interpretation of written law, although they may not directly enforce conventions as freestanding obligations.
人们常说,机构独立性的法律试金石是机构负责人或负责人是否可以随意撤换,还是只能因公撤换。然而,这个测试并没有充分描述机构独立性的状况。有许多重要的机构传统上被视为独立的,但它们的负责人却无缘无故地缺乏任期保护。相反,有些机构的负责人享有终身职位保护,但从各方面来看,他们完全依赖于有组织的利益集团、白宫、立法者和立法委员会,或者所有这些。法律上可强制执行的权属保护既不是业务独立性的必要条件,也不是充分条件。文献中很大程度上被忽视的关键考虑因素是英联邦律师所谓的惯例的作用。那些没有固定任期但享有运作独立性的机构受到不成文公约的保护,这些公约限制政治行为者试图罢免其成员,或指导其行使自由裁量权,或两者兼而有之。这些公约可以由各种机制产生;共同的特点是,在有关的法律和政治社区内产生的规范对侵犯机构独立性的行为施加制裁,或创造保护这种独立性的信念或内化的道德约束。相反,在机构享有法定独立性但缺乏业务独立性的情况下,其原因是有关政治行为者之间的相互作用未能产生任何这种保护性公约。惯例的视角有助于解决有关总统、立法者、法官和其他行为主体在机构独立性方面的一系列困惑——包括最高法院在自由企业基金诉PCAOB案中对SEC独立性的令人困惑的处理。通过将机构独立性的传统特征展现出来,美国法院可能会开始吸收英联邦法律体系法院的思想,如英国和加拿大,这些法院熟悉公约的承诺和问题,以及公约与书面法律规则相协调的方法。我的主要建议是,美国法院在解释与机构独立性有关的成文法和宪法规则时,应该采用联邦的主要方法,根据这种方法,法官可以间接地“承认”公约,并将其纳入成文法的解释中,尽管他们可能不会将公约作为独立的义务直接执行。
{"title":"Conventions of Agency Independence","authors":"Adrian Vermeule","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.2103338","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.2103338","url":null,"abstract":"It is often said that the legal touchstone of agency independence is whether the agency head or heads are removable at will, or only for cause. Yet this test does not adequately describe the landscape of agency independence. There are many important agencies who are conventionally treated as independent, yet whose heads lack for-cause tenure protection. Conversely, there are agencies whose heads enjoy for-cause tenure protection, yet are by all accounts thoroughly dependent upon organized interest groups, the White House, legislators and legislative committees, or all of these. Legally enforceable for-cause tenure protection is neither necessary nor sufficient for operational independence. The crucial consideration, largely neglected in the literature, is the role of what Commonwealth lawyers call conventions. Agencies that lack for-cause tenure yet enjoy operative independence are protected by unwritten conventions that constrain political actors from attempting to remove their members, to direct their exercise of discretion, or both. Such conventions may be generated by a variety of mechanisms; the common feature is that norms arising within relevant legal and political communities impose sanctions for violations of agency independence or create beliefs or internalized moral strictures protecting that independence. Conversely, where agencies enjoy statutory independence yet lack operative independence, the reason is that the interaction among relevant political actors has failed to generate any such set of protective conventions. The lens of convention helps resolve a range of puzzles about the behavior of Presidents, legislators, judges and other actors with respect to agency independence – including the Supreme Court’s puzzling treatment of SEC independence in Free Enterprise Fund v. PCAOB.By bringing the conventional character of agency independence to the surface, U.S. courts may begin to incorporate ideas from the courts of Commonwealth legal systems – such as the United Kingdom and Canada – that are familiar with the promise and problems of conventions and with the methods for harmonizing conventions with written rules of law. My principal suggestion is that U.S. courts interpreting statutes and constitutional rules that bear on agency independence should adopt the leading Commonwealth approach, according to which judges may indirectly “recognize” conventions and incorporate them into their interpretation of written law, although they may not directly enforce conventions as freestanding obligations.","PeriodicalId":51408,"journal":{"name":"Columbia Law Review","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":2.9,"publicationDate":"2012-07-10","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"67912700","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":2,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 8
Thirteenth Amendment Optimism 第十三条修正案的乐观主义
IF 2.9 2区 社会学 Pub Date : 2012-05-24 DOI: 10.7916/D8KD1X1F
J. Greene
Thirteenth Amendment optimism is the view that the Thirteenth Amendment may be used to reach doctrinal outcomes neither specifically intended by the amendment's drafters nor obvious to contemporary audiences. In prominent legal scholarship, Thirteenth Amendment optimism has supported constitutional rights to abortion and health care and constitutional powers to prohibit hate speech and domestic violence, among other things. This article examines the practical utility of Thirteenth Amendment optimism in the face of dim prospects for adoption by courts. I argue that Thirteenth Amendment optimism is most valuable, both historically and today, as a means of motivating the political process to protect affirmative constitutional rights.
第十三修正案乐观主义认为,第十三修正案可能被用来达到既不是修正案起草者的具体意图,也不是当代受众显而易见的教义结果。在著名的法律学者中,第十三条修正案的乐观主义支持堕胎和医疗保健的宪法权利,以及禁止仇恨言论和家庭暴力等宪法权力。本文考察了在法院采用第十三条修正案前景黯淡的情况下,第十三条修正案的乐观主义的实际效用。我认为,无论是在历史上还是在今天,第十三条修正案的乐观主义都是最有价值的,因为它是一种激励政治进程以保护平权宪法权利的手段。
{"title":"Thirteenth Amendment Optimism","authors":"J. Greene","doi":"10.7916/D8KD1X1F","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.7916/D8KD1X1F","url":null,"abstract":"Thirteenth Amendment optimism is the view that the Thirteenth Amendment may be used to reach doctrinal outcomes neither specifically intended by the amendment's drafters nor obvious to contemporary audiences. In prominent legal scholarship, Thirteenth Amendment optimism has supported constitutional rights to abortion and health care and constitutional powers to prohibit hate speech and domestic violence, among other things. This article examines the practical utility of Thirteenth Amendment optimism in the face of dim prospects for adoption by courts. I argue that Thirteenth Amendment optimism is most valuable, both historically and today, as a means of motivating the political process to protect affirmative constitutional rights.","PeriodicalId":51408,"journal":{"name":"Columbia Law Review","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":2.9,"publicationDate":"2012-05-24","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"71366927","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":2,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Stock Unloading and Banker Incentives 股票抛售和银行家激励
IF 2.9 2区 社会学 Pub Date : 2012-05-01 DOI: 10.7916/D8RF5V2G
R. Jackson
{"title":"Stock Unloading and Banker Incentives","authors":"R. Jackson","doi":"10.7916/D8RF5V2G","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.7916/D8RF5V2G","url":null,"abstract":"","PeriodicalId":51408,"journal":{"name":"Columbia Law Review","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":2.9,"publicationDate":"2012-05-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"71368126","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":2,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Delegating to Enemies 委派给敌人
IF 2.9 2区 社会学 Pub Date : 2012-03-07 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.2017974
Jacob E. Gersen, Adrian Vermeule
An axiom of institutional design is known as the ally principle: all else equal, voters, legislators or other principals will rationally delegate more authority to agents who share their preferences (“allies”). The ally principle is a conventional starting point for large literatures on principal-agent relationships in economics, political science, and law. In public law, theories of delegation – from legislatures to internal committees, from legislatures to agencies and the executive, or from higher courts to lower courts – universally assume the ally principle. Yet history and institutional practice reveal many cases in which the ally principle not only fails to hold, but actually gets things backwards. We identify an enemy principle: in certain cases principals rationally delegate, not to allies, but to enemies or potential enemies — agents who do not share the principal’s preferences or whose preferences are uncertain at the time of the delegation. Our aim is to describe these cases of delegating to enemies, to explain the mechanisms on which they rest, and to offer an account of the conditions under which principals do best by following the enemy principle and reversing the ally principle. Such an account is a necessary first step towards a fully general and comprehensive theory of delegation, one that includes both the ally principle and the enemy principle as special cases.
制度设计的一个公理被称为盟友原则:在其他条件相同的情况下,选民、立法者或其他主体会理性地将更多权力下放给与他们有共同偏好的代理人(“盟友”)。同盟原则是经济学、政治学和法学中关于委托代理关系的大量文献的传统起点。在公法中,授权理论——从立法机关到内部委员会,从立法机关到机构和行政部门,或从高等法院到下级法院——普遍采用同盟原则。然而,历史和制度实践表明,在许多情况下,盟友原则不仅不成立,而且实际上是在倒退。我们确定了一个敌人原则:在某些情况下,委托人会理性地委托,不是委托给盟友,而是委托给敌人或潜在的敌人——那些与委托人的偏好不同或在委托时偏好不确定的代理人。我们的目的是描述这些委托给敌人的案例,解释它们所依赖的机制,并提供一个条件的说明,在这些条件下,通过遵循敌人原则和逆转盟友原则,委托人做得最好。这样的解释是必要的第一步,目的是建立一个完全一般和全面的授权理论,其中包括作为特殊情况的同盟者原则和敌人原则。
{"title":"Delegating to Enemies","authors":"Jacob E. Gersen, Adrian Vermeule","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.2017974","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.2017974","url":null,"abstract":"An axiom of institutional design is known as the ally principle: all else equal, voters, legislators or other principals will rationally delegate more authority to agents who share their preferences (“allies”). The ally principle is a conventional starting point for large literatures on principal-agent relationships in economics, political science, and law. In public law, theories of delegation – from legislatures to internal committees, from legislatures to agencies and the executive, or from higher courts to lower courts – universally assume the ally principle. Yet history and institutional practice reveal many cases in which the ally principle not only fails to hold, but actually gets things backwards. We identify an enemy principle: in certain cases principals rationally delegate, not to allies, but to enemies or potential enemies — agents who do not share the principal’s preferences or whose preferences are uncertain at the time of the delegation. Our aim is to describe these cases of delegating to enemies, to explain the mechanisms on which they rest, and to offer an account of the conditions under which principals do best by following the enemy principle and reversing the ally principle. Such an account is a necessary first step towards a fully general and comprehensive theory of delegation, one that includes both the ally principle and the enemy principle as special cases.","PeriodicalId":51408,"journal":{"name":"Columbia Law Review","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":2.9,"publicationDate":"2012-03-07","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"67856626","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":2,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 5
The Agency Class Action 机构集体诉讼
IF 2.9 2区 社会学 Pub Date : 2012-01-22 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.1997421
Michael D. Sant'Ambrogio, Adam S. Zimmerman
The number of claims languishing on administrative dockets has become a new “crisis” — producing significant backlogs, arbitrary outcomes and new barriers to justice. Coal miners, disabled employees, and wounded soldiers sit on endless waitlists to appeal the same kinds of administrative decisions that frequently result in reversal. Refugees seeking asylum from the same country play a dangerous game of “roulette” before arbitrary decisionmakers. Defrauded consumers and investors miss out on fair compensation, as agencies settle the same claims with wrongdoers without victim participation or meaningful judicial oversight. Reformers have called for new resources, more administrative law judges and improved attorney fee arrangements. But surprisingly, commentators have largely ignored tools long used by courts to resolve common claims raised by large groups of people: the class action and other complex litigation procedures. Almost no administrative law process allows groups to aggregate and resolve common claims for relief. As a result, in a wide variety adjudicatory proceedings, administrative agencies routinely (1) waste resources on repetitive cases, (2) reach inconsistent decisions for the same kinds of claims, and (3) deny individuals access to the affordable representation that aggregate procedures otherwise promise. Moreover, procedural and substantive hurdles — including exhaustion of administrative remedies and judicial deference to agency expertise — often prevent federal courts from providing class-wide relief to parties in agency adjudications.We argue that agencies themselves should adopt aggregation procedures, like those under Rule 23 of the Federal Rules of Civil Procedure, to adjudicate common claims raised by large groups of people. After surveying the current tools by which agencies could promote more efficiency, consistency and legal access — including rulemaking, stare decisis, attorneys fees and federal court class actions — we find agency class action rules more effectively resolve common disputes by: (1) efficiently creating ways to pool information about recurring problems and enjoin systemic harms; (2) achieving greater equality in outcomes than individual adjudication; and (3) securing legal and expert assistance at a critical stage in the process. In this way, The Agency Class Action represents a new kind of decision-making for administrative agencies — a blend of adjudication and rulemaking for large groups of people who similarly depend upon the administrative state for relief.
积压在行政案卷上的索赔数量已成为一种新的“危机”——造成大量积压、武断的结果和新的司法障碍。煤矿工人、残疾雇员和受伤的士兵等着对同样的行政决定提出上诉,而这些行政决定往往导致撤销。从同一个国家寻求庇护的难民在武断的决策者面前玩着一场危险的“轮盘赌”游戏。被欺骗的消费者和投资者无法获得公平的赔偿,因为机构在没有受害者参与或有意义的司法监督的情况下与不法行为者解决了同样的索赔。改革派呼吁增加资源,增加行政法法官,改善律师费安排。但令人惊讶的是,评论人士在很大程度上忽略了法院长期以来用来解决大量人群提出的共同索赔的工具:集体诉讼和其他复杂的诉讼程序。几乎没有任何行政法程序允许团体聚集并解决共同的救济要求。因此,在各种各样的审判程序中,行政机构通常(1)在重复的案件上浪费资源,(2)对同类索赔作出不一致的决定,以及(3)拒绝个人获得综合程序所承诺的负担得起的代理。此外,程序性和实质性障碍- -包括用尽行政补救办法和司法上对机构专门知识的尊重- -往往妨碍联邦法院在机构裁决中向当事人提供班级范围的救济。我们认为,行政机关本身应该采用汇总程序,就像《联邦民事诉讼规则》第23条规定的那样,来裁决由一大群人提出的共同索赔。在调查了机构可以提高效率、一致性和法律获取的现有工具——包括规则制定、决策、律师费和联邦法院集体诉讼——之后,我们发现机构集体诉讼规则通过以下方式更有效地解决了常见的争议:(1)有效地创造了关于反复出现的问题和禁止系统性损害的信息汇集的方法;(2)实现比单独裁决更大的结果平等;(3)在过程的关键阶段确保法律和专家援助。通过这种方式,“机构集体诉讼”代表了行政机构的一种新的决策方式——为同样依赖行政国家获得救济的大批人提供裁决和规则制定的混合。
{"title":"The Agency Class Action","authors":"Michael D. Sant'Ambrogio, Adam S. Zimmerman","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.1997421","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.1997421","url":null,"abstract":"The number of claims languishing on administrative dockets has become a new “crisis” — producing significant backlogs, arbitrary outcomes and new barriers to justice. Coal miners, disabled employees, and wounded soldiers sit on endless waitlists to appeal the same kinds of administrative decisions that frequently result in reversal. Refugees seeking asylum from the same country play a dangerous game of “roulette” before arbitrary decisionmakers. Defrauded consumers and investors miss out on fair compensation, as agencies settle the same claims with wrongdoers without victim participation or meaningful judicial oversight. Reformers have called for new resources, more administrative law judges and improved attorney fee arrangements. But surprisingly, commentators have largely ignored tools long used by courts to resolve common claims raised by large groups of people: the class action and other complex litigation procedures. Almost no administrative law process allows groups to aggregate and resolve common claims for relief. As a result, in a wide variety adjudicatory proceedings, administrative agencies routinely (1) waste resources on repetitive cases, (2) reach inconsistent decisions for the same kinds of claims, and (3) deny individuals access to the affordable representation that aggregate procedures otherwise promise. Moreover, procedural and substantive hurdles — including exhaustion of administrative remedies and judicial deference to agency expertise — often prevent federal courts from providing class-wide relief to parties in agency adjudications.We argue that agencies themselves should adopt aggregation procedures, like those under Rule 23 of the Federal Rules of Civil Procedure, to adjudicate common claims raised by large groups of people. After surveying the current tools by which agencies could promote more efficiency, consistency and legal access — including rulemaking, stare decisis, attorneys fees and federal court class actions — we find agency class action rules more effectively resolve common disputes by: (1) efficiently creating ways to pool information about recurring problems and enjoin systemic harms; (2) achieving greater equality in outcomes than individual adjudication; and (3) securing legal and expert assistance at a critical stage in the process. In this way, The Agency Class Action represents a new kind of decision-making for administrative agencies — a blend of adjudication and rulemaking for large groups of people who similarly depend upon the administrative state for relief.","PeriodicalId":51408,"journal":{"name":"Columbia Law Review","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":2.9,"publicationDate":"2012-01-22","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"67838184","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":2,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 6
Unions, Corporations, and Political Opt-Out Rights after Citizens United 联合公民之后的工会、公司和政治选择退出权
IF 2.9 2区 社会学 Pub Date : 2011-08-15 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.1924916
B. Sachs
Citizens United upends much of campaign finance law, but it maintains at least one feature of that legal regime: the equal treatment of corporations and unions. Prior to Citizens United, that is, corporations and unions were equally constrained in their ability to spend general treasury funds on federal electoral politics. After the decision, campaign finance law leaves both equally unconstrained and free to use their general treasuries to finance political spending. But the symmetrical treatment that Citizens United leaves in place masks a less visible, but equally significant, way in which the law treats union and corporate political spending differently. Namely, federal law prohibits a union from spending its general treasury funds on politics if individual employees object to such use - employees, in short, enjoy a federally protected right to opt out of funding union political activity. In contrast, corporations are free to spend their general treasuries on politics even if individual shareholders object - shareholders enjoy no right to opt out of financing corporate political activity. This article assesses whether the asymmetric rule of political opt-out rights is justified. The article first offers an affirmative case for symmetry grounded in the principle that the power to control access to economic opportunities - whether employment or investment-based - should not be used to secure compliance with or support for the economic actor’s political agenda. It then addresses three arguments in favor of asymmetry. Given the relative weakness of these arguments, the article suggests that the current asymmetry in opt-out rules may be unjustified. The article concludes by pointing to constitutional questions raised by this asymmetry, and by arguing that lawmakers would be justified in correcting it.
联合公民颠覆了竞选财务法的大部分内容,但它至少保持了该法律制度的一个特征:对企业和工会的平等对待。也就是说,在联合公民之前,企业和工会在联邦选举政治上使用一般国库资金的能力同样受到限制。在这一决定之后,竞选财务法允许两党同样不受限制地自由使用他们的国库来资助政治支出。但是,“联合公民”所保留的对称待遇掩盖了一个不太明显、但同样重要的问题,即法律对工会和企业政治支出的区别对待。也就是说,联邦法律禁止工会在个别雇员反对的情况下将其一般财政资金用于政治活动——简而言之,雇员享有联邦保护的选择不资助工会政治活动的权利。相比之下,即使个别股东反对,企业也可以自由地将其国库用于政治——股东没有选择不为企业政治活动提供资金的权利。本文评估了政治选择退出权的不对称规则是否合理。这篇文章首先提供了一个对称的肯定案例,其基础是不应利用控制获得经济机会(无论是就业机会还是投资机会)的权力来确保经济行动者的政治议程得到遵守或支持。然后,它提出了支持不对称的三个论点。考虑到这些论点的相对薄弱,这篇文章表明,当前选择退出规则的不对称可能是不合理的。文章最后指出了这种不对称引发的宪法问题,并认为立法者有理由纠正这种不对称。
{"title":"Unions, Corporations, and Political Opt-Out Rights after Citizens United","authors":"B. Sachs","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.1924916","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.1924916","url":null,"abstract":"Citizens United upends much of campaign finance law, but it maintains at least one feature of that legal regime: the equal treatment of corporations and unions. Prior to Citizens United, that is, corporations and unions were equally constrained in their ability to spend general treasury funds on federal electoral politics. After the decision, campaign finance law leaves both equally unconstrained and free to use their general treasuries to finance political spending. But the symmetrical treatment that Citizens United leaves in place masks a less visible, but equally significant, way in which the law treats union and corporate political spending differently. Namely, federal law prohibits a union from spending its general treasury funds on politics if individual employees object to such use - employees, in short, enjoy a federally protected right to opt out of funding union political activity. In contrast, corporations are free to spend their general treasuries on politics even if individual shareholders object - shareholders enjoy no right to opt out of financing corporate political activity. This article assesses whether the asymmetric rule of political opt-out rights is justified. The article first offers an affirmative case for symmetry grounded in the principle that the power to control access to economic opportunities - whether employment or investment-based - should not be used to secure compliance with or support for the economic actor’s political agenda. It then addresses three arguments in favor of asymmetry. Given the relative weakness of these arguments, the article suggests that the current asymmetry in opt-out rules may be unjustified. The article concludes by pointing to constitutional questions raised by this asymmetry, and by arguing that lawmakers would be justified in correcting it.","PeriodicalId":51408,"journal":{"name":"Columbia Law Review","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":2.9,"publicationDate":"2011-08-15","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"67791464","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":2,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 13
Of Speech and Sanctions: Toward a Penalty-Sensitive Approach to the First Amendment 论言论与制裁:对第一修正案的处罚敏感态度
IF 2.9 2区 社会学 Pub Date : 2011-08-11 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.1908408
Michaela Coenen
Courts confronting First Amendment claims do not often scrutinize the severity of a speaker’s punishment. Embracing a “penalty-neutral” understanding of the free-speech right, these courts tend to treat an individual’s expression as either protected, in which case the government may not punish it at all, or unprotected, in which case the government may punish it to a very great degree. There is, however, a small but important body of “penalty-sensitive” case law that runs counter to the penalty-neutral norm. Within this case law, the severity of a speaker’s punishment affects the merits of her First Amendment claim, thus giving rise to categories of expression that the government may punish, but only to a limited extent. This Article defends penalty-sensitive free- speech adjudication and calls for its expanded use within First Amendment law. Pulling together existing strands of penalty-sensitive doctrine, the Article identifies five ways in which penalty-sensitive analysis can further important constitutional objectives: (1) by increasing fairness for similarly-situated speakers; (2) by mitigating chilling effects on protected speech; (3) by facilitating the “efficient breach” of constitutionally borderline speech restrictions; (4) by rooting out improper government motives; and (5) by promoting transparency in judicial decision-making. The Article also considers and rejects potential objections to the penalty-sensitive approach, concluding that it will often generate proper results in difficult First Amendment cases.
面对第一修正案主张的法院通常不会仔细审查对发言人的惩罚的严重程度。这些法院对言论自由权持“惩罚中立”的理解,倾向于将个人的言论视为受保护的,在这种情况下,政府可能根本不会惩罚它,或者不受保护的,在这种情况下,政府可能会对其进行很大程度的惩罚。然而,有一小部分“对刑罚敏感”的判例法,与“刑罚中立”的准则背道而驰,但这部分判例法很重要。在这一判例法中,对发言人的惩罚的严重程度影响到她所主张的第一修正案的价值,从而产生了政府可以惩罚的言论类别,但仅限于有限的程度。本文捍卫对刑罚敏感的言论自由裁决,并呼吁在第一修正案法律范围内扩大其使用。将现有的对刑罚敏感的学说整合在一起,本文确定了对刑罚敏感的分析可以促进重要宪法目标的五种方式:(1)通过增加对处境相似的发言者的公平;(2)减轻对受保护言论的寒蝉效应;(3)通过促进“有效违反”宪法边界的言论限制;(四)根除政府的不正当动机;(5)提高司法决策的透明度。该条还考虑并驳回了对惩罚敏感方法的潜在反对意见,结论是它通常会在棘手的第一修正案案件中产生适当的结果。
{"title":"Of Speech and Sanctions: Toward a Penalty-Sensitive Approach to the First Amendment","authors":"Michaela Coenen","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.1908408","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1908408","url":null,"abstract":"Courts confronting First Amendment claims do not often scrutinize the severity of a speaker’s punishment. Embracing a “penalty-neutral” understanding of the free-speech right, these courts tend to treat an individual’s expression as either protected, in which case the government may not punish it at all, or unprotected, in which case the government may punish it to a very great degree. There is, however, a small but important body of “penalty-sensitive” case law that runs counter to the penalty-neutral norm. Within this case law, the severity of a speaker’s punishment affects the merits of her First Amendment claim, thus giving rise to categories of expression that the government may punish, but only to a limited extent. This Article defends penalty-sensitive free- speech adjudication and calls for its expanded use within First Amendment law. Pulling together existing strands of penalty-sensitive doctrine, the Article identifies five ways in which penalty-sensitive analysis can further important constitutional objectives: (1) by increasing fairness for similarly-situated speakers; (2) by mitigating chilling effects on protected speech; (3) by facilitating the “efficient breach” of constitutionally borderline speech restrictions; (4) by rooting out improper government motives; and (5) by promoting transparency in judicial decision-making. The Article also considers and rejects potential objections to the penalty-sensitive approach, concluding that it will often generate proper results in difficult First Amendment cases.","PeriodicalId":51408,"journal":{"name":"Columbia Law Review","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":2.9,"publicationDate":"2011-08-11","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"67778031","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":2,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2
Article III, Agency Adjudication, and the Origins of the Appellate Review Model of Administrative Law 第三章行政机关裁决与行政法上诉审查模式的渊源
IF 2.9 2区 社会学 Pub Date : 2011-06-01 DOI: 10.7916/D88915DF
T. Merrill
American administrative law is grounded in a conception of the relationship between reviewing courts and agencies modeled on the relationship between appeals courts and trial courts in civil litigation. This appellate review model was not an inevitable foundation of administrative law, but it has had far-reaching consequences, and its origins are poorly understood. This Article details how the appellate review model emerged after 1906 as an improvised response by the U.S. Supreme Court to a political crisis brought on by aggressive judicial review of decisions of the Interstate Commerce Commission. Once the jeny-built model was in place, Congress signaled its approval, and an academic-John Dickinson-wrote a persuasive book extolling its virtues. As a result, the appellate review model became entrenched by the 1920s and eventually spread to all of administrative law. The early adoption of the appellate review model helps explain why the Supreme Court never seriously grappled with Article III problems created by the widespread use of administrative agencies to adjudicate cases once the New Deal and the expansion of the administrative state arrived. It also helps explain why the judiciary has played such a large role in the development of administrative policy in the United States relative to other legal systems. INTRODUCTION . .................................................. 940 I. NINETEENTH-CENTURY BACKGROUND ........................... 946 II. THE EMERGENCE OF THE APPELLATE REVIEW MODEL ........ 953 A. The ICC Crisis ....................................... 953 B. The Hepburn Act .................................... 955 C. Strategic Retreat ..................................... 959 D. The Source of the Appellate Review Model ........... 963 * Charles Evans Hughes Professor of Law, Columbia Law School. The Article has benefited from comments by participants in workshops at Chicago, Columbia, Minnesota, and Vanderbilt Law Schools. Special thanks to Charles McCurdy,Jerry Mashaw, and Henry Monaghan for their interest and input. Brad Lipton and Brantley Webb provided valuable research assistance. Some of the material in this Article appears in abbreviated form in Thomas W. Merrill, The Origins of American Style Judicial Review, in Comparative Administrative Law 389 (Susan Rose-Ackerman & Peter L. Lindseth eds., 2011).
美国行政法是以民事诉讼中上诉法院和初审法院之间的关系为蓝本的审查法院和代理机构之间的关系概念为基础的。这种上诉审查模式并不是行政法的必然基础,但它产生了深远的影响,其起源却鲜为人知。本文详细介绍了上诉审查模式是如何在1906年之后作为美国最高法院对州际商务委员会裁决的激进司法审查所带来的政治危机的临时反应而出现的。一旦珍妮建造的模型就位,国会就表示同意,一位学者——约翰·迪金森——写了一本有说服力的书,颂扬了它的优点。因此,上诉审查模式在20世纪20年代变得根深蒂固,并最终扩展到所有行政法。上诉审查模式的早期采用有助于解释为什么在新政和行政国家的扩张到来后,最高法院从未认真解决因广泛使用行政机构来裁决案件而产生的第三条问题。这也有助于解释为什么相对于其他法律制度,司法机构在美国行政政策的发展中发挥了如此大的作用。介绍 . ..................................................940年即19世纪的背景 ...........................946二世。上诉审查模式的出现........953 A。国际刑事法院的危机 .......................................953 b .赫本法案 ....................................955 c战略退却 .....................................959 D.上诉审查模式的来源...........哥伦比亚大学法学院查尔斯·埃文斯·休斯法学教授。这篇文章得益于芝加哥、哥伦比亚、明尼苏达和范德比尔特法学院研讨会参与者的评论。特别感谢Charles McCurdy,Jerry Mashaw和Henry Monaghan的关心和投入。布拉德·利普顿和布兰特利·韦伯提供了宝贵的研究协助。本文中的一些材料以缩略形式出现在托马斯·w·梅里尔的《美国式司法审查的起源》,《比较行政法》第389期(苏珊·罗斯-阿克曼和彼得·l·林德赛斯主编)。, 2011)。
{"title":"Article III, Agency Adjudication, and the Origins of the Appellate Review Model of Administrative Law","authors":"T. Merrill","doi":"10.7916/D88915DF","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.7916/D88915DF","url":null,"abstract":"American administrative law is grounded in a conception of the relationship between reviewing courts and agencies modeled on the relationship between appeals courts and trial courts in civil litigation. This appellate review model was not an inevitable foundation of administrative law, but it has had far-reaching consequences, and its origins are poorly understood. This Article details how the appellate review model emerged after 1906 as an improvised response by the U.S. Supreme Court to a political crisis brought on by aggressive judicial review of decisions of the Interstate Commerce Commission. Once the jeny-built model was in place, Congress signaled its approval, and an academic-John Dickinson-wrote a persuasive book extolling its virtues. As a result, the appellate review model became entrenched by the 1920s and eventually spread to all of administrative law. The early adoption of the appellate review model helps explain why the Supreme Court never seriously grappled with Article III problems created by the widespread use of administrative agencies to adjudicate cases once the New Deal and the expansion of the administrative state arrived. It also helps explain why the judiciary has played such a large role in the development of administrative policy in the United States relative to other legal systems. INTRODUCTION . .................................................. 940 I. NINETEENTH-CENTURY BACKGROUND ........................... 946 II. THE EMERGENCE OF THE APPELLATE REVIEW MODEL ........ 953 A. The ICC Crisis ....................................... 953 B. The Hepburn Act .................................... 955 C. Strategic Retreat ..................................... 959 D. The Source of the Appellate Review Model ........... 963 * Charles Evans Hughes Professor of Law, Columbia Law School. The Article has benefited from comments by participants in workshops at Chicago, Columbia, Minnesota, and Vanderbilt Law Schools. Special thanks to Charles McCurdy,Jerry Mashaw, and Henry Monaghan for their interest and input. Brad Lipton and Brantley Webb provided valuable research assistance. Some of the material in this Article appears in abbreviated form in Thomas W. Merrill, The Origins of American Style Judicial Review, in Comparative Administrative Law 389 (Susan Rose-Ackerman & Peter L. Lindseth eds., 2011).","PeriodicalId":51408,"journal":{"name":"Columbia Law Review","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":2.9,"publicationDate":"2011-06-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"71364836","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":2,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 32
期刊
Columbia Law Review
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1