首页 > 最新文献

Journal of Theoretical Politics最新文献

英文 中文
Collective agency and positive political theory 集体能动性与积极政治理论
4区 社会学 Q2 Social Sciences Pub Date : 2023-09-20 DOI: 10.1177/09516298231203158
Lars J. K. Moen
Positive political theorists typically deny the possibility of collective agents by understanding aggregation problems to imply that groups are not rational decision-makers. This view contrasts with List and Pettit’s view that such problems actually imply the necessity of accounting for collective agents in explanations of group behaviour. In this paper, I explore these conflicting views and ask whether positive political theorists should alter their individualist analyses of groups like legislatures, political parties, and constituent assemblies. I show how we fail to appreciate the significance of strategic voting and agenda control by treating groups as agents. I, therefore, conclude that positive political theorists should cling to their individualist approach and maintain that groups are not agents.
积极的政治理论家通常否认集体代理人的可能性,通过理解聚集问题来暗示群体不是理性的决策者。这一观点与List和Pettit的观点形成对比,他们认为这些问题实际上意味着在解释群体行为时必须考虑集体行为者。在本文中,我探讨了这些相互矛盾的观点,并询问积极的政治理论家是否应该改变他们对立法机构、政党和制宪会议等群体的个人主义分析。我展示了我们是如何通过将群体视为代理人而忽视了战略投票和议程控制的重要性。因此,我的结论是,积极的政治理论家应该坚持他们的个人主义方法,并坚持群体不是代理人。
{"title":"Collective agency and positive political theory","authors":"Lars J. K. Moen","doi":"10.1177/09516298231203158","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1177/09516298231203158","url":null,"abstract":"Positive political theorists typically deny the possibility of collective agents by understanding aggregation problems to imply that groups are not rational decision-makers. This view contrasts with List and Pettit’s view that such problems actually imply the necessity of accounting for collective agents in explanations of group behaviour. In this paper, I explore these conflicting views and ask whether positive political theorists should alter their individualist analyses of groups like legislatures, political parties, and constituent assemblies. I show how we fail to appreciate the significance of strategic voting and agenda control by treating groups as agents. I, therefore, conclude that positive political theorists should cling to their individualist approach and maintain that groups are not agents.","PeriodicalId":51606,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Theoretical Politics","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2023-09-20","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"136314023","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Decentralized legislative oversight of bureaucratic policy making 对官僚政策制定的分散立法监督
4区 社会学 Q2 Social Sciences Pub Date : 2023-09-20 DOI: 10.1177/09516298231202428
Janna King, Sean Gailmard, Abby Wood
Congressional oversight is a potentially potent tool to affect policy making and implementation by executive agencies. However, oversight of any agency is dispersed among several committees across the House and Senate. How does this decentralization affect the strategic incentives for oversight by each committee? And how do the strategic incentives of oversight committees align with the collective interest of Congress as a whole? We develop a formal, spatial model of decentralized oversight to investigate these questions. The model shows that when committees have similar interests in affecting agency policy, committees attempt to free ride on each other, and oversight levels are inefficiently low. But if committees have competing interests in affecting agency policy, they engage in “dueling oversight” with little overall effect, and oversight levels are inefficiently high. Overall, we contend that committee oversight incentives do not generally align with the collective interests of Congress, and the problem cannot be easily solved by structural changes within a single chamber.
国会监督是影响行政机构政策制定和实施的潜在有力工具。然而,任何机构的监督都分散在众议院和参议院的几个委员会中。这种权力下放如何影响每个委员会监督的战略激励?监督委员会的战略激励如何与国会整体的集体利益保持一致?我们开发了一个正式的、分散监督的空间模型来调查这些问题。该模型表明,当委员会在影响机构政策方面具有相似的利益时,委员会试图相互搭便车,并且监督水平无效地低。但是,如果委员会在影响机构政策方面有相互竞争的利益,他们就会进行“决斗式监督”,而总体效果甚微,而且监督水平也会低效率地高。总的来说,我们认为,委员会的监督激励措施通常与国会的集体利益不一致,这个问题不能通过单一议院的结构改革来轻易解决。
{"title":"Decentralized legislative oversight of bureaucratic policy making","authors":"Janna King, Sean Gailmard, Abby Wood","doi":"10.1177/09516298231202428","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1177/09516298231202428","url":null,"abstract":"Congressional oversight is a potentially potent tool to affect policy making and implementation by executive agencies. However, oversight of any agency is dispersed among several committees across the House and Senate. How does this decentralization affect the strategic incentives for oversight by each committee? And how do the strategic incentives of oversight committees align with the collective interest of Congress as a whole? We develop a formal, spatial model of decentralized oversight to investigate these questions. The model shows that when committees have similar interests in affecting agency policy, committees attempt to free ride on each other, and oversight levels are inefficiently low. But if committees have competing interests in affecting agency policy, they engage in “dueling oversight” with little overall effect, and oversight levels are inefficiently high. Overall, we contend that committee oversight incentives do not generally align with the collective interests of Congress, and the problem cannot be easily solved by structural changes within a single chamber.","PeriodicalId":51606,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Theoretical Politics","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2023-09-20","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"136314450","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Zone defense: Why liberal cities build too few homes 区域防御:为什么自由主义城市建造的房屋太少
IF 1 4区 社会学 Q2 Social Sciences Pub Date : 2023-07-16 DOI: 10.1177/09516298231186604
J. Ornstein
In this article, I investigate a puzzling feature of American urban politics: cities with more liberal residents tend to enact more restrictive zoning policies and permit fewer new housing units each year than similar conservative cities. To help explain this puzzle, I develop a formal model in which local governments regulate the size of their population to balance the benefits of agglomeration with the costs of congestion. To defend against congestion externalities imposed by new residents, cities enact zoning policies that undersupply housing relative to the social optimum. In liberal cities, where residents value the benefits of agglomeration the most, this undersupply of housing is the most severe.
在这篇文章中,我调查了美国城市政治的一个令人困惑的特点:与类似的保守城市相比,居民更自由的城市往往制定更严格的分区政策,每年允许的新住房数量更少。为了帮助解释这个谜题,我开发了一个正式的模型,在这个模型中,地方政府调节其人口规模,以平衡集聚的好处和拥堵的成本。为了抵御新居民带来的拥堵外部性,城市制定了分区政策,使住房供应相对于社会最优水平不足。在自由城市,居民最看重集聚的好处,住房供应不足最为严重。
{"title":"Zone defense: Why liberal cities build too few homes","authors":"J. Ornstein","doi":"10.1177/09516298231186604","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1177/09516298231186604","url":null,"abstract":"In this article, I investigate a puzzling feature of American urban politics: cities with more liberal residents tend to enact more restrictive zoning policies and permit fewer new housing units each year than similar conservative cities. To help explain this puzzle, I develop a formal model in which local governments regulate the size of their population to balance the benefits of agglomeration with the costs of congestion. To defend against congestion externalities imposed by new residents, cities enact zoning policies that undersupply housing relative to the social optimum. In liberal cities, where residents value the benefits of agglomeration the most, this undersupply of housing is the most severe.","PeriodicalId":51606,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Theoretical Politics","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":1.0,"publicationDate":"2023-07-16","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"48096378","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Bayesian explanations for persuasion 说服的贝叶斯解释
IF 1 4区 社会学 Q2 Social Sciences Pub Date : 2023-07-01 DOI: 10.1177/09516298231185060
A. Little
The central puzzle of persuasion is why a receiver would listen to a sender who they know is trying to change their beliefs or behavior. This article summarizes five approaches to solving this puzzle: (1) some messages are easier to send for those with favorable information (costly signaling), (2) the sender and receiver have common interest, (3) the sender messages are verifiable information, (4) the sender cares about their reputation for competence/honesty, and (5) the sender can commit to a messaging strategy (often called ‘Bayesian Persuasion’). After reviewing these approaches with common notation, I discuss which provide insight into prominent empirical findings on campaigns, partisan media, and lobbying. While models focusing on commitment have rapidly become prominent (if not dominant) in the recent theoretical literature on persuasion in political science and economics, the insights they provide are primarily technical, and are not particularly well-suited to explaining most of these phenomena.
说服的核心难题是,为什么接收者会听从发送者的话,而发送者知道发送者正试图改变他们的信仰或行为。本文总结了解决这一难题的五种方法:(1)对于那些拥有有利信息(代价高昂的信号)的人来说,一些消息更容易发送,(2)发送者和接收者有共同的兴趣,(3)发送者的消息是可验证的信息,(4)发送者关心他们的能力/诚实声誉,以及(5)发送者可以采用消息传递策略(通常称为“贝叶斯说服”)。在用通用符号回顾了这些方法后,我讨论了哪些方法可以深入了解竞选、党派媒体和游说方面的突出实证发现。虽然在最近的政治学和经济学说服理论文献中,专注于承诺的模型迅速变得突出(如果不是占主导地位的话),但它们提供的见解主要是技术性的,并不特别适合解释大多数这些现象。
{"title":"Bayesian explanations for persuasion","authors":"A. Little","doi":"10.1177/09516298231185060","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1177/09516298231185060","url":null,"abstract":"The central puzzle of persuasion is why a receiver would listen to a sender who they know is trying to change their beliefs or behavior. This article summarizes five approaches to solving this puzzle: (1) some messages are easier to send for those with favorable information (costly signaling), (2) the sender and receiver have common interest, (3) the sender messages are verifiable information, (4) the sender cares about their reputation for competence/honesty, and (5) the sender can commit to a messaging strategy (often called ‘Bayesian Persuasion’). After reviewing these approaches with common notation, I discuss which provide insight into prominent empirical findings on campaigns, partisan media, and lobbying. While models focusing on commitment have rapidly become prominent (if not dominant) in the recent theoretical literature on persuasion in political science and economics, the insights they provide are primarily technical, and are not particularly well-suited to explaining most of these phenomena.","PeriodicalId":51606,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Theoretical Politics","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":1.0,"publicationDate":"2023-07-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"43465281","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2
Mowing the grass 割草
IF 1 4区 社会学 Q2 Social Sciences Pub Date : 2023-07-01 DOI: 10.1177/09516298231185113
Michael B. Gibilisco
Mowing the grass is a cyclical pattern in counterterrorism campaigns where governments attack to destroy terrorist capacity, thereby achieving a period of quiet as groups recover. If groups expect their capacity to be destroyed, why build their capabilities in the first place? I analyze an infinite-horizon dynamic game where a group endogenously builds capacity in the face of potential attacks and capacity is an evolving, persistent variable. The model highlights that terrorist groups and governments have incentives to create strategic uncertainty and thus explains attack cycles without punishment strategies, revenge preferences or imperfect/incomplete information. I calibrate the model to time-series data in the Israeli–Palestinian conflict describing rockets fired from Gaza. The results illustrate a peace-making dilemma: altering the government’s incentives will have comparatively minimal effects on long-term conflict dynamics, whereas changing the terrorists’ incentives to acquire capacity would either increase the frequency of high-capacity terrorism or government attacks.
在反恐运动中,“割草”是一种周期性模式,即政府发动袭击,摧毁恐怖分子的能力,从而在恐怖组织恢复的过程中获得一段时间的平静。如果团体期望他们的能力被摧毁,为什么要首先建立他们的能力?我分析了一个无限视界动态博弈,在这个博弈中,一个群体在面对潜在攻击时内生地建立能力,而能力是一个不断进化的、持久的变量。该模型强调,恐怖组织和政府有创造战略不确定性的动机,因此在没有惩罚策略、报复偏好或不完全/不完整信息的情况下解释了攻击周期。我根据巴以冲突中的时间序列数据校准模型,这些数据描述了从加沙发射的火箭弹。研究结果说明了一个促成和平的困境:改变政府的激励措施对长期冲突动态的影响相对较小,而改变恐怖分子获取能力的激励措施,要么会增加高容量恐怖主义的频率,要么会增加政府袭击的频率。
{"title":"Mowing the grass","authors":"Michael B. Gibilisco","doi":"10.1177/09516298231185113","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1177/09516298231185113","url":null,"abstract":"Mowing the grass is a cyclical pattern in counterterrorism campaigns where governments attack to destroy terrorist capacity, thereby achieving a period of quiet as groups recover. If groups expect their capacity to be destroyed, why build their capabilities in the first place? I analyze an infinite-horizon dynamic game where a group endogenously builds capacity in the face of potential attacks and capacity is an evolving, persistent variable. The model highlights that terrorist groups and governments have incentives to create strategic uncertainty and thus explains attack cycles without punishment strategies, revenge preferences or imperfect/incomplete information. I calibrate the model to time-series data in the Israeli–Palestinian conflict describing rockets fired from Gaza. The results illustrate a peace-making dilemma: altering the government’s incentives will have comparatively minimal effects on long-term conflict dynamics, whereas changing the terrorists’ incentives to acquire capacity would either increase the frequency of high-capacity terrorism or government attacks.","PeriodicalId":51606,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Theoretical Politics","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":1.0,"publicationDate":"2023-07-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"44367635","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Talking to the enemy: Explaining the emergence of peace talks in interstate war 与敌人对话:解释国家间战争中和平谈判的出现
IF 1 4区 社会学 Q2 Social Sciences Pub Date : 2023-07-01 DOI: 10.1177/09516298231185112
O. Mastro, David A. Siegel
Why are some states open to talking while fighting while others are not? We argue that a state considering opening negotiations is concerned not only with the adverse inference that the opposing state will draw, but also the actions that the opposing state might take in response to that inference. We use a formal model, with assumptions grounded in extensive historical evidence, to highlight one particular response to opening negotiations—the escalation of war efforts—and one particular characteristic of the state opening negotiations—its resilience to escalation. We find that states are willing to open negotiations under two conditions: when their opponents find escalation too costly, and when there is a signal of high resilience that only the highly resilient care to use. To illustrate the dynamics of the second condition, we offer an extended case study detailing North Vietnam’s changing approach to negotiations during the Vietnam War.
为什么有些国家愿意边谈边打,而另一些国家却不愿意?我们认为,一个考虑开启谈判的国家不仅要考虑对方将得出的不利推论,还要考虑对方可能针对该推论采取的行动。我们使用一个正式的模型,以广泛的历史证据为基础的假设,来强调对开放谈判的一种特殊反应——战争努力的升级——以及国家开放谈判的一个特殊特征——对升级的弹性。我们发现,各国愿意在两种情况下展开谈判:当对手发现升级代价太大时,以及当有高弹性的信号时,只有高弹性的国家才愿意使用。为了说明第二个条件的动态,我们提供了一个扩展的案例研究,详细说明了北越在越南战争期间不断变化的谈判方法。
{"title":"Talking to the enemy: Explaining the emergence of peace talks in interstate war","authors":"O. Mastro, David A. Siegel","doi":"10.1177/09516298231185112","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1177/09516298231185112","url":null,"abstract":"Why are some states open to talking while fighting while others are not? We argue that a state considering opening negotiations is concerned not only with the adverse inference that the opposing state will draw, but also the actions that the opposing state might take in response to that inference. We use a formal model, with assumptions grounded in extensive historical evidence, to highlight one particular response to opening negotiations—the escalation of war efforts—and one particular characteristic of the state opening negotiations—its resilience to escalation. We find that states are willing to open negotiations under two conditions: when their opponents find escalation too costly, and when there is a signal of high resilience that only the highly resilient care to use. To illustrate the dynamics of the second condition, we offer an extended case study detailing North Vietnam’s changing approach to negotiations during the Vietnam War.","PeriodicalId":51606,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Theoretical Politics","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":1.0,"publicationDate":"2023-07-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"42030844","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Indirect rule and mass threat: Two paths to direct rule 间接统治与大规模威胁:通往直接统治的两条道路
IF 1 4区 社会学 Q2 Social Sciences Pub Date : 2023-06-23 DOI: 10.1177/09516298231183640
Benjamin Broman
What is the impact of popular discontent on the transition from indirect to direct rule? The current literature suggests contrasting theories, variously arguing that rulers are more likely to govern directly when facing either a particularly high or particularly low probability of mass resistance. I reconcile these views by arguing that the decision to rule indirectly is subject to competing dilemmas. In a formal model, I show that these twin tensions influence the choice to centralize power in opposing manners. Accordingly, there are two distinct political logics driving direct rule: one resulting from a high likelihood of revolt and the other from a low likelihood, with contrasting comparative statics. The model therefore reconciles contrasting views in the literature. I illustrate the model's logic with reference to key cases and provide heuristics for predicting comparative statics in new empirical settings.
民众不满对从间接统治向直接统治过渡的影响是什么?目前的文献提出了对比鲜明的理论,各种各样的观点认为,当统治者面临特别高或特别低的大规模抵抗概率时,他们更有可能直接执政。我调和了这些观点,认为间接统治的决定受制于相互竞争的困境。在一个正式的模型中,我表明,这两种紧张关系会影响以相反的方式集中权力的选择。因此,有两种不同的政治逻辑驱动着直接统治:一种是由叛乱的高可能性产生的,另一种是从低可能性产生的。因此,该模型调和了文献中对比鲜明的观点。我参考关键案例说明了模型的逻辑,并为在新的经验环境中预测比较静态提供了启发。
{"title":"Indirect rule and mass threat: Two paths to direct rule","authors":"Benjamin Broman","doi":"10.1177/09516298231183640","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1177/09516298231183640","url":null,"abstract":"What is the impact of popular discontent on the transition from indirect to direct rule? The current literature suggests contrasting theories, variously arguing that rulers are more likely to govern directly when facing either a particularly high or particularly low probability of mass resistance. I reconcile these views by arguing that the decision to rule indirectly is subject to competing dilemmas. In a formal model, I show that these twin tensions influence the choice to centralize power in opposing manners. Accordingly, there are two distinct political logics driving direct rule: one resulting from a high likelihood of revolt and the other from a low likelihood, with contrasting comparative statics. The model therefore reconciles contrasting views in the literature. I illustrate the model's logic with reference to key cases and provide heuristics for predicting comparative statics in new empirical settings.","PeriodicalId":51606,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Theoretical Politics","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":1.0,"publicationDate":"2023-06-23","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"47122863","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Access to justice in revenue-seeking legal institutions 在寻求收入的法律机构中诉诸司法
IF 1 4区 社会学 Q2 Social Sciences Pub Date : 2023-03-22 DOI: 10.1177/09516298231162040
H. Simpson
Legal bias against the poor, and competition from nonstate legal services providers, can both seriously affect state justice provision. But analyses of these factors often fail to incorporate a critical feature of justice systems: states use them for revenue generation. I build a series of formal models to understand how these factors interact. I derive several insights into empirical patterns of bias, competition, access to justice, and legal system viability. First, in poor countries, bias can increase access to justice and legal effectiveness. Second, given competition, poor groups will pay a premium for state-provided justice, while wealthy groups will pay a premium for private dispute resolution. However, losing a poor group to competition is also less costly than losing a wealthy group, and the latter loss can sometimes destroy the viability of the state justice system. These results contribute to our understanding of state capacity and rule of law development.
对穷人的法律偏见和非国家法律服务提供者的竞争都会严重影响国家司法的提供。但对这些因素的分析往往没有纳入司法系统的一个关键特征:各州利用它们来创收。我建立了一系列正式的模型来了解这些因素是如何相互作用的。我对偏见、竞争、诉诸司法和法律制度可行性的经验模式有一些见解。首先,在贫穷国家,偏见会增加诉诸司法的机会和法律效力。其次,考虑到竞争,贫困群体将为国家提供的正义支付溢价,而富裕群体将为私人纠纷解决支付溢价。然而,在竞争中失去一个贫穷群体的成本也比失去一个富裕群体低,而后者的损失有时会破坏国家司法系统的生存能力。这些结果有助于我们理解国家能力和法治发展。
{"title":"Access to justice in revenue-seeking legal institutions","authors":"H. Simpson","doi":"10.1177/09516298231162040","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1177/09516298231162040","url":null,"abstract":"Legal bias against the poor, and competition from nonstate legal services providers, can both seriously affect state justice provision. But analyses of these factors often fail to incorporate a critical feature of justice systems: states use them for revenue generation. I build a series of formal models to understand how these factors interact. I derive several insights into empirical patterns of bias, competition, access to justice, and legal system viability. First, in poor countries, bias can increase access to justice and legal effectiveness. Second, given competition, poor groups will pay a premium for state-provided justice, while wealthy groups will pay a premium for private dispute resolution. However, losing a poor group to competition is also less costly than losing a wealthy group, and the latter loss can sometimes destroy the viability of the state justice system. These results contribute to our understanding of state capacity and rule of law development.","PeriodicalId":51606,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Theoretical Politics","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":1.0,"publicationDate":"2023-03-22","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"41667632","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
The political economy of noncompliance in customs unions 关税同盟中不服从的政治经济学
IF 1 4区 社会学 Q2 Social Sciences Pub Date : 2022-10-18 DOI: 10.1177/09516298221130262
Joshua C. Fjelstul
States create customs unions to accrue consumer welfare gains. Given the incentives to cheat to protect domestic firms from foreign competition, they create regulatory regimes with international courts to manage noncompliance. I develop a formal model that explains how the politics of compliance in regulatory regimes systematically distorts the welfare gains that states accrue from developing customs unions. The model predicts that regulatory regimes are most effective at enforcing compliance (i.e., at reducing trade barriers) in industries with intermediate levels of firm homogeneity in terms of productivity. In highly homogenous industries, regulatory regimes are not effective because noncompliance is minimal enough that litigation is not cost-effective; in highly heterogenous industries, regulatory regimes are not effective because courts, concerned about noncompliance with their rulings, are unlikely to rule against the defendants, deterring the plaintiffs from bringing cases. The model also predicts the downstream consequences for the performance of individual firms and consumer welfare.
各国建立关税同盟以积累消费者福利收益。考虑到为了保护国内公司免受外国竞争而作弊的动机,他们建立了由国际法院管理违规行为的监管制度。我开发了一个正式模型,解释了监管制度中的合规政治如何系统性地扭曲了各国从发展中关税同盟中获得的福利收益。该模型预测,监管制度在强制遵守(即减少贸易壁垒)方面最有效,在生产率方面具有中等水平的企业同质性。在高度同质化的行业中,监管制度并不有效,因为违规行为极少,诉讼不具有成本效益;在高度异质的行业中,监管制度并不有效,因为法院担心不遵守其裁决,不太可能做出不利于被告的裁决,从而阻止原告提起诉讼。该模型还预测了个别企业绩效和消费者福利的下游后果。
{"title":"The political economy of noncompliance in customs unions","authors":"Joshua C. Fjelstul","doi":"10.1177/09516298221130262","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1177/09516298221130262","url":null,"abstract":"States create customs unions to accrue consumer welfare gains. Given the incentives to cheat to protect domestic firms from foreign competition, they create regulatory regimes with international courts to manage noncompliance. I develop a formal model that explains how the politics of compliance in regulatory regimes systematically distorts the welfare gains that states accrue from developing customs unions. The model predicts that regulatory regimes are most effective at enforcing compliance (i.e., at reducing trade barriers) in industries with intermediate levels of firm homogeneity in terms of productivity. In highly homogenous industries, regulatory regimes are not effective because noncompliance is minimal enough that litigation is not cost-effective; in highly heterogenous industries, regulatory regimes are not effective because courts, concerned about noncompliance with their rulings, are unlikely to rule against the defendants, deterring the plaintiffs from bringing cases. The model also predicts the downstream consequences for the performance of individual firms and consumer welfare.","PeriodicalId":51606,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Theoretical Politics","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":1.0,"publicationDate":"2022-10-18","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"46700941","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Ideological sorting 意识形态分类
IF 1 4区 社会学 Q2 Social Sciences Pub Date : 2022-10-18 DOI: 10.1177/09516298221130261
D. Baron
This paper presents a model in which people sort between two districts based on economic and ideological preferences. People are either ideologues who prefer redistribution over a public good or non-ideologues who prefer a public good that benefits everyone equally. Individuals differ in their productivity with the distribution of productivities the same for both ideologues and non-ideologues. Ideologues back their ideology by working harder when there is redistribution even when not recipients, and non-ideologues work harder when the public good is provided. The tax rate in each district is chosen by majority rule with the median voter theorem identifying the winner. In the focal equilibrium, high productivity ideologues and non-ideologues locate together in a low tax district, and low productivity non-ideologues and ideologues locate together in a high tax district to benefit from redistribution. Middle-income individuals separate with non-ideologues locating in the low tax district and ideologues locating in the high tax district. Ideology thus results in a polarization interval in the middle of the income distribution. If ideology leads to partisanship and a strong party government that chooses the tax rate based on the party median, partisanship widens the polarization interval.
本文提出了一个模型,在这个模型中,人们根据经济和意识形态偏好在两个地区之间进行排序。人们要么是倾向于再分配而不是公共利益的空想家,要么是非空想家,他们倾向于每个人都能平等受益的公共利益。个人的生产力是不同的,而意识形态和非意识形态的生产力分配是相同的。即使不是接受者,如果有再分配,理论家也会更加努力地支持自己的意识形态;如果有公共利益,非理论家也会更加努力。每个地区的税率由多数决原则选择,中间选民定理确定获胜者。在焦点均衡中,高生产率的理论家和非理论家共同居住在低税区,而低生产率的非理论家和理论家共同居住在高税区,以从再分配中获益。中等收入人群与居住在低税地区的非意识形态人群和居住在高税地区的意识形态人群分开。因此,意识形态导致了收入分配中间的两极分化区间。如果意识形态导致党派之争,并形成一个根据党派中间值选择税率的强大的政党政府,党派之争就会扩大两极分化的间隔。
{"title":"Ideological sorting","authors":"D. Baron","doi":"10.1177/09516298221130261","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1177/09516298221130261","url":null,"abstract":"This paper presents a model in which people sort between two districts based on economic and ideological preferences. People are either ideologues who prefer redistribution over a public good or non-ideologues who prefer a public good that benefits everyone equally. Individuals differ in their productivity with the distribution of productivities the same for both ideologues and non-ideologues. Ideologues back their ideology by working harder when there is redistribution even when not recipients, and non-ideologues work harder when the public good is provided. The tax rate in each district is chosen by majority rule with the median voter theorem identifying the winner. In the focal equilibrium, high productivity ideologues and non-ideologues locate together in a low tax district, and low productivity non-ideologues and ideologues locate together in a high tax district to benefit from redistribution. Middle-income individuals separate with non-ideologues locating in the low tax district and ideologues locating in the high tax district. Ideology thus results in a polarization interval in the middle of the income distribution. If ideology leads to partisanship and a strong party government that chooses the tax rate based on the party median, partisanship widens the polarization interval.","PeriodicalId":51606,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Theoretical Politics","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":1.0,"publicationDate":"2022-10-18","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"46881811","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
期刊
Journal of Theoretical Politics
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1