首页 > 最新文献

Economic History of Developing Regions最新文献

英文 中文
South Africa’s 2003–2013 credit boom and bust: Lessons for macroprudential policy 南非2003-2013年的信贷繁荣与萧条:宏观审慎政策的教训
IF 0.5 Q1 HISTORY Pub Date : 2021-05-04 DOI: 10.1080/20780389.2021.1938532
H. Hollander, R. Havemann
ABSTRACT We evaluate South African financial stability policy from 2003 to 2013 – the country’s most significant credit boom and bust cycle. This cycle overlapped with both rising bank capital adequacy ratios and the global financial crisis of 2007/8. We use a dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model to identify South African Reserve Bank (SARB) interventions and run counterfactual policy scenarios. We document two instances of policy inaction. Our counterfactual scenarios suggest that, with the benefit of hindsight, the SARB took the correct steps to raise capital requirements during the credit boom, but could have persisted with raising capital requirements for longer (past 2004), and could have adopted a looser policy stance after the global financial crisis to mitigate the credit bust. Our findings reaffirm the importance of counter-cyclical action, the usefulness of bank capital as a buffer against unexpected shocks to build financial sector resilience, and the need for independent but close coordination between monetary and macroprudential policy. In addition, because of structural differences between household and firm credit, the SARB should consider buttressing the uniform countercyclical capital buffer with sector-specific capital requirements.
摘要我们评估了南非2003年至2013年的金融稳定政策,这是该国最重要的信贷繁荣和萧条周期。这一周期与银行资本充足率上升和2007/8年全球金融危机重叠。我们使用动态随机一般均衡模型来确定南非储备银行(SARB)的干预措施,并运行反事实政策情景。我们记录了两个政策不作为的例子。我们的反事实情景表明,事后来看,特区政府在信贷繁荣期间采取了正确的措施来提高资本要求,但本可以在更长时间内(2004年之后)坚持提高资本要求;在全球金融危机后,本可以采取更宽松的政策立场来缓解信贷紧缩。我们的研究结果重申了反周期行动的重要性,银行资本作为缓冲意外冲击的有用性,以建立金融部门的韧性,以及货币政策和宏观审慎政策之间独立但密切协调的必要性。此外,由于家庭信贷和企业信贷之间的结构差异,SARB应考虑通过特定行业的资本要求来支持统一的反周期资本缓冲。
{"title":"South Africa’s 2003–2013 credit boom and bust: Lessons for macroprudential policy","authors":"H. Hollander, R. Havemann","doi":"10.1080/20780389.2021.1938532","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1080/20780389.2021.1938532","url":null,"abstract":"ABSTRACT We evaluate South African financial stability policy from 2003 to 2013 – the country’s most significant credit boom and bust cycle. This cycle overlapped with both rising bank capital adequacy ratios and the global financial crisis of 2007/8. We use a dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model to identify South African Reserve Bank (SARB) interventions and run counterfactual policy scenarios. We document two instances of policy inaction. Our counterfactual scenarios suggest that, with the benefit of hindsight, the SARB took the correct steps to raise capital requirements during the credit boom, but could have persisted with raising capital requirements for longer (past 2004), and could have adopted a looser policy stance after the global financial crisis to mitigate the credit bust. Our findings reaffirm the importance of counter-cyclical action, the usefulness of bank capital as a buffer against unexpected shocks to build financial sector resilience, and the need for independent but close coordination between monetary and macroprudential policy. In addition, because of structural differences between household and firm credit, the SARB should consider buttressing the uniform countercyclical capital buffer with sector-specific capital requirements.","PeriodicalId":54115,"journal":{"name":"Economic History of Developing Regions","volume":"36 1","pages":"339 - 365"},"PeriodicalIF":0.5,"publicationDate":"2021-05-04","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1080/20780389.2021.1938532","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"46079750","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 4
Professor Vishnu Padayachee, 1952–2021 Vishnu Padayachee教授,1952–2021
IF 0.5 Q1 HISTORY Pub Date : 2021-05-04 DOI: 10.1080/20780389.2021.1940490
Bradley Bordiss, J. Rossouw
On Saturday, the 29 May 2021, the sad news came that Vishnu Padayachee, a dear friend and mentor, had died after a year-long illness. Mahavishnu (Vishnu) Padayachee was born in Umkomaas and commenced his studies at the University of Durban-Westville. He completed a PhD in economics at the University of Natal in 1990. Vishnu was a key member of the ANC’s Macro-economic Research Group (MERG) which proposed a Structuralist and Post-Keynesian approach to economic policy, and which recognized effective demand failures and unemployment as key problems in South Africa. The ANC’s abandonment of this approach in favour of a neoliberal one disappointed him deeply. His long academic career began with a Junior Lectureship in economics at the University of Durban-Westville and ended with him becoming the holder of the Derek Schrier and Cecily Cameron Chair in Development Economics at the University of the Witwatersrand. He also held a lifetime Fellowship at Johns Hopkins University in Washington, D.C. and an honorary doctorate in economics conferred on him in 2018 by Rhodes University. As an academic and researcher, Vishnu was widely cited, being known for his research in economics, economic history, economic transformation, and development. He was the author or co-author of 10 books and monographs, numerous book chapters, and over a hundred journal articles. Vishnu regularly spoke at local and international conferences and made important contributions to public debates. Vishnu was not just an academic, and had many other interests and hobbies. He enjoyed, and wrote a book on cricket in South Africa. He was a book collector and dealer, and co-owner of the legendary Ike’s Books and Collectables in Durban. In 1996, Vishnu was appointed a non-executive Director of the SA Reserve Bank and served in this capacity for 12 years. This appointment further stimulated his interest developed in MERG and contributed to his vast knowledge of central banking in general and the SA Reserve Bank in particular. Future generations of scholars will continue to benefit from his work in this field. Economics is a discipline in which dogmas and articles of faith abound. Supervisors who can lift themselves above their own articles of faith are regrettably rare. Although Vishnu’s main intellectual influences were heterodox, especially Marx and Keynes, he had no difficulty supervising neo-classical scholars working on topics he found interesting. He did not just bring tolerant eclecticism to his supervisions, he bought immense energy and enthusiasm. After hearing of an archive that had not yet been plumbed by
2021年5月29日星期六,一个悲伤的消息传来,亲爱的朋友和导师Vishnu Padayachee在患病一年后去世。Mahavishnu(Vishnu)Padayachee出生于乌姆科玛斯,在德班韦斯特维尔大学开始学习。1990年,他在纳塔尔大学获得经济学博士学位。Vishnu是非国大宏观经济研究小组(MERG)的关键成员,该小组提出了结构主义和后凯恩斯主义的经济政策方法,并认识到有效需求失败和失业是南非的关键问题。非国大放弃了这种做法,转而支持新自由主义,这让他深感失望。他漫长的学术生涯始于德班威斯特维尔大学经济学初级讲师,最终成为威特沃特斯兰德大学发展经济学Derek Schrier和Cecily Cameron主席。他还在华盛顿特区的约翰霍普金斯大学获得终身奖学金,并于2018年获得罗兹大学授予的经济学荣誉博士学位。作为一名学者和研究员,毗湿奴被广泛引用,以其在经济学、经济史、经济转型和发展方面的研究而闻名。他是10本书和专著的作者或合著者,许多书籍章节和100多篇期刊文章。毗湿奴定期在地方和国际会议上发言,并为公开辩论做出重要贡献。毗湿奴不仅仅是一个学者,还有许多其他的兴趣和爱好。他很喜欢,并写了一本关于南非板球的书。他是一名图书收藏家和经销商,也是德班传奇的艾克图书和收藏品的共同所有者。1996年,Vishnu被任命为南非储备银行的非执行董事,并在该职位上任职12年。这一任命进一步激发了他对MERG的兴趣,并有助于他对中央银行,特别是南非储备银行的广泛了解。未来几代学者将继续受益于他在这一领域的工作。经济学是一门充满教条和信条的学科。令人遗憾的是,能够超越自己信条的监管者并不多见。尽管毗湿奴的主要思想影响是异端,尤其是马克思和凯恩斯,但他毫不困难地监督新古典主义学者研究他感兴趣的主题。他不仅为自己的监督带来了宽容的折衷主义,他还带来了巨大的活力和热情。在听说一个尚未被调查的档案后
{"title":"Professor Vishnu Padayachee, 1952–2021","authors":"Bradley Bordiss, J. Rossouw","doi":"10.1080/20780389.2021.1940490","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1080/20780389.2021.1940490","url":null,"abstract":"On Saturday, the 29 May 2021, the sad news came that Vishnu Padayachee, a dear friend and mentor, had died after a year-long illness. Mahavishnu (Vishnu) Padayachee was born in Umkomaas and commenced his studies at the University of Durban-Westville. He completed a PhD in economics at the University of Natal in 1990. Vishnu was a key member of the ANC’s Macro-economic Research Group (MERG) which proposed a Structuralist and Post-Keynesian approach to economic policy, and which recognized effective demand failures and unemployment as key problems in South Africa. The ANC’s abandonment of this approach in favour of a neoliberal one disappointed him deeply. His long academic career began with a Junior Lectureship in economics at the University of Durban-Westville and ended with him becoming the holder of the Derek Schrier and Cecily Cameron Chair in Development Economics at the University of the Witwatersrand. He also held a lifetime Fellowship at Johns Hopkins University in Washington, D.C. and an honorary doctorate in economics conferred on him in 2018 by Rhodes University. As an academic and researcher, Vishnu was widely cited, being known for his research in economics, economic history, economic transformation, and development. He was the author or co-author of 10 books and monographs, numerous book chapters, and over a hundred journal articles. Vishnu regularly spoke at local and international conferences and made important contributions to public debates. Vishnu was not just an academic, and had many other interests and hobbies. He enjoyed, and wrote a book on cricket in South Africa. He was a book collector and dealer, and co-owner of the legendary Ike’s Books and Collectables in Durban. In 1996, Vishnu was appointed a non-executive Director of the SA Reserve Bank and served in this capacity for 12 years. This appointment further stimulated his interest developed in MERG and contributed to his vast knowledge of central banking in general and the SA Reserve Bank in particular. Future generations of scholars will continue to benefit from his work in this field. Economics is a discipline in which dogmas and articles of faith abound. Supervisors who can lift themselves above their own articles of faith are regrettably rare. Although Vishnu’s main intellectual influences were heterodox, especially Marx and Keynes, he had no difficulty supervising neo-classical scholars working on topics he found interesting. He did not just bring tolerant eclecticism to his supervisions, he bought immense energy and enthusiasm. After hearing of an archive that had not yet been plumbed by","PeriodicalId":54115,"journal":{"name":"Economic History of Developing Regions","volume":"36 1","pages":"122 - 123"},"PeriodicalIF":0.5,"publicationDate":"2021-05-04","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"49367490","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
The fuel of unparalleled recovery: Monetary policy in South Africa between 1925 and 1936 空前复苏的燃料:1925年至1936年间南非的货币政策
IF 0.5 Q1 HISTORY Pub Date : 2021-05-04 DOI: 10.1080/20780389.2021.1945436
C. Swanepoel, Philip T. Fliers
ABSTRACT The newly established South African Reserve Bank (SARB) was tasked to protect the currency by navigating the interwar gold standard, and, from March 1933, maintaining parity with the Pound Sterling. We find that South Africa’s exit from gold secured an unparalleled and rapid recovery from the Great Depression. South Africa’s exit was accompanied by an inextricable link of the SARB’s policy rate to the interest rate set by the Bank of England (BoE). This sacrifice of independent monetary policy allowed the SARB to fix the country’s exchange rate without impeding the flow of gold to London. The SARB fuelled the economy by reducing its policy rates and accumulating gold. Had South Africa not devalued, the country would have suffered a severe depression and persistent deflation. An alternative to the devaluation was for the SARB to pursue a cheap money strategy. By setting interest rates historically low, we find that South Africa could have achieved higher levels of economic growth, at the cost of higher inflation. Ultimately, South Africa’s unparalleled recovery can be ascribed to the devaluation; however the change in the SARB monetary policy and the bank’s control over the gold markets were of paramount importance.
摘要新成立的南非储备银行(SARB)的任务是通过驾驭两次世界大战之间的金本位制来保护货币,并从1933年3月起保持与英镑的平价。我们发现,南非退出黄金市场确保了其从大萧条中无与伦比的快速复苏。南非的退出伴随着南非特别行政区银行的政策利率与英格兰银行(BoE)设定的利率之间不可分割的联系。这种对独立货币政策的牺牲使SARB能够在不阻碍黄金流入伦敦的情况下固定国家汇率。特区政府通过降低政策利率和积累黄金来刺激经济。如果南非没有贬值,该国将遭受严重的萧条和持续的通货紧缩。货币贬值的另一种选择是,特区政府采取廉价货币策略。通过将利率设定在历史低位,我们发现南非本可以以更高的通货膨胀为代价实现更高水平的经济增长。归根结底,南非无与伦比的复苏可以归因于货币贬值;然而,特区银行货币政策的变化和该行对黄金市场的控制至关重要。
{"title":"The fuel of unparalleled recovery: Monetary policy in South Africa between 1925 and 1936","authors":"C. Swanepoel, Philip T. Fliers","doi":"10.1080/20780389.2021.1945436","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1080/20780389.2021.1945436","url":null,"abstract":"ABSTRACT The newly established South African Reserve Bank (SARB) was tasked to protect the currency by navigating the interwar gold standard, and, from March 1933, maintaining parity with the Pound Sterling. We find that South Africa’s exit from gold secured an unparalleled and rapid recovery from the Great Depression. South Africa’s exit was accompanied by an inextricable link of the SARB’s policy rate to the interest rate set by the Bank of England (BoE). This sacrifice of independent monetary policy allowed the SARB to fix the country’s exchange rate without impeding the flow of gold to London. The SARB fuelled the economy by reducing its policy rates and accumulating gold. Had South Africa not devalued, the country would have suffered a severe depression and persistent deflation. An alternative to the devaluation was for the SARB to pursue a cheap money strategy. By setting interest rates historically low, we find that South Africa could have achieved higher levels of economic growth, at the cost of higher inflation. Ultimately, South Africa’s unparalleled recovery can be ascribed to the devaluation; however the change in the SARB monetary policy and the bank’s control over the gold markets were of paramount importance.","PeriodicalId":54115,"journal":{"name":"Economic History of Developing Regions","volume":"36 1","pages":"213 - 244"},"PeriodicalIF":0.5,"publicationDate":"2021-05-04","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"47862283","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2
One hundred years of private shareholding in the South African Reserve Bank 南非储备银行100年的私人股权
IF 0.5 Q1 HISTORY Pub Date : 2021-05-04 DOI: 10.1080/20780389.2021.1923399
C. Vermeulen
ABSTRACT The South African Reserve Bank (SARB) is one of only nine central banks around the world with private shareholders. This paper contributes to the understanding of this ownership arrangement by outlining the history and evolution of private shareholding in the SARB since its inception in 1921 to the present day. It considers the reasons for shares having been issued to establish the SARB, and changes in legislation which influenced the SARB’s ownership structure and the roles and responsibilities of the Board of Directors, shareholders and shareholder-elected directors. It also considers some earlier calls for the SARB to be nationalized. The historical overview shows that executive power has always rested with government appointees, while the government has gradually gained more control – relative to private shareholders – over the Board. This paper also confirms that – with respect to monetary policy – ownership of the SARB is purely notional. The SARB’s policy goals and executive powers are derived directly from the government and the Constitution, and neither the shareholders nor the directors appointed by shareholders have a say in the SARB’s mandate, its policy goals, or the conduct of monetary policy. The role of shareholders is limited to matters of corporate governance only.
摘要南非储备银行是世界上仅有的九家拥有私人股东的中央银行之一。本文概述了自1921年成立至今私人持股的历史和演变,有助于理解这种所有权安排。它考虑了为成立SARB而发行股票的原因,以及影响SARB所有权结构的立法变化,以及董事会、股东和股东选举产生的董事的角色和责任。它还考虑了早些时候要求将广电总局国有化的一些呼吁。历史概况显示,行政权力一直掌握在政府任命的人员手中,而相对于私人股东,政府逐渐获得了对董事会的更多控制权。本文还证实,就货币政策而言,特区银行的所有权纯粹是名义上的。特区政府的政策目标和行政权力直接来自政府和宪法,股东和股东任命的董事对特区政府的任务、政策目标或货币政策的实施都没有发言权。股东的作用仅限于公司治理问题。
{"title":"One hundred years of private shareholding in the South African Reserve Bank","authors":"C. Vermeulen","doi":"10.1080/20780389.2021.1923399","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1080/20780389.2021.1923399","url":null,"abstract":"ABSTRACT The South African Reserve Bank (SARB) is one of only nine central banks around the world with private shareholders. This paper contributes to the understanding of this ownership arrangement by outlining the history and evolution of private shareholding in the SARB since its inception in 1921 to the present day. It considers the reasons for shares having been issued to establish the SARB, and changes in legislation which influenced the SARB’s ownership structure and the roles and responsibilities of the Board of Directors, shareholders and shareholder-elected directors. It also considers some earlier calls for the SARB to be nationalized. The historical overview shows that executive power has always rested with government appointees, while the government has gradually gained more control – relative to private shareholders – over the Board. This paper also confirms that – with respect to monetary policy – ownership of the SARB is purely notional. The SARB’s policy goals and executive powers are derived directly from the government and the Constitution, and neither the shareholders nor the directors appointed by shareholders have a say in the SARB’s mandate, its policy goals, or the conduct of monetary policy. The role of shareholders is limited to matters of corporate governance only.","PeriodicalId":54115,"journal":{"name":"Economic History of Developing Regions","volume":"36 1","pages":"245 - 263"},"PeriodicalIF":0.5,"publicationDate":"2021-05-04","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1080/20780389.2021.1923399","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"46595772","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
A tale of paper and gold: The material history of money in South Africa 纸与黄金的故事:南非货币的物质历史
IF 0.5 Q1 HISTORY Pub Date : 2021-05-04 DOI: 10.1080/20780389.2021.1926232
E. Feingold, J. Fourie, Leigh Gardner
ABSTRACT This paper uses the South African objects in the National Numismatic Collection of the Smithsonian to tell a new material history of money in South Africa. In other parts of the continent, research about the currencies in use and how these changed over time have offered a new perspective on the impact of colonialism, commercialization, and the rise of state capacity. South Africa, and southern Africa more generally, has remained on the periphery of these debates. This paper begins to fill this gap. It shows that even in Africa’s most financially developed region, the process of establishing a stable national currency was long and halting, reflecting struggles over South Africa’s relationship with the global economy and the rise and fall of apartheid.
摘要本文以史密森学会国家钱币收藏馆中的南非实物为例,讲述了南非货币的新物质历史。在非洲大陆的其他地区,对使用中的货币以及这些货币如何随着时间的推移而变化的研究,为殖民主义、商业化和国家能力的提高的影响提供了一个新的视角。南非,以及更普遍的南部非洲,一直处于这些辩论的边缘。本文开始填补这一空白。这表明,即使在非洲金融最发达的地区,建立稳定的国家货币的过程也是漫长而停滞的,这反映出南非与全球经济的关系以及种族隔离制度的兴衰。
{"title":"A tale of paper and gold: The material history of money in South Africa","authors":"E. Feingold, J. Fourie, Leigh Gardner","doi":"10.1080/20780389.2021.1926232","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1080/20780389.2021.1926232","url":null,"abstract":"ABSTRACT This paper uses the South African objects in the National Numismatic Collection of the Smithsonian to tell a new material history of money in South Africa. In other parts of the continent, research about the currencies in use and how these changed over time have offered a new perspective on the impact of colonialism, commercialization, and the rise of state capacity. South Africa, and southern Africa more generally, has remained on the periphery of these debates. This paper begins to fill this gap. It shows that even in Africa’s most financially developed region, the process of establishing a stable national currency was long and halting, reflecting struggles over South Africa’s relationship with the global economy and the rise and fall of apartheid.","PeriodicalId":54115,"journal":{"name":"Economic History of Developing Regions","volume":"36 1","pages":"264 - 281"},"PeriodicalIF":0.5,"publicationDate":"2021-05-04","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1080/20780389.2021.1926232","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"46815038","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 3
Macroeconomic history in South Africa: The South African Reserve Bank centennial special issue 南非宏观经济历史:南非储备银行百年特刊
IF 0.5 Q1 HISTORY Pub Date : 2021-05-04 DOI: 10.1080/20780389.2021.1930709
J. Fourie
When Simon Groot died in 1688 on his Stellenbosch farm – leaving behind his wife, Gertrud Baumann, and their two daughters, aged 6 and 18 months – his probate inventory recorded the collection of household goods and farm implements that the family had owned at the time: some tin and iron equipment, a gun, and a wagon, to name but a few items. The inventory also lists the summer harvest of ten mudden rye and the livestock on the farm: one pig, two horses, twelve trek oxen, ten cattle and fifty-five sheep. Ownership of one enslaved, unnamed boy is recorded – but what is most remarkable about Groot’s inventory is the family’s credit network: despite their relatively humble portfolio of assets, they owed money to at least fifteen people – including a sizeable sum to the Dutch Reformed Church. In contrast to an earlier literature which suggested a mostly subsistence economy, research using these probate inventories and auction rolls has revealed the dense financial network of the eighteenth-century Cape Colony – a financial network underpinned, it must be emphasized, by the institution of slavery (Fourie and Swanepoel 2018). This fact – a thriving capitalist system blemished by exclusion and exploitation – would become characteristic of South Africa’s economic development into the nineteenth and twentieth centuries. The study of capitalism – the history of markets, entrepreneurship, trade, and innovation but also labour coercion, discrimination, and inequality – is back in vogue. There are at least two reasons for this. First, events in the present have forced social scientists to learn from the past. Macroeconomists, enamoured with rational expectations models, had predicted the end of the business cycle – that was, until the Great Recession of 2007 dashed those predictions. As Eichengreen (2012) reminds us, it is during such financial crises that policymakers turn to history for guidance. Furthermore, the rise of populist movements across the globe during the 2010s has warranted comparisons with earlier eras that also witnessed severe levels of societal inequality (Piketty and Zucman 2014). Forms of exclusion along race and gender identities persist – exclusions that have deep historic roots (Wanamaker 2017). And research on the Spanish flu of 1918 is in high demand in the wake of the Covid-19 pandemic (Arthi and Parman 2021). A second reason for the rising interest in the study of economic history is the availability of new methods and sources (Mitchener 2015). This is especially applicable to the developing world, where conventional historical sources are often inaccessible or
西蒙·格鲁特于1688年在他的斯泰伦博斯农场去世,留下了他的妻子格特鲁德·鲍曼和两个分别为6岁和18个月大的女儿。他的遗嘱清单记录了当时家庭拥有的家庭用品和农具:一些锡和铁设备,一支枪,一辆马车,等等。清单上还列出了十只黑麦的夏季收成和农场上的牲畜:一头猪,两匹马,十二头牛,十头牛和五十五只羊。一个被奴役的无名男孩的所有权被记录了下来,但格鲁特的清单中最引人注目的是这个家庭的信用网络:尽管他们的资产组合相对不起眼,但他们至少欠了15个人的钱,其中包括荷兰归正教会的一大笔钱。与早期文献提出的主要是自给自足的经济相比,使用这些遗嘱清单和拍卖卷的研究揭示了18世纪开普殖民地的密集金融网络——必须强调的是,这一金融网络是由奴隶制制度支撑的(Fourie and Swanepoel 2018)。这一事实- -被排斥和剥削玷污的繁荣的资本主义制度- -将成为南非进入19和20世纪的经济发展的特点。对资本主义的研究——市场、创业、贸易和创新的历史,以及劳动强制、歧视和不平等的历史——重新流行起来。这至少有两个原因。首先,当前发生的事件迫使社会科学家从过去学习。痴迷于理性预期模型的宏观经济学家曾预测到商业周期的结束——直到2007年的大衰退打破了这些预测。正如Eichengreen(2012)提醒我们的那样,正是在此类金融危机期间,政策制定者才会从历史中寻求指导。此外,2010年代民粹主义运动在全球范围内的兴起,值得与早期社会严重不平等的时代进行比较(Piketty和Zucman 2014)。种族和性别认同的排斥形式依然存在——这种排斥有着深刻的历史根源(Wanamaker 2017)。在Covid-19大流行之后,对1918年西班牙流感的研究需求量很大(Arthi和Parman 2021)。对经济史研究越来越感兴趣的第二个原因是新方法和新来源的可用性(Mitchener 2015)。这尤其适用于发展中国家,在这些国家,传统的历史资料往往难以获得
{"title":"Macroeconomic history in South Africa: The South African Reserve Bank centennial special issue","authors":"J. Fourie","doi":"10.1080/20780389.2021.1930709","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1080/20780389.2021.1930709","url":null,"abstract":"When Simon Groot died in 1688 on his Stellenbosch farm – leaving behind his wife, Gertrud Baumann, and their two daughters, aged 6 and 18 months – his probate inventory recorded the collection of household goods and farm implements that the family had owned at the time: some tin and iron equipment, a gun, and a wagon, to name but a few items. The inventory also lists the summer harvest of ten mudden rye and the livestock on the farm: one pig, two horses, twelve trek oxen, ten cattle and fifty-five sheep. Ownership of one enslaved, unnamed boy is recorded – but what is most remarkable about Groot’s inventory is the family’s credit network: despite their relatively humble portfolio of assets, they owed money to at least fifteen people – including a sizeable sum to the Dutch Reformed Church. In contrast to an earlier literature which suggested a mostly subsistence economy, research using these probate inventories and auction rolls has revealed the dense financial network of the eighteenth-century Cape Colony – a financial network underpinned, it must be emphasized, by the institution of slavery (Fourie and Swanepoel 2018). This fact – a thriving capitalist system blemished by exclusion and exploitation – would become characteristic of South Africa’s economic development into the nineteenth and twentieth centuries. The study of capitalism – the history of markets, entrepreneurship, trade, and innovation but also labour coercion, discrimination, and inequality – is back in vogue. There are at least two reasons for this. First, events in the present have forced social scientists to learn from the past. Macroeconomists, enamoured with rational expectations models, had predicted the end of the business cycle – that was, until the Great Recession of 2007 dashed those predictions. As Eichengreen (2012) reminds us, it is during such financial crises that policymakers turn to history for guidance. Furthermore, the rise of populist movements across the globe during the 2010s has warranted comparisons with earlier eras that also witnessed severe levels of societal inequality (Piketty and Zucman 2014). Forms of exclusion along race and gender identities persist – exclusions that have deep historic roots (Wanamaker 2017). And research on the Spanish flu of 1918 is in high demand in the wake of the Covid-19 pandemic (Arthi and Parman 2021). A second reason for the rising interest in the study of economic history is the availability of new methods and sources (Mitchener 2015). This is especially applicable to the developing world, where conventional historical sources are often inaccessible or","PeriodicalId":54115,"journal":{"name":"Economic History of Developing Regions","volume":"36 1","pages":"117 - 121"},"PeriodicalIF":0.5,"publicationDate":"2021-05-04","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"48752011","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
The growth and diversity of the Cape private capital market, 1892–1902 开普私人资本市场的成长和多样性,1892-1902
IF 0.5 Q1 HISTORY Pub Date : 2021-05-04 DOI: 10.1080/20780389.2021.1943347
Lloyd Melusi Maphosa, A. Ehlers, J. Fourie, E. Kerby
ABSTRACT The adoption of limited liability in the nineteenth century is considered to have boosted economic growth and expanded capital markets in Europe and North America. Despite similar legal changes in frontier markets such as South Africa, very few attempts have been made to analyse the economic effects thereof. After the Cape Joint Stock Company Act No. 25 of 1892 there was an upsurge in new joint stock companies in the Cape Colony, but little is known about the people who financed them. This study is an enquiry into who they were. Using a list of 6883 shareholders from 263 companies, we show that the Cape’s sources of private capital were a diverse group of people. Unlike previous studies, we find that most capital came from the middle class at the Cape and very little from foreign investors. The paper contributes to our understanding of early financial developments on the frontier and the evolution of capitalism at the Cape. It also contributes broadly to the economic and business history of the late nineteenth- and twentieth-century Cape.
摘要十九世纪有限责任的采用被认为促进了欧洲和北美的经济增长和资本市场的扩张。尽管南非等前沿市场也发生了类似的法律变化,但很少有人试图分析其经济影响。1892年第25号《开普股份公司法》颁布后,开普殖民地出现了新的股份公司热潮,但对资助这些公司的人知之甚少。这项研究是对他们是谁的调查。使用来自263家公司的6883名股东名单,我们发现开普省的私人资本来源是不同的人群。与之前的研究不同,我们发现大多数资本来自开普省的中产阶级,很少来自外国投资者。这篇论文有助于我们理解边境地区的早期金融发展和开普省资本主义的演变。它也为19世纪末和20世纪开普省的经济和商业史做出了广泛贡献。
{"title":"The growth and diversity of the Cape private capital market, 1892–1902","authors":"Lloyd Melusi Maphosa, A. Ehlers, J. Fourie, E. Kerby","doi":"10.1080/20780389.2021.1943347","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1080/20780389.2021.1943347","url":null,"abstract":"ABSTRACT The adoption of limited liability in the nineteenth century is considered to have boosted economic growth and expanded capital markets in Europe and North America. Despite similar legal changes in frontier markets such as South Africa, very few attempts have been made to analyse the economic effects thereof. After the Cape Joint Stock Company Act No. 25 of 1892 there was an upsurge in new joint stock companies in the Cape Colony, but little is known about the people who financed them. This study is an enquiry into who they were. Using a list of 6883 shareholders from 263 companies, we show that the Cape’s sources of private capital were a diverse group of people. Unlike previous studies, we find that most capital came from the middle class at the Cape and very little from foreign investors. The paper contributes to our understanding of early financial developments on the frontier and the evolution of capitalism at the Cape. It also contributes broadly to the economic and business history of the late nineteenth- and twentieth-century Cape.","PeriodicalId":54115,"journal":{"name":"Economic History of Developing Regions","volume":"36 1","pages":"149 - 174"},"PeriodicalIF":0.5,"publicationDate":"2021-05-04","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1080/20780389.2021.1943347","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"44455029","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Two of the most eventful years in the history of the South African Reserve Bank: William Henry Clegg and Johannes Postmus and the 1931–1932 crisis 南非储备银行历史上最多事的两年:威廉·亨利·克莱格和约翰内斯·波斯特马斯以及1931-1932年的危机
IF 0.5 Q1 HISTORY Pub Date : 2021-05-04 DOI: 10.1080/20780389.2021.1927697
Bradley Bordiss, V. Padayachee, J. Rossouw
ABSTRACT The SA Reserve Bank (SARB) was created as a result of an earlier gold standard monetary crisis that unfolded after World War I. From 1919, South Africa nominally maintained the gold standard, but not the conversion of banknotes into gold. This article seeks to discuss the SARB's views on the gold standard controversy, and to highlight the different attitudes of the first two governors, Clegg and Postmus, attitudes that have not previously been examined in the literature. It will also discuss the way in which the Bank of England misled Clegg, and how the views expressed privately differed from those in the SARB's Ordinary General Meeting (OGM) documentation. This paper considers the irony that Clegg was selected from the ranks of the Bank of England and was loyal to Threadneedle Street, but defended a monetary policy which aided one of the biggest constituencies of the Afrikaner Nationalist Party – Afrikaner farmers. By contrast, Postmus was previously at the Nederlandsche Bankvoor Zuid-Afrika, and supported the National Party position that South Africa should return to, and remain on, a gold standard independent of Britain. Despite this, Postmus's policy turned out to be disastrous for the mostly Afrikaner farmers affected by the 1931–1932 crisis.
南非储备银行(SARB)是在第一次世界大战后爆发的金本位货币危机后成立的,从1919年开始,南非名义上维持了金本位,但没有将纸币兑换成黄金。本文试图讨论SARB对金本位争议的看法,并强调前两位行长克莱格和波斯特马斯的不同态度,这些态度在以前的文献中没有被研究过。它还将讨论英格兰银行误导克莱格的方式,以及私下表达的观点与SARB普通股东大会(OGM)文件中的观点有何不同。本文认为,具有讽刺意味的是,克莱格是从英格兰银行(Bank of England)中挑选出来的,忠于针线街(Threadneedle Street),但却捍卫了一项帮助南非白人民族主义党的最大选区之一——南非白人农民的货币政策。相比之下,波斯特马斯之前在荷兰中央银行任职,支持国民党的立场,即南非应该回归并保持独立于英国的金本位制。尽管如此,波斯特马斯的政策对受1931-1932年危机影响的大多数南非白人农民来说是灾难性的。
{"title":"Two of the most eventful years in the history of the South African Reserve Bank: William Henry Clegg and Johannes Postmus and the 1931–1932 crisis","authors":"Bradley Bordiss, V. Padayachee, J. Rossouw","doi":"10.1080/20780389.2021.1927697","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1080/20780389.2021.1927697","url":null,"abstract":"ABSTRACT The SA Reserve Bank (SARB) was created as a result of an earlier gold standard monetary crisis that unfolded after World War I. From 1919, South Africa nominally maintained the gold standard, but not the conversion of banknotes into gold. This article seeks to discuss the SARB's views on the gold standard controversy, and to highlight the different attitudes of the first two governors, Clegg and Postmus, attitudes that have not previously been examined in the literature. It will also discuss the way in which the Bank of England misled Clegg, and how the views expressed privately differed from those in the SARB's Ordinary General Meeting (OGM) documentation. This paper considers the irony that Clegg was selected from the ranks of the Bank of England and was loyal to Threadneedle Street, but defended a monetary policy which aided one of the biggest constituencies of the Afrikaner Nationalist Party – Afrikaner farmers. By contrast, Postmus was previously at the Nederlandsche Bankvoor Zuid-Afrika, and supported the National Party position that South Africa should return to, and remain on, a gold standard independent of Britain. Despite this, Postmus's policy turned out to be disastrous for the mostly Afrikaner farmers affected by the 1931–1932 crisis.","PeriodicalId":54115,"journal":{"name":"Economic History of Developing Regions","volume":"36 1","pages":"194 - 212"},"PeriodicalIF":0.5,"publicationDate":"2021-05-04","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1080/20780389.2021.1927697","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"45160624","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
The South African small banks’ crisis of 2002/3 2002/3年南非小银行危机
IF 0.5 Q1 HISTORY Pub Date : 2021-05-04 DOI: 10.1080/20780389.2021.1943348
R. Havemann
ABSTRACT Following the collapse of Saambou bank in February 2002, contagion rapidly spread amongst South African small and medium-sized banks. By the end of 2003, half of the country’s banks had deregistered. The paper constructs a unique monthly bank-level data set to show that the banks that failed were those with short-term liabilities from other financial institutions. An initial delay in providing liquidity to solvent banks in distress and raising interest rates may have exacerbated the crisis. The need for prompt, swift action echoes lessons from banking panics throughout history.
自2002年2月Saambou银行倒闭后,危机在南非中小银行间迅速蔓延。到2003年底,全国一半的银行已经注销。这篇论文构建了一个独特的月度银行级数据集,以显示破产的银行是那些从其他金融机构获得短期债务的银行。最初在向陷入困境的有偿付能力的银行提供流动性和提高利率方面的延迟可能加剧了危机。采取迅速行动的必要性与历史上银行业恐慌的教训相呼应。
{"title":"The South African small banks’ crisis of 2002/3","authors":"R. Havemann","doi":"10.1080/20780389.2021.1943348","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1080/20780389.2021.1943348","url":null,"abstract":"ABSTRACT Following the collapse of Saambou bank in February 2002, contagion rapidly spread amongst South African small and medium-sized banks. By the end of 2003, half of the country’s banks had deregistered. The paper constructs a unique monthly bank-level data set to show that the banks that failed were those with short-term liabilities from other financial institutions. An initial delay in providing liquidity to solvent banks in distress and raising interest rates may have exacerbated the crisis. The need for prompt, swift action echoes lessons from banking panics throughout history.","PeriodicalId":54115,"journal":{"name":"Economic History of Developing Regions","volume":"36 1","pages":"313 - 338"},"PeriodicalIF":0.5,"publicationDate":"2021-05-04","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1080/20780389.2021.1943348","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"47559145","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2
The Portuguese escudo area in Africa and its lessons for monetary unions 葡萄牙在非洲的埃斯库多地区及其对货币联盟的教训
IF 0.5 Q1 HISTORY Pub Date : 2021-04-16 DOI: 10.1080/20780389.2021.1890579
M. E. Mata, L. Nunes, Mário Roldão
ABSTRACT The beginnings of the Portuguese Escudo Monetary Zone (EMZ) in 1961, to promote the economic integration of Portugal and its empire, coincide in time with Mundell’s seminal paper about optimum currency areas. If non-optimality was the cause of the EMZ’s demise, this would suggest that monetary unions are fragile achievements, with little prospect for survival. The EMZ turned out to be a short-lived experiment, with Angola and Mozambique building up large cumulative deficit positions offset by the sizeable cumulative surpluses of the mainland. A cobweb model using monthly observations for macroeconomic variables of these two territories describes a time divergent process caused by structural imbalances, as well as by the loan granting system. The EMZ was not an optimum currency area and was not sustainable in the long run. This is an historical experiment that is not without interest for the study of other monetary areas.
葡萄牙埃斯库多货币区(EMZ)于1961年成立,旨在促进葡萄牙及其帝国的经济一体化,与蒙代尔关于最优货币区的开创性论文不见不合。如果非最优性是EMZ消亡的原因,这将表明货币联盟是脆弱的成就,几乎没有生存的希望。事实证明,EMZ只是一个短暂的实验,安哥拉和莫桑比克累积了巨额赤字头寸,被中国内地可观的累积盈余所抵消。一个蛛网模型利用对这两个地区宏观经济变量的月度观察,描述了一个由结构失衡和贷款发放系统引起的时间分歧过程。EMZ不是最优货币区,从长远来看也不可持续。这是一个历史性的实验,对其他货币领域的研究并非毫无意义。
{"title":"The Portuguese escudo area in Africa and its lessons for monetary unions","authors":"M. E. Mata, L. Nunes, Mário Roldão","doi":"10.1080/20780389.2021.1890579","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1080/20780389.2021.1890579","url":null,"abstract":"ABSTRACT The beginnings of the Portuguese Escudo Monetary Zone (EMZ) in 1961, to promote the economic integration of Portugal and its empire, coincide in time with Mundell’s seminal paper about optimum currency areas. If non-optimality was the cause of the EMZ’s demise, this would suggest that monetary unions are fragile achievements, with little prospect for survival. The EMZ turned out to be a short-lived experiment, with Angola and Mozambique building up large cumulative deficit positions offset by the sizeable cumulative surpluses of the mainland. A cobweb model using monthly observations for macroeconomic variables of these two territories describes a time divergent process caused by structural imbalances, as well as by the loan granting system. The EMZ was not an optimum currency area and was not sustainable in the long run. This is an historical experiment that is not without interest for the study of other monetary areas.","PeriodicalId":54115,"journal":{"name":"Economic History of Developing Regions","volume":"36 1","pages":"392 - 421"},"PeriodicalIF":0.5,"publicationDate":"2021-04-16","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1080/20780389.2021.1890579","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"46217854","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
期刊
Economic History of Developing Regions
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1