首页 > 最新文献

Advances in health economics and health services research最新文献

英文 中文
Achieving the Healthy People 2010 goal of elimination of health disparities: what will it take? 实现健康人2010年消除健康差距的目标:需要做些什么?
Pub Date : 2008-01-01 DOI: 10.1016/s0731-2199(08)19002-1
Kevin Fiscella

The second national goal for Healthy People 2010 is the elimination of health disparities related to social disadvantage in the United States. Unfortunately, progress to date has been limited. Our national strategy to achieve this goal has been too narrowly focused on public health. Success will require a broader strategy including alignment of existing national policies in non-health areas that affect the health of the socially disadvantaged such as education, health care, labor, welfare, housing, criminal justice, the environment, and taxation if it is to succeed. Key criteria are needed to begin to prioritize areas for federal investment to achieve this goal. These include the impact of the targeted condition on disparities, evidence base for the intervention, potential impact of the policy on disparities, economic impact, and federal politics. Two "big ideas" offer promise including federal investment in early child education and enhanced primary care within federally qualified community health centers. The proposed criteria are applied to each proposed policy.

“2010年健康人口”的第二个国家目标是消除美国与社会不利地位有关的健康差距。不幸的是,迄今为止的进展有限。我们实现这一目标的国家战略过于狭隘地侧重于公共卫生。要想取得成功,就需要一项更广泛的战略,包括协调影响社会弱势群体健康的非卫生领域的现有国家政策,如教育、保健、劳工、福利、住房、刑事司法、环境和税收。为实现这一目标,需要制定关键标准,以便开始确定联邦投资领域的优先次序。这些包括目标条件对差异的影响、干预的证据基础、政策对差异的潜在影响、经济影响和联邦政治。两个“大想法”提供了希望,包括联邦政府对早期儿童教育的投资,以及在联邦合格的社区卫生中心加强初级保健。建议的标准适用于每个建议的政策。
{"title":"Achieving the Healthy People 2010 goal of elimination of health disparities: what will it take?","authors":"Kevin Fiscella","doi":"10.1016/s0731-2199(08)19002-1","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1016/s0731-2199(08)19002-1","url":null,"abstract":"<p><p>The second national goal for Healthy People 2010 is the elimination of health disparities related to social disadvantage in the United States. Unfortunately, progress to date has been limited. Our national strategy to achieve this goal has been too narrowly focused on public health. Success will require a broader strategy including alignment of existing national policies in non-health areas that affect the health of the socially disadvantaged such as education, health care, labor, welfare, housing, criminal justice, the environment, and taxation if it is to succeed. Key criteria are needed to begin to prioritize areas for federal investment to achieve this goal. These include the impact of the targeted condition on disparities, evidence base for the intervention, potential impact of the policy on disparities, economic impact, and federal politics. Two \"big ideas\" offer promise including federal investment in early child education and enhanced primary care within federally qualified community health centers. The proposed criteria are applied to each proposed policy.</p>","PeriodicalId":79553,"journal":{"name":"Advances in health economics and health services research","volume":"19 ","pages":"25-41"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2008-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1016/s0731-2199(08)19002-1","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"28338395","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 3
Influence, information overload, and information technology in health care. 医疗保健中的影响、信息超载和信息技术。
James B Rebitzer, Mari Rege, Christopher Shepard

We investigate whether information technology (IT) can help physicians more efficiently acquire new knowledge in a clinical environment characterized by information overload. We combine analysis of data from a randomized trial with a theoretical model of the influence that IT has on the acquisition of new medical knowledge. Although the theoretical framework we develop is conventionally microeconomic, the model highlights the non-market and non-pecuniary influence activities that have been emphasized in the sociological literature on technology diffusion. We report three findings. First, empirical evidence and theoretical reasoning suggests that computer-based decision support will speed the diffusion of new medical knowledge when physicians are coping with information overload. Second, spillover effects will likely lead to "underinvestment" in this decision support technology. Third, alternative financing strategies common to new IT, such as the use of marketing dollars to pay for the decision support systems, may lead to undesirable outcomes if physician information overload is sufficiently severe and if there is significant ambiguity in how best to respond to the clinical issues identified by the computer. This is the first paper to analyze empirically and theoretically how computer-based decision support influences the acquisition of new knowledge by physicians.

我们调查信息技术(IT)是否可以帮助医生更有效地获取新知识在临床环境的特点是信息超载。我们将随机试验的数据分析与信息技术对获取新医学知识的影响的理论模型相结合。虽然我们开发的理论框架是传统的微观经济,但该模型强调了社会学文献中关于技术扩散的非市场和非金钱影响活动。我们报告了三个发现。首先,经验证据和理论推理表明,当医生应对信息过载时,基于计算机的决策支持将加速新医学知识的传播。其次,溢出效应可能导致该决策支持技术的“投资不足”。第三,新IT常见的替代融资策略,例如使用营销资金来支付决策支持系统,如果医生信息过载足够严重,并且在如何最好地响应计算机识别的临床问题方面存在重大歧义,则可能导致不良后果。这是第一篇从实证和理论上分析基于计算机的决策支持如何影响医生获取新知识的论文。
{"title":"Influence, information overload, and information technology in health care.","authors":"James B Rebitzer,&nbsp;Mari Rege,&nbsp;Christopher Shepard","doi":"","DOIUrl":"","url":null,"abstract":"<p><p>We investigate whether information technology (IT) can help physicians more efficiently acquire new knowledge in a clinical environment characterized by information overload. We combine analysis of data from a randomized trial with a theoretical model of the influence that IT has on the acquisition of new medical knowledge. Although the theoretical framework we develop is conventionally microeconomic, the model highlights the non-market and non-pecuniary influence activities that have been emphasized in the sociological literature on technology diffusion. We report three findings. First, empirical evidence and theoretical reasoning suggests that computer-based decision support will speed the diffusion of new medical knowledge when physicians are coping with information overload. Second, spillover effects will likely lead to \"underinvestment\" in this decision support technology. Third, alternative financing strategies common to new IT, such as the use of marketing dollars to pay for the decision support systems, may lead to undesirable outcomes if physician information overload is sufficiently severe and if there is significant ambiguity in how best to respond to the clinical issues identified by the computer. This is the first paper to analyze empirically and theoretically how computer-based decision support influences the acquisition of new knowledge by physicians.</p>","PeriodicalId":79553,"journal":{"name":"Advances in health economics and health services research","volume":"19 ","pages":"43-69"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2008-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"28338397","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
How primates (including us!) respond to inequity. 灵长类动物(包括人类)对不平等的反应。
Pub Date : 2008-01-01 DOI: 10.1016/S0731-2199(08)20005-1
S. Brosnan
{"title":"How primates (including us!) respond to inequity.","authors":"S. Brosnan","doi":"10.1016/S0731-2199(08)20005-1","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1016/S0731-2199(08)20005-1","url":null,"abstract":"","PeriodicalId":79553,"journal":{"name":"Advances in health economics and health services research","volume":"20 1","pages":"99-124"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2008-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1016/S0731-2199(08)20005-1","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"56183214","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 4
Emotion, decision-making and the brain. 情感,决策和大脑。
Luke J Chang, Alan G Sanfey

Purpose: Initial explorations in the burgeoning field of neuroeconomics have highlighted evidence supporting a potential dissociation between a fast automatic system and a slow deliberative controlled system. Growing research in the role of emotion in decision-making has attempted to draw parallels to the automatic system. This chapter will discuss a theoretical framework for understanding the role of emotion in decision-making and evidence supporting the underlying neural substrates.

Design/methodology/approach: This chapter applies a conceptual framework to understanding the role of emotion in decision-making, and emphasizes a distinction between expected and immediate emotions. Expected emotions refer to anticipated emotional states associated with a given decision that are never actually experienced. Immediate emotions, however, are experienced at the time of decision, and either can occur in response to a particular decision or merely as a result of a transitory fluctuation. This chapter will review research from the neuroeconomics literature that supports a neural dissociation between these two classes of emotion and also discuss a few interpretive caveats.

Findings: Several lines of research including regret, uncertainty, social decision-making, and moral decision-making have yielded evidence consistent with our formulization--expected and immediate emotions may invoke dissociable neural systems.

Originality/value: This chapter provides a more specific conceptualization of the mediating role of emotions in the decision-making process, which has important implications for understanding the interacting neural systems underlying the interface between emotion and cognition--a topic of immediate value to anyone investigating topics within the context of social-cognitive-affective-neuroscience.

目的:在新兴的神经经济学领域的初步探索已经突出了支持快速自动系统和缓慢审慎控制系统之间潜在分离的证据。越来越多关于情绪在决策中的作用的研究试图将其与自动系统相提并论。本章将讨论理解情绪在决策中的作用的理论框架和支持潜在神经基质的证据。设计/方法论/方法:本章应用概念框架来理解情绪在决策中的作用,并强调预期情绪和直接情绪之间的区别。预期情绪是指与特定决策相关的、从未实际经历过的预期情绪状态。然而,即时情绪是在做决定的时候经历的,既可以是对特定决定的反应,也可以仅仅是短暂波动的结果。本章将回顾神经经济学文献中支持这两类情绪之间神经分离的研究,并讨论一些解释性的警告。研究发现:包括后悔、不确定性、社会决策和道德决策在内的几项研究都得出了与我们的公式化相一致的证据——预期的和即时的情绪可能会调用可分离的神经系统。原创性/价值:本章对情绪在决策过程中的中介作用提供了更具体的概念化,这对于理解情绪和认知之间界面的相互作用的神经系统具有重要意义——这是一个对任何在社会认知情感神经科学背景下研究主题的人都具有直接价值的主题。
{"title":"Emotion, decision-making and the brain.","authors":"Luke J Chang,&nbsp;Alan G Sanfey","doi":"","DOIUrl":"","url":null,"abstract":"<p><strong>Purpose: </strong>Initial explorations in the burgeoning field of neuroeconomics have highlighted evidence supporting a potential dissociation between a fast automatic system and a slow deliberative controlled system. Growing research in the role of emotion in decision-making has attempted to draw parallels to the automatic system. This chapter will discuss a theoretical framework for understanding the role of emotion in decision-making and evidence supporting the underlying neural substrates.</p><p><strong>Design/methodology/approach: </strong>This chapter applies a conceptual framework to understanding the role of emotion in decision-making, and emphasizes a distinction between expected and immediate emotions. Expected emotions refer to anticipated emotional states associated with a given decision that are never actually experienced. Immediate emotions, however, are experienced at the time of decision, and either can occur in response to a particular decision or merely as a result of a transitory fluctuation. This chapter will review research from the neuroeconomics literature that supports a neural dissociation between these two classes of emotion and also discuss a few interpretive caveats.</p><p><strong>Findings: </strong>Several lines of research including regret, uncertainty, social decision-making, and moral decision-making have yielded evidence consistent with our formulization--expected and immediate emotions may invoke dissociable neural systems.</p><p><strong>Originality/value: </strong>This chapter provides a more specific conceptualization of the mediating role of emotions in the decision-making process, which has important implications for understanding the interacting neural systems underlying the interface between emotion and cognition--a topic of immediate value to anyone investigating topics within the context of social-cognitive-affective-neuroscience.</p>","PeriodicalId":79553,"journal":{"name":"Advances in health economics and health services research","volume":"20 ","pages":"31-53"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2008-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"28265409","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
How primates (including us!) respond to inequity. 灵长类动物(包括人类)对不平等的反应。
Sarah F Brosnan

Purpose: Responding negatively to inequity is not a uniquely human trait. Some of our closest evolutionary ancestors respond negatively when treated less well than a conspecific. Comparative work between humans and other primates can help elucidate the evolutionary underpinnings of humans' social preferences.

Methodology/approach: Results from studies of nonhuman primates, in particular chimpanzees and capuchin monkeys, are presented in comparison to human results that have been collected during economic game studies in humans, such as in the Ultimatum Game or Impunity Game.

Findings: Among nonhuman primates, a frequent behavioral reaction to inequity is to refuse to continue the interaction. While in some cases this response appears to be caused by the inequitable distribution, in others, it seems to be caused by another individual's inequitable behavior. While these reactions are similar to those of humans, this reaction does not appear to be a sense of fairness in the way that we think of it in humans. Neither nonhuman primate species alters their behavior when they are the benefited individual, and in an experimental situation, chimpanzees do not alter their behavior to obtain food for their partner as well as for themselves.

Originality/value of the chapter: Although there are differences between human and nonhuman primate responses, such studies allow us to better understand the evolution of our own responses to inequity. Given the strong behavioral reactions that even monkeys show to inequitable treatment, it is not surprising that humans are concerned with equity. Such comparisons increase understanding of issues such as healthcare disparities in humans.

目的:对不平等作出消极反应并不是人类独有的特征。在进化过程中,我们的一些最亲近的祖先在受到不如同类的待遇时,会做出消极的反应。人类和其他灵长类动物之间的比较研究有助于阐明人类社会偏好的进化基础。方法/方法:非人类灵长类动物,特别是黑猩猩和卷尾猴的研究结果,与人类经济博弈研究中收集的人类结果进行了比较,如最后通牒博弈或有罪不罚博弈。研究发现:在非人类灵长类动物中,对不平等的常见行为反应是拒绝继续互动。虽然在某些情况下,这种反应似乎是由不公平的分配引起的,但在其他情况下,它似乎是由另一个人的不公平行为引起的。虽然这些反应与人类的反应相似,但这种反应似乎并不像我们认为的人类那样具有公平感。当非人类灵长类动物是受益的个体时,它们都不会改变自己的行为,在实验中,黑猩猩不会改变自己的行为来为伴侣和自己获取食物。本章的原创性/价值:尽管人类和非人类灵长类动物的反应存在差异,但这些研究使我们能够更好地理解我们自己对不平等反应的进化。考虑到即使是猴子也会对不公平的待遇表现出强烈的行为反应,人类关心公平就不足为奇了。这种比较增进了对诸如人类医疗保健差异等问题的理解。
{"title":"How primates (including us!) respond to inequity.","authors":"Sarah F Brosnan","doi":"","DOIUrl":"","url":null,"abstract":"<p><strong>Purpose: </strong>Responding negatively to inequity is not a uniquely human trait. Some of our closest evolutionary ancestors respond negatively when treated less well than a conspecific. Comparative work between humans and other primates can help elucidate the evolutionary underpinnings of humans' social preferences.</p><p><strong>Methodology/approach: </strong>Results from studies of nonhuman primates, in particular chimpanzees and capuchin monkeys, are presented in comparison to human results that have been collected during economic game studies in humans, such as in the Ultimatum Game or Impunity Game.</p><p><strong>Findings: </strong>Among nonhuman primates, a frequent behavioral reaction to inequity is to refuse to continue the interaction. While in some cases this response appears to be caused by the inequitable distribution, in others, it seems to be caused by another individual's inequitable behavior. While these reactions are similar to those of humans, this reaction does not appear to be a sense of fairness in the way that we think of it in humans. Neither nonhuman primate species alters their behavior when they are the benefited individual, and in an experimental situation, chimpanzees do not alter their behavior to obtain food for their partner as well as for themselves.</p><p><strong>Originality/value of the chapter: </strong>Although there are differences between human and nonhuman primate responses, such studies allow us to better understand the evolution of our own responses to inequity. Given the strong behavioral reactions that even monkeys show to inequitable treatment, it is not surprising that humans are concerned with equity. Such comparisons increase understanding of issues such as healthcare disparities in humans.</p>","PeriodicalId":79553,"journal":{"name":"Advances in health economics and health services research","volume":"20 ","pages":"99-124"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2008-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"28265413","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
On the nature, modeling, and neural bases of social ties. 关于社会关系的本质、模型和神经基础。
Frans van Winden, Mirre Stallen, K Richard Ridderinkhof

Purpose: This chapter addresses the nature, formalization, and neural bases of (affective) social ties and discusses the relevance of ties for health economics. A social tie is defined as an affective weight attached by an individual to the well-being of another individual ('utility interdependence'). Ties can be positive or negative, and symmetric or asymmetric between individuals. Characteristic of a social tie, as conceived of here, is that it develops over time under the influence of interaction, in contrast with a trait like altruism. Moreover, a tie is not related to strategic behavior such as reputation formation but seen as generated by affective responses.

Methodology/approach: A formalization is presented together with some supportive evidence from behavioral experiments. This is followed by a discussion of related psychological constructs and the presentation of suggestive existing neural findings. To help prepare the grounds for a model-based neural analysis some speculations on the neural networks involved are provided, together with suggestions for future research.

Findings: Social ties are not only found to be important from an economic viewpoint, it is also shown that they can be modeled and related to neural substrates.

Originality/value of the chapter: By providing an overview of the economic research on social ties and connecting it with the broader behavioral and neuroeconomics literature, the chapter may contribute to the development of a neuroeconomics of social ties.

目的:本章讨论(情感)社会关系的性质、形式化和神经基础,并讨论关系与卫生经济学的相关性。社会关系被定义为一个人对另一个人的幸福所附加的情感重量(“效用相互依赖”)。关系可以是积极的也可以是消极的,个人之间可以是对称的也可以是不对称的。社会关系的特征,正如这里所设想的那样,是在相互作用的影响下随着时间的推移而发展的,与利他主义等特征相反。此外,领带与声誉形成等战略行为无关,而是由情感反应产生的。方法论/方法:一种形式化的方法与来自行为实验的一些支持性证据一起提出。接下来是对相关心理构念的讨论和现有神经学发现的提示。为了为基于模型的神经网络分析奠定基础,本文对所涉及的神经网络进行了一些推测,并对未来的研究提出了建议。研究发现:社会关系不仅从经济角度来看是重要的,而且还表明它们可以建模并与神经基质相关。本章的独创性/价值:通过对社会关系的经济研究进行概述,并将其与更广泛的行为和神经经济学文献联系起来,本章可能有助于社会关系神经经济学的发展。
{"title":"On the nature, modeling, and neural bases of social ties.","authors":"Frans van Winden,&nbsp;Mirre Stallen,&nbsp;K Richard Ridderinkhof","doi":"","DOIUrl":"","url":null,"abstract":"<p><strong>Purpose: </strong>This chapter addresses the nature, formalization, and neural bases of (affective) social ties and discusses the relevance of ties for health economics. A social tie is defined as an affective weight attached by an individual to the well-being of another individual ('utility interdependence'). Ties can be positive or negative, and symmetric or asymmetric between individuals. Characteristic of a social tie, as conceived of here, is that it develops over time under the influence of interaction, in contrast with a trait like altruism. Moreover, a tie is not related to strategic behavior such as reputation formation but seen as generated by affective responses.</p><p><strong>Methodology/approach: </strong>A formalization is presented together with some supportive evidence from behavioral experiments. This is followed by a discussion of related psychological constructs and the presentation of suggestive existing neural findings. To help prepare the grounds for a model-based neural analysis some speculations on the neural networks involved are provided, together with suggestions for future research.</p><p><strong>Findings: </strong>Social ties are not only found to be important from an economic viewpoint, it is also shown that they can be modeled and related to neural substrates.</p><p><strong>Originality/value of the chapter: </strong>By providing an overview of the economic research on social ties and connecting it with the broader behavioral and neuroeconomics literature, the chapter may contribute to the development of a neuroeconomics of social ties.</p>","PeriodicalId":79553,"journal":{"name":"Advances in health economics and health services research","volume":"20 ","pages":"125-59"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2008-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"28265414","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Health disparities and direct-to-consumer advertising of pharmaceutical products. 健康差距和药品直接面向消费者的广告。
Rosemary J Avery, Donald Kenkel, Dean R Lillard, Alan Mathios, Hua Wang
{"title":"Health disparities and direct-to-consumer advertising of pharmaceutical products.","authors":"Rosemary J Avery,&nbsp;Donald Kenkel,&nbsp;Dean R Lillard,&nbsp;Alan Mathios,&nbsp;Hua Wang","doi":"","DOIUrl":"","url":null,"abstract":"","PeriodicalId":79553,"journal":{"name":"Advances in health economics and health services research","volume":"19 ","pages":"71-94"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2008-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"28338399","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
The potential role of regret in the physician-patient relationship: insights from neuroeconomics. 后悔在医患关系中的潜在作用:来自神经经济学的见解。
Pub Date : 2008-01-01 DOI: 10.1016/S0731-2199(08)20004-X
G. Coricelli
{"title":"The potential role of regret in the physician-patient relationship: insights from neuroeconomics.","authors":"G. Coricelli","doi":"10.1016/S0731-2199(08)20004-X","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1016/S0731-2199(08)20004-X","url":null,"abstract":"","PeriodicalId":79553,"journal":{"name":"Advances in health economics and health services research","volume":"20 1","pages":"85-97"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2008-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1016/S0731-2199(08)20004-X","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"56183198","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 5
Quantifying national spending on wellness and prevention. 量化国家在健康和预防方面的支出。
George Miller, Charles Roehrig, Paul Hughes-Cromwick, Craig Lake

Purpose: We estimate national health expenditures on prevention using precise definitions, a transparent methodology, and a subdivision of the estimates into components to aid researchers in applying their own concepts of prevention activities.

Methodology/approach: We supplemented the National Health Expenditure Accounts (NHEA) with additional data to identify national spending on primary and secondary prevention for each year from 1996 to 2004 across eight spending categories.

Findings: We estimate that NHEA expenditures devoted to prevention grew from $83.2 billion in 1996 to $159.8 billion in 2004, in current dollars. As a share of NHEA, this represents an increase from 7.8 percent in 1996 to 8.6 percent in 2004. This share peaked at 9 percent in 2002 and then declined due to reductions in public health spending as a percent of NHEA between 2002 and 2004. Primary prevention represents about half the expenditures, consisting largely of public health expenditures--the largest prevention element. ORIGINALITY/VALUE OF PAPER: Our 2004 estimate that 8.6 percent of NHEA goes to prevention is nearly three times as large as the commonly cited figure of 3 percent, but depends on the definitions used: our estimate falls to 8.1 percent when the research component is excluded, 5.1 percent when consideration is limited to primary prevention plus screening, 4.2 percent for primary prevention alone, and 2.8 percent if we count only public health expenditures. These findings should contribute to a more informed discussion of our nation's allocation of health care resources to prevention.

目的:我们使用精确的定义、透明的方法和将估计数细分为组成部分来估计国家预防卫生支出,以帮助研究人员应用他们自己的预防活动概念。方法/方法:我们用额外的数据补充了国家卫生支出账户(NHEA),以确定1996年至2004年每年在八个支出类别中用于一级和二级预防的国家支出。研究结果:我们估计NHEA用于预防的支出从1996年的832亿美元增加到2004年的1598亿美元。这一比例从1996年的7.8%增加到2004年的8.6%。这一比例在2002年达到9%的峰值,然后由于2002年至2004年期间公共卫生支出占全国卫生保健机构的百分比减少而下降。初级预防约占支出的一半,主要由公共卫生支出构成,这是最大的预防部分。论文原创性/价值:我们在2004年估计,8.6%的NHEA用于预防,这几乎是通常引用的3%的三倍,但这取决于所使用的定义:当排除研究部分时,我们的估计降至8.1%,当考虑仅限于初级预防加筛查时,我们的估计降至5.1%,仅初级预防为4.2%,如果仅计算公共卫生支出则为2.8%。这些发现应该有助于对我国卫生保健资源在预防方面的分配进行更明智的讨论。
{"title":"Quantifying national spending on wellness and prevention.","authors":"George Miller,&nbsp;Charles Roehrig,&nbsp;Paul Hughes-Cromwick,&nbsp;Craig Lake","doi":"","DOIUrl":"","url":null,"abstract":"<p><strong>Purpose: </strong>We estimate national health expenditures on prevention using precise definitions, a transparent methodology, and a subdivision of the estimates into components to aid researchers in applying their own concepts of prevention activities.</p><p><strong>Methodology/approach: </strong>We supplemented the National Health Expenditure Accounts (NHEA) with additional data to identify national spending on primary and secondary prevention for each year from 1996 to 2004 across eight spending categories.</p><p><strong>Findings: </strong>We estimate that NHEA expenditures devoted to prevention grew from $83.2 billion in 1996 to $159.8 billion in 2004, in current dollars. As a share of NHEA, this represents an increase from 7.8 percent in 1996 to 8.6 percent in 2004. This share peaked at 9 percent in 2002 and then declined due to reductions in public health spending as a percent of NHEA between 2002 and 2004. Primary prevention represents about half the expenditures, consisting largely of public health expenditures--the largest prevention element. ORIGINALITY/VALUE OF PAPER: Our 2004 estimate that 8.6 percent of NHEA goes to prevention is nearly three times as large as the commonly cited figure of 3 percent, but depends on the definitions used: our estimate falls to 8.1 percent when the research component is excluded, 5.1 percent when consideration is limited to primary prevention plus screening, 4.2 percent for primary prevention alone, and 2.8 percent if we count only public health expenditures. These findings should contribute to a more informed discussion of our nation's allocation of health care resources to prevention.</p>","PeriodicalId":79553,"journal":{"name":"Advances in health economics and health services research","volume":"19 ","pages":"1-24"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2008-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"28336348","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Source preference and ambiguity aversion: models and evidence from behavioral and neuroimaging experiments. 来源偏好和歧义厌恶:行为和神经影像学实验的模型和证据。
Soo Hong Chew, King King Li, Robin Chark, Songfa Zhong

Purpose: This experimental economics study using brain imaging techniques investigates the risk-ambiguity distinction in relation to the source preference hypothesis (Fox & Tversky, 1995) in which identically distributed risks arising from different sources of uncertainty may engender distinct preferences for the same decision maker, contrary to classical economic thinking. The use of brain imaging enables sharper testing of the implications of different models of decision-making including Chew and Sagi's (2008) axiomatization of source preference.

Methodology/approach: Using fMRI, brain activations were observed when subjects make 48 sequential binary choices among even-chance lotteries based on whether the trailing digits of a number of stock prices at market closing would be odd or even. Subsequently, subjects rate familiarity of the stock symbols.

Findings: When contrasting brain activation from more familiar sources with those from less familiar ones, regions appearing to be more active include the putamen, medial frontal cortex, and superior temporal gyrus. ROI analysis showed that the activation patterns in the familiar-unfamiliar and unfamiliar-familiar contrasts are similar to those in the risk-ambiguity and ambiguity-risk contrasts reported by Hsu et al. (2005). This supports the conjecture that the risk-ambiguity distinction can be subsumed by the source preference hypothesis.

Research limitations/implications: Our odd-even design has the advantage of inducing the same "unambiguous" probability of half for each subject in each binary comparison. Our finding supports the implications of the Chew-Sagi model and rejects models based on global probabilistic sophistication, including rank-dependent models derived from non-additive probabilities, e.g., Choquet expected utility and cumulative prospect theory, as well as those based on multiple priors, e.g., alpha-maxmin. The finding in Hsu et al. (2005) that orbitofrontal cortex lesion patients display neither ambiguity aversion nor risk aversion offers further support to the Chew-Sagi model. Our finding also supports the Levy et al. (2007) contention of a single valuation system encompassing risk and ambiguity aversion.

Originality/value of chapter: This is the first neuroimaging study of the source preference hypothesis using a design which can discriminate among decision models ranging from risk-based ones to those relying on multiple priors.

目的:这项使用脑成像技术的实验经济学研究调查了与来源偏好假设(Fox & Tversky, 1995)相关的风险-模糊区分。在该假设中,来自不同不确定性来源的相同分布的风险可能会对同一决策者产生不同的偏好,这与经典经济学思维相反。脑成像的使用可以更清晰地测试不同决策模型的含义,包括Chew和Sagi(2008)对来源偏好的公理化。方法/方法:使用功能磁共振成像,当受试者根据一些股票在市场收盘时的尾数是奇数还是偶数,在偶数机会的彩票中做出48个连续的二进制选择时,观察大脑的激活情况。随后,受试者对股票符号的熟悉程度进行评分。研究发现:当比较来自熟悉来源和不熟悉来源的大脑激活时,壳核、内侧额叶皮层和颞上回等区域似乎更活跃。ROI分析表明,熟悉-不熟悉和不熟悉-熟悉对比的激活模式与Hsu等人(2005)报道的风险-歧义和歧义-风险对比的激活模式相似。这支持了风险-歧义区分可以被纳入源偏好假设的猜想。研究限制/启示:我们的奇偶设计的优势在于,在每个二元比较中,每个受试者都有相同的“明确的”一半概率。我们的发现支持了Chew-Sagi模型的含义,并拒绝了基于全局概率复杂性的模型,包括基于非加性概率的秩相关模型,例如Choquet期望效用和累积前景理论,以及基于多重先验的模型,例如alpha-maxmin。Hsu等人(2005)发现眼窝额叶皮质病变患者既不表现出模糊厌恶,也不表现出风险厌恶,这进一步支持了Chew-Sagi模型。我们的发现也支持Levy等人(2007)关于包含风险和模糊性规避的单一评估系统的论点。本章的原创性/价值:这是第一个关于来源偏好假设的神经影像学研究,它使用了一种设计,可以区分决策模型,从基于风险的模型到依赖于多个先验的模型。
{"title":"Source preference and ambiguity aversion: models and evidence from behavioral and neuroimaging experiments.","authors":"Soo Hong Chew,&nbsp;King King Li,&nbsp;Robin Chark,&nbsp;Songfa Zhong","doi":"","DOIUrl":"","url":null,"abstract":"<p><strong>Purpose: </strong>This experimental economics study using brain imaging techniques investigates the risk-ambiguity distinction in relation to the source preference hypothesis (Fox & Tversky, 1995) in which identically distributed risks arising from different sources of uncertainty may engender distinct preferences for the same decision maker, contrary to classical economic thinking. The use of brain imaging enables sharper testing of the implications of different models of decision-making including Chew and Sagi's (2008) axiomatization of source preference.</p><p><strong>Methodology/approach: </strong>Using fMRI, brain activations were observed when subjects make 48 sequential binary choices among even-chance lotteries based on whether the trailing digits of a number of stock prices at market closing would be odd or even. Subsequently, subjects rate familiarity of the stock symbols.</p><p><strong>Findings: </strong>When contrasting brain activation from more familiar sources with those from less familiar ones, regions appearing to be more active include the putamen, medial frontal cortex, and superior temporal gyrus. ROI analysis showed that the activation patterns in the familiar-unfamiliar and unfamiliar-familiar contrasts are similar to those in the risk-ambiguity and ambiguity-risk contrasts reported by Hsu et al. (2005). This supports the conjecture that the risk-ambiguity distinction can be subsumed by the source preference hypothesis.</p><p><strong>Research limitations/implications: </strong>Our odd-even design has the advantage of inducing the same \"unambiguous\" probability of half for each subject in each binary comparison. Our finding supports the implications of the Chew-Sagi model and rejects models based on global probabilistic sophistication, including rank-dependent models derived from non-additive probabilities, e.g., Choquet expected utility and cumulative prospect theory, as well as those based on multiple priors, e.g., alpha-maxmin. The finding in Hsu et al. (2005) that orbitofrontal cortex lesion patients display neither ambiguity aversion nor risk aversion offers further support to the Chew-Sagi model. Our finding also supports the Levy et al. (2007) contention of a single valuation system encompassing risk and ambiguity aversion.</p><p><strong>Originality/value of chapter: </strong>This is the first neuroimaging study of the source preference hypothesis using a design which can discriminate among decision models ranging from risk-based ones to those relying on multiple priors.</p>","PeriodicalId":79553,"journal":{"name":"Advances in health economics and health services research","volume":"20 ","pages":"179-201"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2008-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"28263771","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
期刊
Advances in health economics and health services research
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1