首页 > 最新文献

CEPR: Financial Economics (Topic)最新文献

英文 中文
Spillover Effects in Empirical Corporate Finance 实证企业融资的溢出效应
Pub Date : 2020-12-01 DOI: 10.1016/J.JFINECO.2021.04.039
Tobias Berg, Markus Reisinger, D. Streitz
{"title":"Spillover Effects in Empirical Corporate Finance","authors":"Tobias Berg, Markus Reisinger, D. Streitz","doi":"10.1016/J.JFINECO.2021.04.039","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1016/J.JFINECO.2021.04.039","url":null,"abstract":"","PeriodicalId":9906,"journal":{"name":"CEPR: Financial Economics (Topic)","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2020-12-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"84547397","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 32
Central Bank Money: Liability, Asset, or Equity of the Nation? 中央银行货币:负债、资产还是国家权益?
Pub Date : 2020-11-14 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3730608
Michael Kumhof, J. Allen, Will Bateman, R. Lastra, Simon Gleeson, S. Omarova
Based on legal arguments, we advocate a conceptual and normative shift in our understanding of the economic character of central bank money (CBM). The widespread treatment of CBM as a central bank liability goes back to the gold standard, and uses analogies with commercial bank balance sheets. However, CBM is sui generis and legally not comparable to commercial bank money. Furthermore, in modern economies, CBM holders cannot demand repayment of CBM in anything other than CBM. CBM is not an asset of central banks either, and it is not central bank shareholder equity because it does not confer the same ownership rights as regular shareholder equity. Based on comparisons across a number of legal characteristics of financial instruments, we suggest that an appropriate characterization of CBM is as ‘social equity’ that confers rights of participation in the economy’s payment system and thereby its economy. This interpretation is important for macroeconomic policy in light of quantitative easing and potential future issuance of central bank digital currency (CBDC). It suggests that in robust economies with credible monetary institutions, and where demand for CBM is sufficiently and sustainably high, large-scale issuance such as under CBDC is not inflationary, and it does not weaken public sector finances.
基于法律论据,我们主张在我们对中央银行货币(CBM)的经济特征的理解上进行概念和规范的转变。将CBM视为央行负债的普遍做法可以追溯到金本位,并将其与商业银行的资产负债表进行类比。然而,CBM是自成一体的,在法律上不能与商业银行的货币相提并论。此外,在现代经济中,CBM持有者不能要求以CBM以外的任何形式偿还CBM。CBM也不是央行的资产,也不是央行的股东权益,因为它不赋予与普通股东权益相同的所有权。基于对金融工具的许多法律特征的比较,我们认为CBM的适当特征是“社会公平”,它赋予了参与经济支付系统的权利,从而赋予了经济的权利。鉴于量化宽松和未来可能发行的央行数字货币(CBDC),这种解释对宏观经济政策很重要。它表明,在拥有可靠货币机构的强劲经济体中,以及对CBM的需求足够高且持续高的地方,CBDC等大规模发行不会导致通胀,也不会削弱公共部门的财政。
{"title":"Central Bank Money: Liability, Asset, or Equity of the Nation?","authors":"Michael Kumhof, J. Allen, Will Bateman, R. Lastra, Simon Gleeson, S. Omarova","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3730608","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3730608","url":null,"abstract":"Based on legal arguments, we advocate a conceptual and normative shift in our understanding of the economic character of central bank money (CBM). The widespread treatment of CBM as a central bank liability goes back to the gold standard, and uses analogies with commercial bank balance sheets. However, CBM is sui generis and legally not comparable to commercial bank money. Furthermore, in modern economies, CBM holders cannot demand repayment of CBM in anything other than CBM. CBM is not an asset of central banks either, and it is not central bank shareholder equity because it does not confer the same ownership rights as regular shareholder equity. Based on comparisons across a number of legal characteristics of financial instruments, we suggest that an appropriate characterization of CBM is as ‘social equity’ that confers rights of participation in the economy’s payment system and thereby its economy. This interpretation is important for macroeconomic policy in light of quantitative easing and potential future issuance of central bank digital currency (CBDC). It suggests that in robust economies with credible monetary institutions, and where demand for CBM is sufficiently and sustainably high, large-scale issuance such as under CBDC is not inflationary, and it does not weaken public sector finances.","PeriodicalId":9906,"journal":{"name":"CEPR: Financial Economics (Topic)","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2020-11-14","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"91496243","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 11
Risk Mitigating Versus Risk Shifting: Evidence from Banks Security Trading in Crises 风险缓解与风险转移:危机中银行证券交易的证据
Pub Date : 2020-11-01 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3732831
J. Peydró, Andrea Polo, Enrico Sette
We show that risk mitigating incentives dominate risk shifting incentives in fragile banks. Risk shifting could be particularly severe in banking since it is the most opaque industry and banks are one of the most leveraged corporations with very low skin in the game. To analyze this question, we exploit security trading by banks during financial crises, as banks can easily and quickly change their risk exposure within their security portfolio. However, in contrast with the risk shifting hypothesis, we find that less capitalized banks take relatively less risk after financial market stress shocks. We show this using the supervisory ISIN-bank-month level dataset from Italy with all securities for each bank. Our results are over and above capital regulation as we show lower reach-for-yield effects by less capitalized banks within government bonds (with zero risk weights) or within securities with the same rating and maturity in the same month (which determines regulatory capital). Effects are robust to controlling for the covariance with the existence portfolio, and less capitalized banks, if anything, reduce concentration risk. Further, effects are stronger when uncertainty is higher, despite that risk shifting motives may be then higher. Moreover, three separate tests – based on different accounting portfolios (trading book versus held to maturity), the distribution of capital and franchise value – suggest that bank own incentives, instead of supervision, are the main drivers. Results are confirmed if we consider other sources of balance sheet fragility and different measures of risk-taking. Finally, evidence from the recent COVID-19 shock corroborates findings from the Global Financial Crisis and the Euro Area Sovereign Crisis.
我们表明,在脆弱的银行中,风险缓解激励主导风险转移激励。银行业的风险转移可能尤其严重,因为它是最不透明的行业,而且银行是杠杆率最高的企业之一,在游戏中参与度非常低。为了分析这个问题,我们利用银行在金融危机期间的证券交易,因为银行可以轻松快速地改变其证券投资组合中的风险敞口。然而,与风险转移假说相反,我们发现资本较少的银行在金融市场压力冲击后承担的风险相对较小。我们使用来自意大利的监管ISIN-bank-month级别数据集来展示这一点,其中包含每家银行的所有证券。我们的结果超越了资本监管,因为我们显示了资本较少的银行在政府债券(风险权重为零)或具有相同评级和同月到期的证券(这决定了监管资本)中获得收益的影响较低。控制与现有投资组合的协方差的效果是稳健的,如果有的话,资本较少的银行降低了集中风险。此外,尽管风险转移的动机可能更高,但当不确定性更高时,影响更强。此外,基于不同会计组合(交易账簿与持有至到期)、资本分配和特许经营价值的三项独立测试表明,银行自身的激励(而非监管)才是主要驱动因素。如果我们考虑到资产负债表脆弱性的其他来源和不同的风险承担指标,结果就得到了证实。最后,最近的COVID-19冲击的证据证实了全球金融危机和欧元区主权危机的结论。
{"title":"Risk Mitigating Versus Risk Shifting: Evidence from Banks Security Trading in Crises","authors":"J. Peydró, Andrea Polo, Enrico Sette","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3732831","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3732831","url":null,"abstract":"We show that risk mitigating incentives dominate risk shifting incentives in fragile banks. Risk shifting could be particularly severe in banking since it is the most opaque industry and banks are one of the most leveraged corporations with very low skin in the game. To analyze this question, we exploit security trading by banks during financial crises, as banks can easily and quickly change their risk exposure within their security portfolio. However, in contrast with the risk shifting hypothesis, we find that less capitalized banks take relatively less risk after financial market stress shocks. We show this using the supervisory ISIN-bank-month level dataset from Italy with all securities for each bank. Our results are over and above capital regulation as we show lower reach-for-yield effects by less capitalized banks within government bonds (with zero risk weights) or within securities with the same rating and maturity in the same month (which determines regulatory capital). Effects are robust to controlling for the covariance with the existence portfolio, and less capitalized banks, if anything, reduce concentration risk. Further, effects are stronger when uncertainty is higher, despite that risk shifting motives may be then higher. Moreover, three separate tests – based on different accounting portfolios (trading book versus held to maturity), the distribution of capital and franchise value – suggest that bank own incentives, instead of supervision, are the main drivers. Results are confirmed if we consider other sources of balance sheet fragility and different measures of risk-taking. Finally, evidence from the recent COVID-19 shock corroborates findings from the Global Financial Crisis and the Euro Area Sovereign Crisis.","PeriodicalId":9906,"journal":{"name":"CEPR: Financial Economics (Topic)","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2020-11-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"73390730","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Financial Intermediation and Technology: What's Old, What's New? 金融中介与技术:什么是旧的,什么是新的?
Pub Date : 2020-07-01 DOI: 10.5089/9781513552491.001
P. Hoffmann, L. Laeven, Lev Ratnovski
We study the effects of technological change on financial intermediation, distinguishing between innovations in information (data collection and processing) and communication (relationships and distribution). Both follow historic trends towards an increased use of hard information and less in-person interaction, which are accelerating rapidly. We point to more recent innovations, such as the combination of data abundance and artificial intelligence, and the rise of digital platforms. We argue that in particular the rise of new communication channels can lead to the vertical and horizontal disintegration of the traditional bank business model. Specialized providers of financial services can chip away activities that do not rely on access to balance sheets, while platforms can interject themselves between banks and customers. We discuss limitations to these challenges, and the resulting policy implications.
我们研究了技术变革对金融中介的影响,区分了信息(数据收集和处理)和通信(关系和分配)方面的创新。两者都遵循着增加硬信息使用和减少面对面互动的历史趋势,这一趋势正在迅速加速。我们指出了最近的创新,比如数据丰富与人工智能的结合,以及数字平台的兴起。我们认为,特别是新的沟通渠道的兴起可能导致传统银行业务模式的纵向和横向解体。专业金融服务提供商可以削弱不依赖于资产负债表的活动,而平台可以介入银行和客户之间。我们将讨论这些挑战的局限性,以及由此产生的政策影响。
{"title":"Financial Intermediation and Technology: What's Old, What's New?","authors":"P. Hoffmann, L. Laeven, Lev Ratnovski","doi":"10.5089/9781513552491.001","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.5089/9781513552491.001","url":null,"abstract":"We study the effects of technological change on financial intermediation, distinguishing between innovations in information (data collection and processing) and communication (relationships and distribution). Both follow historic trends towards an increased use of hard information and less in-person interaction, which are accelerating rapidly. We point to more recent innovations, such as the combination of data abundance and artificial intelligence, and the rise of digital platforms. We argue that in particular the rise of new communication channels can lead to the vertical and horizontal disintegration of the traditional bank business model. Specialized providers of financial services can chip away activities that do not rely on access to balance sheets, while platforms can interject themselves between banks and customers. We discuss limitations to these challenges, and the resulting policy implications.","PeriodicalId":9906,"journal":{"name":"CEPR: Financial Economics (Topic)","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2020-07-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"80446337","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 27
Product Market Competition and the Relocation of Economic Activity: Evidence from the Supply Chain 产品市场竞争与经济活动转移:来自供应链的证据
Pub Date : 2020-07-01 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3652190
Chen Chen, S. Dasgupta, Thanh D. Huynh, Ying Xia
We show that intensified competition changes the location of business activity and, in turn, affects supply chain relationships. Using establishment-level data, we find that, when upstream product markets become more competitive, suppliers are more likely to relocate their establishments closer to customers. Following the supplier’s relocation, its sales to the customer increase, its relationship with the customer is less likely to be terminated, and its innovation is more aligned with the customer’s innovation. The relocated supplier also experiences more analyst following and institutional ownership that are in common with the customer and is more likely to issue equity than debt. However, the improved relationship, by causing the supplier to engage more in innovation dedicated to the customer, adversely affects creative innovation, which is known to drive growth. This paper was accepted by Gustavo Manso, finance.
我们表明,激烈的竞争改变了商业活动的位置,进而影响了供应链关系。利用企业层面的数据,我们发现,当上游产品市场竞争变得更加激烈时,供应商更有可能将其企业搬迁到离客户更近的地方。供应商搬迁后,其对客户的销售额增加,与客户的关系不太可能被终止,其创新与客户的创新更加一致。重新安置的供应商还会经历更多的分析师追随和机构所有权,这与客户相同,并且更有可能发行股权而不是债务。然而,改善的关系,通过使供应商更多地致力于客户的创新,对创造性创新产生不利影响,而创造性创新是众所周知的推动增长的因素。这篇论文被金融学的Gustavo Manso接受。
{"title":"Product Market Competition and the Relocation of Economic Activity: Evidence from the Supply Chain","authors":"Chen Chen, S. Dasgupta, Thanh D. Huynh, Ying Xia","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3652190","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3652190","url":null,"abstract":"We show that intensified competition changes the location of business activity and, in turn, affects supply chain relationships. Using establishment-level data, we find that, when upstream product markets become more competitive, suppliers are more likely to relocate their establishments closer to customers. Following the supplier’s relocation, its sales to the customer increase, its relationship with the customer is less likely to be terminated, and its innovation is more aligned with the customer’s innovation. The relocated supplier also experiences more analyst following and institutional ownership that are in common with the customer and is more likely to issue equity than debt. However, the improved relationship, by causing the supplier to engage more in innovation dedicated to the customer, adversely affects creative innovation, which is known to drive growth. This paper was accepted by Gustavo Manso, finance.","PeriodicalId":9906,"journal":{"name":"CEPR: Financial Economics (Topic)","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2020-07-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"77339403","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 5
Gaussian Rank Correlation and Regression 高斯秩相关与回归
Pub Date : 2020-06-01 DOI: 10.1108/s0731-90532021000043b012
Dante Amengual, Enrique Sentana, Zhanyuan Tian
We study the statistical properties of Pearson correlation coefficients of Gaussian ranks, and Gaussian rank regressions -- OLS applied to those ranks. We show that these procedures are fully efficient when the true copula is Gaussian and the margins are non-parametrically estimated, and remain consistent for their population analogues otherwise. We compare them to Spearman and Pearson correlations and their regression counterparts theoretically and in extensive Monte Carlo simulations. Empirical applications to migration and growth across US states, the augmented Solow growth model, and momentum and reversal effects in individual stock returns confirm that Gaussian rank procedures are insensitive to outliers.
我们研究了高斯秩的Pearson相关系数的统计性质,以及应用于这些秩的高斯秩回归—OLS。我们表明,当真copula为高斯且边缘是非参数估计时,这些过程是完全有效的,并且对于它们的总体类似物保持一致。我们将它们与Spearman和Pearson相关性及其在理论上和广泛的蒙特卡罗模拟中的回归对应物进行比较。对美国各州的移民和增长、增强型索洛增长模型以及个股收益的动量和逆转效应的实证应用证实,高斯秩过程对异常值不敏感。
{"title":"Gaussian Rank Correlation and Regression","authors":"Dante Amengual, Enrique Sentana, Zhanyuan Tian","doi":"10.1108/s0731-90532021000043b012","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1108/s0731-90532021000043b012","url":null,"abstract":"We study the statistical properties of Pearson correlation coefficients of Gaussian ranks, and Gaussian rank regressions -- OLS applied to those ranks. We show that these procedures are fully efficient when the true copula is Gaussian and the margins are non-parametrically estimated, and remain consistent for their population analogues otherwise. We compare them to Spearman and Pearson correlations and their regression counterparts theoretically and in extensive Monte Carlo simulations. Empirical applications to migration and growth across US states, the augmented Solow growth model, and momentum and reversal effects in individual stock returns confirm that Gaussian rank procedures are insensitive to outliers.","PeriodicalId":9906,"journal":{"name":"CEPR: Financial Economics (Topic)","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2020-06-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"80063321","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2
The Long Shadows of the Great Inflation: Evidence from Residential Mortgages 大通胀的长期阴影:来自住房抵押贷款的证据
Pub Date : 2020-06-01 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3888762
M. Botsch, Ulrike Malmendier
A major puzzle in financial contracting is consumers' aversion to adjustable rates. In the mortgage market, the empirical mix of contracts (80% fixed-rate) is inconsistent with standard life-cycle consumption models. We argue that these choices reflect the longlasting effect of the Great Inflation, and have sizable welfare implications. First, we show that consumers who have experienced higher inflation expect higher future interest-rate increases, which explains their preference for fixed-rate financing. Next, we quantify the influence of personal inflation experiences on mortgage financing using linked data from the Census Bureau's Residential Finance Survey. We estimate a discrete-choice model over mortgage financing alternatives. The structural parameters indicate that one additional percentage point of experienced inflation increases a borrower's willingness to pay for a fixed-rate mortgage by 6 to 14 basis points, compared to the adjustable-rate alternative in a given origination year. This experience effect has a major impact on the product mix of FRMs versus ARMs: Nearly one in seven households would switch to an ARM if not for the longlasting effect of personal inflation experiences. Our simulations suggest that households who would otherwise have switched pay $8,000-$16,000 in year-2000, after-tax dollars for the embedded inflation protection of the FRM.
金融合同的一个主要难题是消费者对可调利率的厌恶。在抵押贷款市场,合同的经验组合(80%固定利率)与标准的生命周期消费模型不一致。我们认为,这些选择反映了大通货膨胀的长期影响,并具有相当大的福利影响。首先,我们表明,经历过更高通胀的消费者预期未来利率会更高,这解释了他们对固定利率融资的偏好。接下来,我们使用人口普查局住宅金融调查的相关数据量化个人通货膨胀经历对抵押贷款融资的影响。我们估计了抵押贷款融资方案的离散选择模型。结构参数表明,在给定的初始年份,与可调利率抵押贷款相比,每经历一个百分点的通货膨胀,借款人支付固定利率抵押贷款的意愿就会增加6到14个基点。这种体验效应对frm和ARM的产品组合产生了重大影响:如果不是因为个人通货膨胀经历的长期影响,近七分之一的家庭会转向ARM。我们的模拟表明,原本要转换的家庭在2000年为FRM嵌入的通货膨胀保护支付了8000 - 16000美元的税后美元。
{"title":"The Long Shadows of the Great Inflation: Evidence from Residential Mortgages","authors":"M. Botsch, Ulrike Malmendier","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3888762","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3888762","url":null,"abstract":"A major puzzle in financial contracting is consumers' aversion to adjustable rates. In the mortgage market, the empirical mix of contracts (80% fixed-rate) is inconsistent with standard life-cycle consumption models. We argue that these choices reflect the longlasting effect of the Great Inflation, and have sizable welfare implications. First, we show that consumers who have experienced higher inflation expect higher future interest-rate increases, which explains their preference for fixed-rate financing. Next, we quantify the influence of personal inflation experiences on mortgage financing using linked data from the Census Bureau's Residential Finance Survey. We estimate a discrete-choice model over mortgage financing alternatives. The structural parameters indicate that one additional percentage point of experienced inflation increases a borrower's willingness to pay for a fixed-rate mortgage by 6 to 14 basis points, compared to the adjustable-rate alternative in a given origination year. This experience effect has a major impact on the product mix of FRMs versus ARMs: Nearly one in seven households would switch to an ARM if not for the longlasting effect of personal inflation experiences. Our simulations suggest that households who would otherwise have switched pay $8,000-$16,000 in year-2000, after-tax dollars for the embedded inflation protection of the FRM.","PeriodicalId":9906,"journal":{"name":"CEPR: Financial Economics (Topic)","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2020-06-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"78875073","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 14
The Tax Cuts and Jobs Act: Which Firms Won? Which Lost? 减税和就业法案:哪些公司赢了?失去了?
Pub Date : 2020-06-01 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3629722
A. Wagner, R. Zeckhauser, Alexandre Ziegler
The Tax Cut and Jobs Act (TCJA) slashed corporations’ median effective tax rates from 31.7% to 20.8%. Nevertheless, 15% of firms experienced an increase. One fifth of firms recorded nonrecurring tax costs or benefits exceeding 3% of total assets. Proxies that existing studies employ to assess the TCJA’s impacts account for just half of actual impacts. Stock prices impounded those proxies during the legislative process. Total impacts were impounded the following year, once firms published their financials. These results indicate that investors find it hard to predict even large and immediate changes to company cash flows due to unfamiliar events.
《减税与就业法案》(TCJA)将企业的有效税率中位数从31.7%大幅削减至20.8%。然而,15%的公司经历了增长。五分之一的公司记录的非经常性税收成本或收益超过总资产的3%。现有研究用来评估TCJA影响的代理仅占实际影响的一半。在立法过程中,股票价格扣押了这些代理权。一旦公司公布了他们的财务状况,总影响就会在第二年被扣留。这些结果表明,由于不熟悉的事件,投资者很难预测公司现金流的变化,即使是大而直接的变化。
{"title":"The Tax Cuts and Jobs Act: Which Firms Won? Which Lost?","authors":"A. Wagner, R. Zeckhauser, Alexandre Ziegler","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3629722","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3629722","url":null,"abstract":"The Tax Cut and Jobs Act (TCJA) slashed corporations’ median effective tax rates from 31.7% to 20.8%. Nevertheless, 15% of firms experienced an increase. One fifth of firms recorded nonrecurring tax costs or benefits exceeding 3% of total assets. Proxies that existing studies employ to assess the TCJA’s impacts account for just half of actual impacts. Stock prices impounded those proxies during the legislative process. Total impacts were impounded the following year, once firms published their financials. These results indicate that investors find it hard to predict even large and immediate changes to company cash flows due to unfamiliar events.","PeriodicalId":9906,"journal":{"name":"CEPR: Financial Economics (Topic)","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2020-06-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"81061459","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 13
The Value of Luck in the Labor Market for CEOS 劳动力市场中运气对ceo的价值
Pub Date : 2020-05-28 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3613544
M. Amore, Sebastian Schwenen
It is well-known that luck increases the compensation of CEOs at their current firm. In this paper, we explore how luck affects CEOs' outside options in the labor market, and the performance of firms that hire lucky CEOs. Our results show that luck at their current firm makes CEOs move to a new firm and be appointed as both CEO and chairman. Lucky CEOs tend to match with firms subject to low analyst coverage and operating in less competitive industries. Moreover, lucky CEOs are able to obtain a higher pay at the new firm (both in absolute terms and compared to new industry peers). Finally, difference-in-differences results show that hiring lucky CEOs hurts firm performance, mostly due to a surge in operating costs and a poorer usage of corporate assets.
众所周知,运气会增加ceo在当前公司的薪酬。在本文中,我们探讨运气如何影响ceo在劳动力市场的外部选择,以及雇佣幸运ceo的公司的绩效。我们的研究结果表明,CEO在当前公司的运气会让他们跳槽到一家新公司,并被任命为CEO和董事长。幸运的ceo往往会选择分析师关注较少、行业竞争力较弱的公司。此外,幸运的首席执行官能够在新公司获得更高的薪酬(无论是绝对值还是与新行业同行相比)。最后,差异中的差异结果显示,雇佣幸运的ceo会损害公司业绩,这主要是由于运营成本飙升和公司资产使用不当。
{"title":"The Value of Luck in the Labor Market for CEOS","authors":"M. Amore, Sebastian Schwenen","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3613544","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3613544","url":null,"abstract":"It is well-known that luck increases the compensation of CEOs at their current firm. In this paper, we explore how luck affects CEOs' outside options in the labor market, and the performance of firms that hire lucky CEOs. Our results show that luck at their current firm makes CEOs move to a new firm and be appointed as both CEO and chairman. Lucky CEOs tend to match with firms subject to low analyst coverage and operating in less competitive industries. Moreover, lucky CEOs are able to obtain a higher pay at the new firm (both in absolute terms and compared to new industry peers). Finally, difference-in-differences results show that hiring lucky CEOs hurts firm performance, mostly due to a surge in operating costs and a poorer usage of corporate assets.","PeriodicalId":9906,"journal":{"name":"CEPR: Financial Economics (Topic)","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2020-05-28","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"77353291","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 4
The Value of "New" and "Old" Intermediation in Online Debt Crowdfunding 网络债务众筹中“新”与“旧”中介的价值
Pub Date : 2020-05-01 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3557942
F. Braggion, A. Manconi, Nicola Pavanini, Haikun Zhu
We study the welfare effects of the transition of online debt crowdfunding from the older "peer-to-peer" model to the "marketplace" model, where the crowdfunding platform sells diversified loan portfolios to investor. We develop an equilibrium model of debt crowdfunding capturing platform design (peer-to-peer or marketplace) and lender preferences over loan and portfolio product characteristics, and we estimate it on a novel database on credit at a large online platform based in China. Moving from the peer-to-peer to the marketplace model raises lender surplus, platform profits, and credit provision. At the same time, reducing lender exposure to liquidity risk can be beneficial. A counterfactual scenario where the platform resembles a bank by bearing liquidity risk has similar welfare properties as the marketplace model when liquidity is high, but results in larger lender surplus and credit provision, and only moderately lower platform profits, when liquidity is low.
本文研究了网络债务众筹从“点对点”模式向“市场”模式转变的福利效应,即众筹平台向投资者出售多样化的贷款组合。我们开发了一个债务众筹平衡模型,捕捉平台设计(点对点或市场)和贷款人对贷款和投资组合产品特征的偏好,并在中国一家大型在线平台的新型信贷数据库上进行了估计。从点对点模式转向市场模式,增加了出借人的盈余、平台的利润和信贷供应。与此同时,减少贷款机构对流动性风险的敞口可能是有益的。当流动性高时,平台类似于银行承担流动性风险的反事实情景具有与市场模型相似的福利属性,但会导致更大的贷款人盈余和信贷供应,而当流动性低时,平台利润只会适度降低。
{"title":"The Value of \"New\" and \"Old\" Intermediation in Online Debt Crowdfunding","authors":"F. Braggion, A. Manconi, Nicola Pavanini, Haikun Zhu","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3557942","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3557942","url":null,"abstract":"We study the welfare effects of the transition of online debt crowdfunding from the older \"peer-to-peer\" model to the \"marketplace\" model, where the crowdfunding platform sells diversified loan portfolios to investor. We develop an equilibrium model of debt crowdfunding capturing platform design (peer-to-peer or marketplace) and lender preferences over loan and portfolio product characteristics, and we estimate it on a novel database on credit at a large online platform based in China. Moving from the peer-to-peer to the marketplace model raises lender surplus, platform profits, and credit provision. At the same time, reducing lender exposure to liquidity risk can be beneficial. A counterfactual scenario where the platform resembles a bank by bearing liquidity risk has similar welfare properties as the marketplace model when liquidity is high, but results in larger lender surplus and credit provision, and only moderately lower platform profits, when liquidity is low.","PeriodicalId":9906,"journal":{"name":"CEPR: Financial Economics (Topic)","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2020-05-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"83143212","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2
期刊
CEPR: Financial Economics (Topic)
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1