首页 > 最新文献

Public Economics: Publicly Provided Goods eJournal最新文献

英文 中文
Happiness and the Quality of Government 幸福与政府质量
Pub Date : 2020-03-01 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3710415
J. Helliwell, Haifang Huang, Shun Wang
This chapter uses happiness data to assess the quality of government. Our happiness data are drawn from the Gallup World Poll, starting in 2005 and extending to 2017 or 2018. In our analysis of the panel of more than 150 countries and generally over 1,500 national-level observations, we show that government delivery quality is significantly correlated with national happiness, but democratic quality is not. We also analyze other quality of government indicators. Confidence in government is correlated with happiness, however forms of democracy and government spending seem not. We further discuss three channels (including peace and conflict, trust, and inequality) whereby quality of government and happiness are linked. We finally summarize what has been learned about how government policies could be formed to improve citizens’ happiness.
本章使用幸福感数据来评估政府的质量。我们的幸福数据来自盖洛普世界民意调查,从2005年开始,一直持续到2017年或2018年。在我们对150多个国家和1500多个国家级观察结果的分析中,我们发现政府的交付质量与国民幸福感显著相关,但民主质量却不是。我们还分析了其他政府质量指标。对政府的信心与幸福感相关,但民主形式和政府支出似乎无关。我们进一步讨论了三个渠道(包括和平与冲突、信任和不平等),从而将政府质量与幸福联系起来。最后,我们总结了关于如何制定政府政策以提高公民幸福感的经验。
{"title":"Happiness and the Quality of Government","authors":"J. Helliwell, Haifang Huang, Shun Wang","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3710415","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3710415","url":null,"abstract":"This chapter uses happiness data to assess the quality of government. Our happiness data are drawn from the Gallup World Poll, starting in 2005 and extending to 2017 or 2018. In our analysis of the panel of more than 150 countries and generally over 1,500 national-level observations, we show that government delivery quality is significantly correlated with national happiness, but democratic quality is not. We also analyze other quality of government indicators. Confidence in government is correlated with happiness, however forms of democracy and government spending seem not. We further discuss three channels (including peace and conflict, trust, and inequality) whereby quality of government and happiness are linked. We finally summarize what has been learned about how government policies could be formed to improve citizens’ happiness.","PeriodicalId":113748,"journal":{"name":"Public Economics: Publicly Provided Goods eJournal","volume":"1 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2020-03-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"130013501","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 12
What Is Socialism Today? Conceptions of a Cooperative Economy 今天的社会主义是什么?合作经济的概念
Pub Date : 2020-01-21 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3524617
J. Roemer
Socialism is back on the political agenda in the United States. Politicians and some economists who identify as socialists, however, do not discuss property relations, a topic that was central in the intellectual history of socialism, but rather limit themselves to advocacy of economic reforms, funded through taxation, that would tilt the income distribution in favor of the disadvantaged in society. In the absence of a more precise discussion of property relations, the presumption must be that ownership of firms would remain private or corporate with privately owned shares. This formula is identified with the Nordic and other western European social democracies. In this article, I propose several variants of socialism, which are characterized by different kinds of property relation in the ownership of society's firms. In addition to varying property relations, I include as part of socialism a conception of what it means for a socialist society to possess a cooperative ethos, in place of the individualistic ethos of capitalist society. Differences in ethea are modeled as differences in the manner in which economic agents optimize. With an individualistic ethos, economic agents optimize in the manner of John Nash, while under a cooperative ethos, many optimize in the manner of Immanuel Kant. It is shown that Kantian optimization can decentralize resource allocation in ways that neatly separate issues of income distribution from those of efficiency. In particular, remuneration of labor and capital contributions to production need no longer be linked to marginal-product pricing of these factors, as is the key to efficiency with capitalist property relations. I present simulations of socialist income distributions, and offer some tentative conclusions concerning how we should conceive of socialism today.
社会主义又回到了美国的政治议程上。然而,自认为是社会主义者的政治家和一些经济学家不讨论财产关系,这是社会主义思想史上的一个核心话题,而是将自己局限于倡导经济改革,通过税收资助,这将使收入分配向有利于社会弱势群体的方向倾斜。在缺乏对财产关系的更精确讨论的情况下,我们的假设必须是,公司的所有权仍将是私人的,或者是拥有私人股份的公司。北欧和其他西欧社会民主国家都认同这一模式。在这篇文章中,我提出了社会主义的几种变体,它们的特征是社会企业所有权中不同类型的财产关系。除了不同的财产关系之外,我还将社会主义的一个概念作为社会主义的一部分,即社会主义社会拥有合作精神,取代资本主义社会的个人主义精神意味着什么。以太的差异被建模为经济主体优化方式的差异。在个人主义精神下,经济主体以约翰·纳什的方式进行优化,而在合作精神下,许多经济主体以康德的方式进行优化。研究表明,康德的最优化可以分散资源配置,将收入分配问题与效率问题巧妙地分离开来。特别是,劳动报酬和资本对生产的贡献不再需要与这些因素的边际产品定价挂钩,而这是资本主义财产关系中效率的关键。我提出了社会主义收入分配的模拟,并提供了一些关于我们今天应该如何设想社会主义的初步结论。
{"title":"What Is Socialism Today? Conceptions of a Cooperative Economy","authors":"J. Roemer","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3524617","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3524617","url":null,"abstract":"Socialism is back on the political agenda in the United States. Politicians and some economists who identify as socialists, however, do not discuss property relations, a topic that was central in the intellectual history of socialism, but rather limit themselves to advocacy of economic reforms, funded through taxation, that would tilt the income distribution in favor of the disadvantaged in society. In the absence of a more precise discussion of property relations, the presumption must be that ownership of firms would remain private or corporate with privately owned shares. This formula is identified with the Nordic and other western European social democracies. In this article, I propose several variants of socialism, which are characterized by different kinds of property relation in the ownership of society's firms. In addition to varying property relations, I include as part of socialism a conception of what it means for a socialist society to possess a cooperative ethos, in place of the individualistic ethos of capitalist society. Differences in ethea are modeled as differences in the manner in which economic agents optimize. With an individualistic ethos, economic agents optimize in the manner of John Nash, while under a cooperative ethos, many optimize in the manner of Immanuel Kant. It is shown that Kantian optimization can decentralize resource allocation in ways that neatly separate issues of income distribution from those of efficiency. In particular, remuneration of labor and capital contributions to production need no longer be linked to marginal-product pricing of these factors, as is the key to efficiency with capitalist property relations. I present simulations of socialist income distributions, and offer some tentative conclusions concerning how we should conceive of socialism today.","PeriodicalId":113748,"journal":{"name":"Public Economics: Publicly Provided Goods eJournal","volume":"230 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2020-01-21","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"128480441","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 6
Of the People, by the People, for the People? The European Union’s Experience with Private Environmental Regulation and Enforcement 民有、民治、民享?欧盟在私人环境监管和执法方面的经验
Pub Date : 2019-12-12 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3502800
S. Kingston, Edwin Alblas
The recent Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC) report on the difference between a global temperature rise of 1.5°C and 2°C is clear in its conclusions: every half a degree counts. Capping temperature rises at 1.5°C would significantly limit our exposure to extreme weather, droughts and rising water levels, but would require ‘rapid and far-reaching transitions in land, energy, industry, buildings, transport and cities’. As the 2018 Nobel prize winner William D Nordhaus concludes, however, the reality is that ‘most countries are on a business-as-usual (BAU) trajectory of minimal policies to reduce their emissions, taking non-cooperative policies that are in their national interest, but far from ones which would represent a global cooperative policy’.
最近政府间气候变化专门委员会(IPCC)关于全球气温上升1.5°C和2°C之间的差异的报告在其结论中很明确:每半度都很重要。将气温上升控制在1.5摄氏度将大大限制我们对极端天气、干旱和水位上升的影响,但这需要“土地、能源、工业、建筑、交通和城市迅速而深远的转变”。然而,正如2018年诺贝尔奖得主威廉·D·诺德豪斯(William D . Nordhaus)所总结的那样,现实情况是“大多数国家都在采取一切照原(BAU)的方式,采取最低限度的减排政策,采取符合其国家利益的非合作政策,但远非代表全球合作政策”。
{"title":"Of the People, by the People, for the People? The European Union’s Experience with Private Environmental Regulation and Enforcement","authors":"S. Kingston, Edwin Alblas","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3502800","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3502800","url":null,"abstract":"The recent Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC) report on the difference between a global temperature rise of 1.5°C and 2°C is clear in its conclusions: every half a degree counts. Capping temperature rises at 1.5°C would significantly limit our exposure to extreme weather, droughts and rising water levels, but would require ‘rapid and far-reaching transitions in land, energy, industry, buildings, transport and cities’. \u0000 \u0000As the 2018 Nobel prize winner William D Nordhaus concludes, however, the reality is that ‘most countries are on a business-as-usual (BAU) trajectory of minimal policies to reduce their emissions, taking non-cooperative policies that are in their national interest, but far from ones which would represent a global cooperative policy’.","PeriodicalId":113748,"journal":{"name":"Public Economics: Publicly Provided Goods eJournal","volume":"45 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2019-12-12","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"117145200","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2
Group Incentives for the Public Good: A Field Experiment on Improving the Urban Environment 公共利益的群体激励:改善城市环境的实地实验
Pub Date : 2019-12-01 DOI: 10.1596/1813-9450-9087
C. Newman, T. Mitchell, Marcus Holmlund, Chloë Fernandez
How to effectively maintain communal spaces is an important concern in many developing countries, particularly in urban environments. But what strategies can communities use to overcome the public goods problems involved in maintaining their local environment? In this paper, we investigate whether changing the incentives for a subset of the community to contribute to the public good can lead to a shift to a more efficient equilibrium for the community as a whole. We use a randomized controlled trial to test the effectiveness of a program called “Operation Clean Neighborhood”, which targets established Community Based Organizations and encourages them, through social recognition and low-value in-kind incentives, to work towards keeping their neighborhoods clean, with the ultimate goal of also reducing flooding in these areas. After one year, we find that our intervention is effective in engaging communities and in improving the cleanliness of the neighborhood and also find evidence that this leads to reduced levels of flooding. We uncover important differences in the effectiveness of the program between areas which have had increased investment in drainage infrastructure and those which have not. In our analysis we also address the issue of spillovers, an important consideration in densely populated urban centers.
如何有效地维护公共空间是许多发展中国家关注的一个重要问题,特别是在城市环境中。但是,社区可以使用什么策略来克服维护当地环境所涉及的公共产品问题呢?在本文中,我们研究了改变社区的一部分人对公共利益做出贡献的激励是否会导致整个社区转向更有效的均衡。我们使用随机对照试验来测试“清洁社区行动”项目的有效性,该项目以已建立的社区组织为目标,通过社会认可和低价值的实物奖励,鼓励他们努力保持社区清洁,最终目标是减少这些地区的洪水。一年后,我们发现我们的干预措施在吸引社区参与和改善社区清洁方面是有效的,并且有证据表明这可以减少洪水的发生。我们发现,在增加排水基础设施投资的地区和没有增加投资的地区之间,该计划的有效性存在重要差异。在我们的分析中,我们还解决了溢出问题,这是人口密集的城市中心的一个重要考虑因素。
{"title":"Group Incentives for the Public Good: A Field Experiment on Improving the Urban Environment","authors":"C. Newman, T. Mitchell, Marcus Holmlund, Chloë Fernandez","doi":"10.1596/1813-9450-9087","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1596/1813-9450-9087","url":null,"abstract":"How to effectively maintain communal spaces is an important concern in many developing countries, particularly in urban environments. But what strategies can communities use to overcome the public goods problems involved in maintaining their local environment? In this paper, we investigate whether changing the incentives for a subset of the community to contribute to the public good can lead to a shift to a more efficient equilibrium for the community as a whole. We use a randomized controlled trial to test the effectiveness of a program called “Operation Clean Neighborhood”, which targets established Community Based Organizations and encourages them, through social recognition and low-value in-kind incentives, to work towards keeping their neighborhoods clean, with the ultimate goal of also reducing flooding in these areas. After one year, we find that our intervention is effective in engaging communities and in improving the cleanliness of the neighborhood and also find evidence that this leads to reduced levels of flooding. We uncover important differences in the effectiveness of the program between areas which have had increased investment in drainage infrastructure and those which have not. In our analysis we also address the issue of spillovers, an important consideration in densely populated urban centers.","PeriodicalId":113748,"journal":{"name":"Public Economics: Publicly Provided Goods eJournal","volume":"49 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2019-12-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"124622219","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2
'No Drugs in My Back Yard:' the Ambivalent Reception of Cannabis Retailers “我家后院没有毒品”:大麻零售商的矛盾态度
Pub Date : 2019-09-30 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3461820
L. M. Bruijn, Rafael P. Ribas
Can individuals' aversion to drug markets curb the benefits of decriminalization? We investigate the effect of two policies on housing demand in the Netherlands: the distance-to-school criterion, which closed some cannabis shops in a few cities; and the zero-tolerance policy, which banned shops within municipal jurisdictions. While a small increase in the distance to retailers raised house prices by 1-5%, a substantial increase reduced them by 1-6%. Both policies reduced property crime, but the zero-tolerance was also related to fewer jobs. Our findings reveal that cities benefit from having cannabis shops, but households' aversion to related nuisances depreciates surrounding areas.
个人对毒品市场的厌恶会抑制非犯罪化的好处吗?我们调查了荷兰两项政策对住房需求的影响:距离学校标准,关闭了一些城市的一些大麻商店;零容忍政策,禁止在市政管辖范围内开店。虽然距离零售商的距离的小幅增加会使房价上涨1-5%,但大幅增加会使房价下降1-6%。这两项政策都减少了财产犯罪,但零容忍也与就业减少有关。我们的研究结果表明,城市从大麻商店中受益,但家庭对相关滋扰的厌恶使周边地区贬值。
{"title":"'No Drugs in My Back Yard:' the Ambivalent Reception of Cannabis Retailers","authors":"L. M. Bruijn, Rafael P. Ribas","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3461820","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3461820","url":null,"abstract":"Can individuals' aversion to drug markets curb the benefits of decriminalization? We investigate the effect of two policies on housing demand in the Netherlands: the distance-to-school criterion, which closed some cannabis shops in a few cities; and the zero-tolerance policy, which banned shops within municipal jurisdictions. While a small increase in the distance to retailers raised house prices by 1-5%, a substantial increase reduced them by 1-6%. Both policies reduced property crime, but the zero-tolerance was also related to fewer jobs. Our findings reveal that cities benefit from having cannabis shops, but households' aversion to related nuisances depreciates surrounding areas.","PeriodicalId":113748,"journal":{"name":"Public Economics: Publicly Provided Goods eJournal","volume":"63 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2019-09-30","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"126647402","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Between Ostrom and Nordhaus: The Research Landscape of Sustainability Economics 奥斯特罗姆与诺德豪斯之间:可持续经济学的研究格局
Pub Date : 2019-07-03 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3503315
Moritz A. Drupp, Stefan Baumgärtner, Moritz Meyer, M. Quaas, H. von Wehrden
We survey the emerging research area of sustainability economics through a quantitative full-text analysis of peer-reviewed journal publications from 1987 to 2013. To identify relevant contributions, we draw on existing definitions of sustainability economics for a keyword-based identification strategy: a combined focus on (a) the human-nature relationship, (b) the long-term uncertain future, (c) normative orientation towards sustainability, and (d) economic analysis. Our analysis of a random subsample of 343 relevant papers reveals that (i) sustainability economics is a rapidly developing research area; (ii) while theoretical contributions shaped the area in earlier years, applied work now constitutes the largest share of contributions; (iii) the research landscape can be clustered into eleven research clusters. These range from participatory governance of social-ecological systems associated with the work of Elinor Ostrom to questions of intertemporal allocation and distribution applied to climate economics associated with the work of William Nordhaus; (iv) the research area is broad in scope and heterogeneous, and there is relatively little interaction between important clusters; (v) relevant contributions are published in more than 100 journals. Ten journals publish half of all contributions, led by Ecological Economics, and 40% appear in non-economics journals, underscoring the importance of interdisciplinary dialogue.
我们通过对1987年至2013年同行评议期刊出版物的定量全文分析,调查了可持续发展经济学这一新兴研究领域。为了确定相关贡献,我们借鉴了可持续发展经济学的现有定义,制定了基于关键字的识别策略:综合关注(a)人与自然的关系,(b)长期不确定的未来,(c)可持续发展的规范取向,以及(d)经济分析。我们对343篇相关论文的随机抽样分析表明:(1)可持续经济学是一个快速发展的研究领域;虽然理论贡献在早些年塑造了这一领域,但现在应用工作占贡献的最大份额;(iii)研究景观可分为11个研究集群。从与埃莉诺·奥斯特罗姆的工作相关的社会生态系统的参与式治理到与威廉·诺德豪斯的工作相关的气候经济学的跨期分配和分配问题;(四)研究领域范围广,异质性强,重要集群之间的相互作用相对较少;(五)相关论文在100种以上期刊上发表。以生态经济学为首的10个期刊发表了所有贡献的一半,40%出现在非经济学期刊上,强调了跨学科对话的重要性。
{"title":"Between Ostrom and Nordhaus: The Research Landscape of Sustainability Economics","authors":"Moritz A. Drupp, Stefan Baumgärtner, Moritz Meyer, M. Quaas, H. von Wehrden","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3503315","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3503315","url":null,"abstract":"We survey the emerging research area of sustainability economics through a quantitative full-text analysis of peer-reviewed journal publications from 1987 to 2013. To identify relevant contributions, we draw on existing definitions of sustainability economics for a keyword-based identification strategy: a combined focus on (a) the human-nature relationship, (b) the long-term uncertain future, (c) normative orientation towards sustainability, and (d) economic analysis. Our analysis of a random subsample of 343 relevant papers reveals that (i) sustainability economics is a rapidly developing research area; (ii) while theoretical contributions shaped the area in earlier years, applied work now constitutes the largest share of contributions; (iii) the research landscape can be clustered into eleven research clusters. These range from participatory governance of social-ecological systems associated with the work of Elinor Ostrom to questions of intertemporal allocation and distribution applied to climate economics associated with the work of William Nordhaus; (iv) the research area is broad in scope and heterogeneous, and there is relatively little interaction between important clusters; (v) relevant contributions are published in more than 100 journals. Ten journals publish half of all contributions, led by Ecological Economics, and 40% appear in non-economics journals, underscoring the importance of interdisciplinary dialogue.","PeriodicalId":113748,"journal":{"name":"Public Economics: Publicly Provided Goods eJournal","volume":"14 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2019-07-03","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"129803595","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 7
Unravelling Hidden Inequities in a Universal Public Long-Term Care System 揭示普遍公共长期护理体系中隐藏的不公平现象
Pub Date : 2019-01-29 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3329198
Pilar García-Gómez, Helena M Hernández-Pizarro, G. López Casasnovas, J. Vidiella-Martin
We investigate whether publicly subsidized long-term care (LTC) is allocated according to needs, independently from income, using administrative data from all applicants for public LTC in Catalonia, from 2011 to 2014. We measure the level of horizontal inequity in subsidies to compensate informal care costs, formal home care, and institutional care using objective detailed information on needs. Our findings suggest that the system is inequitable; cash transfers are distributed among the financially better-off, while the use of nursing homes is concentrated among the worse-off. Additionally, we assess the inequity in the form of provision (voucher versus in- kind) and its implications for the equity in the time to access. Our results show that while in-kind provision is concentrated among the worse-off, the better-off are more likely to receive a voucher to (partly) subsidize LTC expenses. However, this duality does not imply inequity in the time to access a nursing home.
我们使用2011年至2014年加泰罗尼亚所有公共长期护理申请人的行政数据,调查公共补贴长期护理(LTC)是否根据需求而独立于收入进行分配。我们使用客观详细的需求信息来衡量补偿非正式护理成本、正式家庭护理和机构护理的补贴水平的不平等程度。我们的研究结果表明,该系统是不公平的;现金转移支付分配给经济状况较好的人,而养老院的使用则集中在经济状况较差的人身上。此外,我们评估了提供形式的不平等(代金券与实物)及其对获得时间的公平的影响。我们的研究结果表明,虽然实物供应集中在较贫穷的人群中,但较富裕的人群更有可能获得代金券(部分)补贴LTC费用。然而,这种两重性并不意味着进入养老院的时间不平等。
{"title":"Unravelling Hidden Inequities in a Universal Public Long-Term Care System","authors":"Pilar García-Gómez, Helena M Hernández-Pizarro, G. López Casasnovas, J. Vidiella-Martin","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3329198","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3329198","url":null,"abstract":"We investigate whether publicly subsidized long-term care (LTC) is allocated according to needs, independently from income, using administrative data from all applicants for public LTC in Catalonia, from 2011 to 2014. We measure the level of horizontal inequity in subsidies to compensate informal care costs, formal home care, and institutional care using objective detailed information on needs. Our findings suggest that the system is inequitable; cash transfers are distributed among the financially better-off, while the use of nursing homes is concentrated among the worse-off. Additionally, we assess the inequity in the form of provision (voucher versus in- kind) and its implications for the equity in the time to access. Our results show that while in-kind provision is concentrated among the worse-off, the better-off are more likely to receive a voucher to (partly) subsidize LTC expenses. However, this duality does not imply inequity in the time to access a nursing home.","PeriodicalId":113748,"journal":{"name":"Public Economics: Publicly Provided Goods eJournal","volume":"6 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2019-01-29","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"132083075","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
The Limit of Evil: Effects of Inflation and Public Debt on Capital Market Development 邪恶的极限:通货膨胀和公共债务对资本市场发展的影响
Pub Date : 2019-01-24 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3330936
David Leung, Wenzhe Li, A. Wong, Jiayue Zhang
It is almost self-evident that capital markets can thrive only in a benign macroeconomic environment. What is often overlooked is that malign macro factors such as inflation and government debt, provided that they are kept under control, can have their bright sides. Previous studies typically presume that the impact of inflation or government debt on capital market development is monotonic, thus precluding the possibility that these factors could be beneficial within a certain limit or threshold. In this study, we take into account this possibility. Our study finds an inverted U-shaped relationship between inflation and the size of the stock market. Hence, inflation within a certain limit may act as a lubricant to the market and help lower the cost of capital in real terms. However, when inflation is too high, long-term investment decisions would be difficult, which is detrimental to stock market growth. An inverted U-shaped relationship is also found between the size of the government bond market and that of the corporate bond market. This suggests that public debt under a certain threshold can benefit corporate bond market development, supporting the notion that the sovereign yield curve plays an important role in pricing private sector debt securities. However, excessive public debt would stifle it.
资本市场只有在良好的宏观经济环境下才能繁荣,这几乎是不言而喻的。人们常常忽视的是,通胀和政府债务等恶性宏观因素,只要得到控制,也有好的一面。以往的研究通常假设通货膨胀或政府债务对资本市场发展的影响是单调的,从而排除了这些因素在一定限度或阈值内有益的可能性。在这项研究中,我们考虑到了这种可能性。我们的研究发现通货膨胀和股票市场规模之间呈倒u型关系。因此,在一定范围内的通货膨胀可能会成为市场的润滑剂,并有助于降低实际资本成本。然而,当通胀过高时,长期投资决策将变得困难,这不利于股市增长。政府债券市场规模与公司债券市场规模之间也存在倒u型关系。这表明,一定门槛下的公共债务有利于公司债券市场的发展,支持了主权收益率曲线在为私人部门债务证券定价方面发挥重要作用的观点。然而,过多的公共债务会扼杀它。
{"title":"The Limit of Evil: Effects of Inflation and Public Debt on Capital Market Development","authors":"David Leung, Wenzhe Li, A. Wong, Jiayue Zhang","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3330936","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3330936","url":null,"abstract":"It is almost self-evident that capital markets can thrive only in a benign macroeconomic environment. What is often overlooked is that malign macro factors such as inflation and government debt, provided that they are kept under control, can have their bright sides. Previous studies typically presume that the impact of inflation or government debt on capital market development is monotonic, thus precluding the possibility that these factors could be beneficial within a certain limit or threshold. In this study, we take into account this possibility. Our study finds an inverted U-shaped relationship between inflation and the size of the stock market. Hence, inflation within a certain limit may act as a lubricant to the market and help lower the cost of capital in real terms. However, when inflation is too high, long-term investment decisions would be difficult, which is detrimental to stock market growth. An inverted U-shaped relationship is also found between the size of the government bond market and that of the corporate bond market. This suggests that public debt under a certain threshold can benefit corporate bond market development, supporting the notion that the sovereign yield curve plays an important role in pricing private sector debt securities. However, excessive public debt would stifle it.","PeriodicalId":113748,"journal":{"name":"Public Economics: Publicly Provided Goods eJournal","volume":"45 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2019-01-24","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"128273466","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Higher Education: Too Much of a (Potentially) Good Thing? 高等教育:好事太多(潜在的)?
Pub Date : 2019-01-10 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3313535
Omer Kimhi, Tammy Harel Ben-Shahar
Recent decades have seen a dramatic expansion in higher education. Americans are accessing higher education at growing rates, at the undergraduate level and beyond. While this process is widely celebrated, this Article argues that the proliferation of higher education has, also, a dark side. Through a myriad of empirical evidence, we show that American higher education is plagued by an 'arms race'. Individuals acquire more education than is needed for performing their job or for personal growth, in order to gain an edge in a competitive job market. As people gain more education, employers become more selective, further fueling the educational arms-race. The Article argues that this arms-race is both socially wasteful and unjust. It is wasteful because enormous resources are invested by individuals and the public on higher education, without increasing work productivity or contributing to economic growth. It is unjust because it benefits those who can afford to study, while others are either forced to incur huge debt to fund education, or are left with low- paying menial jobs. The article then discusses several legal solutions aimed at mitigating the educational arms-race. The suggestions are designed to target only cases in which the expansion in higher education is indeed inefficient and unjust, rather than to restrict higher education generally. The first suggestion involves “banning the higher education box�?, namely considering higher education requirements discriminatory when they are unjustified by a business necessity and cause racial disparity. Second, we offer imposing a “Signaling Fee�? on employers upon hiring overeducated workers; and third we propose encouraging practices of lifelong learning and on-the-job-training. Adopting these (and perhaps other) measures is crucial for reversing the educational arms race and safeguarding higher education as the socially beneficial institution it should be.
近几十年来,高等教育急剧扩张。美国人接受高等教育的比例越来越高,包括本科及以上阶段。虽然这一过程广受赞誉,但本文认为,高等教育的扩散也有其阴暗面。通过大量的经验证据,我们表明美国高等教育受到“军备竞赛”的困扰。为了在竞争激烈的就业市场中获得优势,个人接受的教育超过了履行工作或个人成长所需的教育。随着人们接受更多的教育,雇主变得更加挑剔,进一步加剧了教育军备竞赛。文章认为,这种军备竞赛既浪费社会资源,又不公平。这是一种浪费,因为个人和公众在高等教育上投入了大量资源,而没有提高工作效率或促进经济增长。这是不公平的,因为它有利于那些有能力学习的人,而其他人要么被迫承担巨额债务来资助教育,要么只能从事低薪的卑微工作。文章随后讨论了旨在减轻教育军备竞赛的几种法律解决办法。这些建议只针对那些高等教育的扩张确实效率低下和不公平的情况,而不是普遍限制高等教育。第一个建议是“禁止高等教育包厢”。即认为高等教育要求是歧视性的,因为它们不符合商业需要,并导致种族差异。第二,我们提供征收“信号费”的服务。雇主雇用受教育程度过高的工人;第三,我们建议鼓励终身学习和在职培训。采取这些(或许还有其他)措施,对于扭转教育军备竞赛和保障高等教育成为对社会有益的机构至关重要。
{"title":"Higher Education: Too Much of a (Potentially) Good Thing?","authors":"Omer Kimhi, Tammy Harel Ben-Shahar","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3313535","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3313535","url":null,"abstract":"Recent decades have seen a dramatic expansion in higher education. Americans are accessing higher education at growing rates, at the undergraduate level and beyond. While this process is widely celebrated, this Article argues that the proliferation of higher education has, also, a dark side. Through a myriad of empirical evidence, we show that American higher education is plagued by an 'arms race'. Individuals acquire more education than is needed for performing their job or for personal growth, in order to gain an edge in a competitive job market. As people gain more education, employers become more selective, further fueling the educational arms-race. The Article argues that this arms-race is both socially wasteful and unjust. It is wasteful because enormous resources are invested by individuals and the public on higher education, without increasing work productivity or contributing to economic growth. It is unjust because it benefits those who can afford to study, while others are either forced to incur huge debt to fund education, or are left with low- paying menial jobs. The article then discusses several legal solutions aimed at mitigating the educational arms-race. The suggestions are designed to target only cases in which the expansion in higher education is indeed inefficient and unjust, rather than to restrict higher education generally. The first suggestion involves “banning the higher education box�?, namely considering higher education requirements discriminatory when they are unjustified by a business necessity and cause racial disparity. Second, we offer imposing a “Signaling Fee�? on employers upon hiring overeducated workers; and third we propose encouraging practices of lifelong learning and on-the-job-training. Adopting these (and perhaps other) measures is crucial for reversing the educational arms race and safeguarding higher education as the socially beneficial institution it should be.","PeriodicalId":113748,"journal":{"name":"Public Economics: Publicly Provided Goods eJournal","volume":"31 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2019-01-10","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"116369042","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Time Horizon of Government and Public Goods Investment: Evidence From Japan 政府与公共产品投资的时间跨度:来自日本的证据
Pub Date : 2018-12-20 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3147815
J. Yamasaki
Abstract Whether the longer tenure of political agents leads to better public policies is a central question in political economy. Tenure security extends the time horizons of dictators, which may explain economic growth under extractive institutions. This study estimates the causal impact of longer time horizons of local dictators using sub-national data from 17th-century Japan. Local lords at that time faced the risk of transferring their domains by order of the central government. In 1651, the death of the executive leader of the central government caused a policy reform, and it disproportionally reduced the transfer risk faced by particular local lords (insiders) for plausibly exogenous reasons. By digitizing the historical dataset and using the difference-in-differences method, I find relatively greater agricultural investment in insiders' domains after 1651. Supplemental analyses indicate that this effect is driven by the longer time horizon channel rather than the career concern or local experience channel.
政治代理人的任期越长是否会带来更好的公共政策是政治经济学中的一个核心问题。使用权保障延长了独裁者的时间跨度,这或许可以解释榨取制度下的经济增长。这项研究利用17世纪日本的次国家级数据,估计了地方独裁者长期执政的因果影响。当时的地方领主面临着被中央政府命令转移领地的风险。1651年,中央政府执行领袖的去世引发了一场政策改革,它不成比例地降低了某些地方领主(局内人)因似是而非的外生原因而面临的转移风险。通过对历史数据进行数字化处理,并采用差中差法,我发现1651年以后,农业在业内人士领域的投资相对较大。补充分析表明,这种影响是由更长的时间范围渠道驱动的,而不是职业关注或当地经验渠道。
{"title":"Time Horizon of Government and Public Goods Investment: Evidence From Japan","authors":"J. Yamasaki","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3147815","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3147815","url":null,"abstract":"Abstract Whether the longer tenure of political agents leads to better public policies is a central question in political economy. Tenure security extends the time horizons of dictators, which may explain economic growth under extractive institutions. This study estimates the causal impact of longer time horizons of local dictators using sub-national data from 17th-century Japan. Local lords at that time faced the risk of transferring their domains by order of the central government. In 1651, the death of the executive leader of the central government caused a policy reform, and it disproportionally reduced the transfer risk faced by particular local lords (insiders) for plausibly exogenous reasons. By digitizing the historical dataset and using the difference-in-differences method, I find relatively greater agricultural investment in insiders' domains after 1651. Supplemental analyses indicate that this effect is driven by the longer time horizon channel rather than the career concern or local experience channel.","PeriodicalId":113748,"journal":{"name":"Public Economics: Publicly Provided Goods eJournal","volume":"31 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2018-12-20","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"129005991","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 4
期刊
Public Economics: Publicly Provided Goods eJournal
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1