首页 > 最新文献

Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag.最新文献

英文 中文
Scan Based Trading and Bargaining Equilibrium: A Structural Estimation of Supply Chain Profit 基于扫描的交易与议价均衡:供应链利润的结构性估计
Pub Date : 2022-03-17 DOI: 10.1287/msom.2022.1087
S. Lim, T. Richards, E. Rabinovich, Min Choi
Problem definition: Scan based trading (SBT) represents a type of replenishment system in which the supplier retains title until the product is scanned through checkout at the retail store by the consumer. Although SBT carries potential benefits for both parties in the supplier-retailer dyad, it may also yield asymmetric gains to these parties, particularly because SBT can impose greater inventory costs to suppliers through shrink. We document the financial benefits in terms of supply chain profit creation and allocation based on the differences in bargaining power between parties in a vertical channel under SBT vis-à-vis the more traditional vendor-managed inventory (VMI) contracts. Academic/practical relevance: Although prior literature has examined inventory benefits and drawbacks from VMI and SBT contracts in retailer-supplier dyads, it has failed to offer a systematic evaluation of the relative impact of these contract forms on bargaining power and profits in these dyads. We address this knowledge gap. Methodology: To that end, we use a methodological approach that incorporates an empirical Nash-in-Nash bargaining model, a supplementary regression, and a counterfactual simulation. Results: We find that retailer bargaining power is higher under SBT relative to VMI contracts. Moreover, the direct effects of a retailer switching from VMI to SBT regimes generate an average increase of 25% in total supply chain profit, allowing the retailer and its supplier to increase their profit by 20% and 29%, respectively. However, although the retailer’s profit share decreases by approximately 3.5%, the supplier’s increases by about 3.3%. We attribute the decrease in the retailer’s share to a stronger bargaining position on the supplier side based on higher supplier shrink costs. Managerial implications: Our findings provide managers with more transparent information regarding the set of outcomes they can expect should they choose to enter into SBT contracts. Importantly, we show how an outcome that has significantly hindered the adoption of SBT contracts (i.e., shrink costs) can enter into the negotiation between retailers and suppliers to optimally split the dyadic surplus of the contracts between these parties.
问题定义:基于扫描的交易(SBT)代表一种补充系统,在这种系统中,供应商保留所有权,直到消费者在零售商店通过结账扫描产品为止。尽管SBT对供应商-零售商二元关系中的双方都有潜在的好处,但它也可能给这些方带来不对称的收益,特别是因为SBT会通过收缩给供应商带来更大的库存成本。我们记录了供应链利润创造和分配方面的财务利益,这是基于垂直渠道中各方在SBT与-à-vis更传统的供应商管理库存(VMI)合同下的议价能力差异。学术/实践相关性:尽管先前的文献已经研究了零售商-供应商二元组合中VMI和SBT合同的库存利弊,但它未能对这些合同形式对这些二元组合的议价能力和利润的相对影响提供系统的评估。我们解决了这一知识鸿沟。方法:为此,我们使用了一种方法方法,该方法方法结合了经验纳什-纳什议价模型,补充回归和反事实模拟。结果:我们发现SBT契约下的零售商议价能力高于VMI契约。此外,零售商从VMI转向SBT制度的直接影响使供应链总利润平均增加25%,使零售商及其供应商的利润分别增加20%和29%。然而,尽管零售商的利润份额减少了约3.5%,供应商的利润份额却增加了约3.3%。我们将零售商份额的减少归因于供应商在更高的供应商缩减成本基础上更强的议价地位。管理启示:我们的研究结果为管理者提供了更透明的信息,说明如果他们选择进入SBT合同,他们可以预期的结果。重要的是,我们展示了一个严重阻碍SBT合同采用的结果(即缩减成本)如何进入零售商和供应商之间的谈判,以最优地分割这些当事方之间的合同的二元盈余。
{"title":"Scan Based Trading and Bargaining Equilibrium: A Structural Estimation of Supply Chain Profit","authors":"S. Lim, T. Richards, E. Rabinovich, Min Choi","doi":"10.1287/msom.2022.1087","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2022.1087","url":null,"abstract":"Problem definition: Scan based trading (SBT) represents a type of replenishment system in which the supplier retains title until the product is scanned through checkout at the retail store by the consumer. Although SBT carries potential benefits for both parties in the supplier-retailer dyad, it may also yield asymmetric gains to these parties, particularly because SBT can impose greater inventory costs to suppliers through shrink. We document the financial benefits in terms of supply chain profit creation and allocation based on the differences in bargaining power between parties in a vertical channel under SBT vis-à-vis the more traditional vendor-managed inventory (VMI) contracts. Academic/practical relevance: Although prior literature has examined inventory benefits and drawbacks from VMI and SBT contracts in retailer-supplier dyads, it has failed to offer a systematic evaluation of the relative impact of these contract forms on bargaining power and profits in these dyads. We address this knowledge gap. Methodology: To that end, we use a methodological approach that incorporates an empirical Nash-in-Nash bargaining model, a supplementary regression, and a counterfactual simulation. Results: We find that retailer bargaining power is higher under SBT relative to VMI contracts. Moreover, the direct effects of a retailer switching from VMI to SBT regimes generate an average increase of 25% in total supply chain profit, allowing the retailer and its supplier to increase their profit by 20% and 29%, respectively. However, although the retailer’s profit share decreases by approximately 3.5%, the supplier’s increases by about 3.3%. We attribute the decrease in the retailer’s share to a stronger bargaining position on the supplier side based on higher supplier shrink costs. Managerial implications: Our findings provide managers with more transparent information regarding the set of outcomes they can expect should they choose to enter into SBT contracts. Importantly, we show how an outcome that has significantly hindered the adoption of SBT contracts (i.e., shrink costs) can enter into the negotiation between retailers and suppliers to optimally split the dyadic surplus of the contracts between these parties.","PeriodicalId":18108,"journal":{"name":"Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag.","volume":"33 1","pages":"2328-2348"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2022-03-17","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"78543294","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Should We All Work in Sprints? How Agile Project Management Improves Performance 我们都应该在冲刺阶段工作吗?敏捷项目管理如何提高性能
Pub Date : 2022-03-17 DOI: 10.1287/msom.2022.1091
Tobias Lieberum, S. Schiffels, R. Kolisch
Problem definition: Agile project management, in particular Scrum, is enjoying increased use in practice despite only scant scientific validation. This article explores how agile project management impacts project performance and execution. We compare the effects of agile sprints—short-term project phases characterized by time-boxed progression from one sprint to the next and self-imposed, phase-specific output goals—with those of traditional project management. Methodology/results: We decompose the two sprint elements of time-boxed progression and self-imposed, phase-specific output goals as factors in a 2 × 2 experimental design. We then conceptualize project execution as a simple real-effort task and conduct a controlled laboratory study. For a given duration, participants perform better with time-boxed progression as, without it, that is, with flexible progression, they spend too much time on early project phases at the expense of later ones. We refer to this effect as “progression fallacy” and show how it differs from well-known behavioral effects that cause project delays. Introducing self-imposed, phase-specific output goals in combination with time-boxed progression, as proposed by Scrum, does not significantly improve performance when compared with time-boxed progression alone. However, the combination of self-imposed, phase-specific output goals and flexible progression, as is common in traditional project management, amplifies the progression fallacy with the result that goal-setting has a negative performance effect. In two control treatments, we show that the progression fallacy is robust to planning and progression prompts despite some mitigation. Managerial implications: This study contributes evidence of higher project performance when working in agile sprints, which mitigate behavioral flaws present in traditional project management. Not only do these behavioral insights apply to project management; they are also relevant in the broader context of task completion.
问题定义:敏捷项目管理,特别是Scrum,在实践中得到了越来越多的应用,尽管只有很少的科学验证。本文探讨了敏捷项目管理如何影响项目性能和执行。我们比较了敏捷冲刺与传统项目管理的效果。敏捷冲刺是指短期项目阶段,其特点是从一个冲刺到下一个冲刺的时间限制进展,以及自我强加的、特定阶段的输出目标。方法/结果:我们在2 × 2实验设计中将时间限制的进度和自我强加的、特定阶段的输出目标这两个冲刺元素分解为因素。然后,我们将项目执行概念化为一个简单的实际任务,并进行受控的实验室研究。在给定的持续时间内,参与者在有时间限制的进度下表现得更好,因为没有时间限制,也就是说,在有弹性的进度下,他们会在项目的早期阶段花费太多时间,而牺牲了后期阶段的时间。我们将这种效应称为“进展谬误”,并说明它与导致项目延迟的众所周知的行为效应有何不同。引入自我强加的、特定阶段的输出目标,结合Scrum提出的限时推进,与单独的限时推进相比,并不能显著提高性能。然而,像传统项目管理中常见的那样,将自我强加的、特定阶段的输出目标与灵活的进度相结合,放大了进度谬论,其结果是目标设定具有负面的绩效效应。在两种对照处理中,我们表明进展谬误对计划和进展提示具有鲁棒性,尽管有一些缓解。管理意义:这项研究提供了在敏捷冲刺中工作时更高的项目绩效的证据,它减轻了传统项目管理中存在的行为缺陷。这些行为洞察不仅适用于项目管理;它们在任务完成的更广泛背景下也是相关的。
{"title":"Should We All Work in Sprints? How Agile Project Management Improves Performance","authors":"Tobias Lieberum, S. Schiffels, R. Kolisch","doi":"10.1287/msom.2022.1091","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2022.1091","url":null,"abstract":"Problem definition: Agile project management, in particular Scrum, is enjoying increased use in practice despite only scant scientific validation. This article explores how agile project management impacts project performance and execution. We compare the effects of agile sprints—short-term project phases characterized by time-boxed progression from one sprint to the next and self-imposed, phase-specific output goals—with those of traditional project management. Methodology/results: We decompose the two sprint elements of time-boxed progression and self-imposed, phase-specific output goals as factors in a 2 × 2 experimental design. We then conceptualize project execution as a simple real-effort task and conduct a controlled laboratory study. For a given duration, participants perform better with time-boxed progression as, without it, that is, with flexible progression, they spend too much time on early project phases at the expense of later ones. We refer to this effect as “progression fallacy” and show how it differs from well-known behavioral effects that cause project delays. Introducing self-imposed, phase-specific output goals in combination with time-boxed progression, as proposed by Scrum, does not significantly improve performance when compared with time-boxed progression alone. However, the combination of self-imposed, phase-specific output goals and flexible progression, as is common in traditional project management, amplifies the progression fallacy with the result that goal-setting has a negative performance effect. In two control treatments, we show that the progression fallacy is robust to planning and progression prompts despite some mitigation. Managerial implications: This study contributes evidence of higher project performance when working in agile sprints, which mitigate behavioral flaws present in traditional project management. Not only do these behavioral insights apply to project management; they are also relevant in the broader context of task completion.","PeriodicalId":18108,"journal":{"name":"Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag.","volume":"91 1","pages":"2293-2309"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2022-03-17","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"79011243","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 3
Drone Network Design for Cardiac Arrest Response 心脏骤停响应无人机网络设计
Pub Date : 2022-03-03 DOI: 10.1287/msom.2022.1092
J. Boutilier, Timothy C. Y. Chan
Problem definition: Our objective is to design a defibrillator-enabled drone network that augments the existing emergency medical services (EMS) system to rapidly respond to out-of-hospital cardiac arrest (OHCA). Academic/practical relevance: OHCA claims more than 400,000 lives each year in North America and is one of the most time-sensitive medical emergencies. Drone-delivered automated external defibrillators (AEDs) have the potential to be a transformative innovation in the provision of emergency care for OHCA. Methodology: We develop an integrated location-queuing model that incorporates existing EMS response times and is based on the p-median architecture, where each base constitutes an explicit [Formula: see text] queue (i.e., Erlang loss). We then develop a reformulation technique that exploits the existing EMS response times, allowing us to solve real-world instances to optimality using an off-the-shelf solver. We evaluate our solutions using a tactical simulation model that accounts for the effects of congestion and dispatching, and we use a machine-learning model to translate our response-time reductions into survival estimates. Results: Using real data from an area covering 26,000 square kilometers around Toronto, Canada, we find that a modest number of drones are required to significantly reduce response times in all regions. An objective function that minimizes average response time results in drone resources concentrated in cities, with little impact on the tail of the distribution. In contrast, optimizing for the tail of the response-time distribution produces larger and more geographically dispersed drone networks that improve response-time equity across the regions. We estimate that the response-time reductions achieved by the drone network are associated with between a 42% and 76% higher survival rate and up to 144 additional lives saved each year across the geographical region we consider. Managerial implications: Overall, this paper provides a realistic framework that can be leveraged by system designers and/or EMS personnel seeking to investigate design questions associated with a drone network. An objective function focused on improving the tail of the response-time distribution is well-suited for use in practice because the model provides equitable solutions that reduce the entire response-time distribution and corresponds to the real-world metrics, on which EMS systems are most commonly evaluated.
问题定义:我们的目标是设计一个启用除颤器的无人机网络,以增强现有的紧急医疗服务(EMS)系统,以快速响应院外心脏骤停(OHCA)。学术/实际意义:OHCA每年在北美夺去40多万人的生命,是对时间最敏感的医疗紧急情况之一。无人机运送的自动体外除颤器(aed)有可能成为为OHCA提供紧急护理的变革性创新。方法:我们开发了一个集成的位置排队模型,该模型结合了现有的EMS响应时间,并基于p-median架构,其中每个基构成一个显式的[公式:见文本]队列(即Erlang损失)。然后,我们开发了一种利用现有EMS响应时间的重新表述技术,使我们能够使用现成的求解器解决实际实例的最优问题。我们使用战术模拟模型来评估我们的解决方案,该模型考虑了拥堵和调度的影响,我们使用机器学习模型将我们的响应时间减少转化为生存估计。结果:使用来自加拿大多伦多周围26,000平方公里区域的真实数据,我们发现需要少量的无人机来显着减少所有地区的响应时间。最小化平均响应时间的目标函数导致无人机资源集中在城市,对分布的尾部影响很小。相比之下,对响应时间分布尾部的优化会产生更大、地理上更分散的无人机网络,从而提高整个地区的响应时间公平性。我们估计,在我们考虑的地理区域内,无人机网络实现的响应时间减少与42%至76%的存活率提高有关,每年可额外挽救多达144人的生命。管理意义:总的来说,本文提供了一个现实的框架,系统设计师和/或EMS人员可以利用它来调查与无人机网络相关的设计问题。专注于改进响应时间分布尾部的目标函数非常适合在实践中使用,因为该模型提供了公平的解决方案,减少了整个响应时间分布,并与EMS系统最常评估的真实度量相对应。
{"title":"Drone Network Design for Cardiac Arrest Response","authors":"J. Boutilier, Timothy C. Y. Chan","doi":"10.1287/msom.2022.1092","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2022.1092","url":null,"abstract":"Problem definition: Our objective is to design a defibrillator-enabled drone network that augments the existing emergency medical services (EMS) system to rapidly respond to out-of-hospital cardiac arrest (OHCA). Academic/practical relevance: OHCA claims more than 400,000 lives each year in North America and is one of the most time-sensitive medical emergencies. Drone-delivered automated external defibrillators (AEDs) have the potential to be a transformative innovation in the provision of emergency care for OHCA. Methodology: We develop an integrated location-queuing model that incorporates existing EMS response times and is based on the p-median architecture, where each base constitutes an explicit [Formula: see text] queue (i.e., Erlang loss). We then develop a reformulation technique that exploits the existing EMS response times, allowing us to solve real-world instances to optimality using an off-the-shelf solver. We evaluate our solutions using a tactical simulation model that accounts for the effects of congestion and dispatching, and we use a machine-learning model to translate our response-time reductions into survival estimates. Results: Using real data from an area covering 26,000 square kilometers around Toronto, Canada, we find that a modest number of drones are required to significantly reduce response times in all regions. An objective function that minimizes average response time results in drone resources concentrated in cities, with little impact on the tail of the distribution. In contrast, optimizing for the tail of the response-time distribution produces larger and more geographically dispersed drone networks that improve response-time equity across the regions. We estimate that the response-time reductions achieved by the drone network are associated with between a 42% and 76% higher survival rate and up to 144 additional lives saved each year across the geographical region we consider. Managerial implications: Overall, this paper provides a realistic framework that can be leveraged by system designers and/or EMS personnel seeking to investigate design questions associated with a drone network. An objective function focused on improving the tail of the response-time distribution is well-suited for use in practice because the model provides equitable solutions that reduce the entire response-time distribution and corresponds to the real-world metrics, on which EMS systems are most commonly evaluated.","PeriodicalId":18108,"journal":{"name":"Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag.","volume":"123 1","pages":"2407-2424"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2022-03-03","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"83336321","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 10
Risk-Averse Bargaining in a Stochastic Optimization Context 随机优化环境下的风险规避议价
Pub Date : 2022-02-04 DOI: 10.1287/msom.2021.1076
W. Gutjahr, Raimund M. Kovacevic, D. Wozabal
Problem definition: Bargaining situations are ubiquitous in economics and management. We consider the problem of bargaining for a fair ex ante distribution of random profits arising from a cooperative effort of a fixed set of risk-averse agents. Our approach integrates optimal managerial decision making into bargaining situations with random outcomes and explicitly models the impact of risk aversion. The proposed solution rests on a firm axiomatic foundation and yet allows to compute concrete bargaining solutions for a wide range of practically relevant problems. Methodology/results: We model risk preferences using coherent acceptability functionals and base our bargaining solution on a set of axioms that can be considered a natural extension of Nash bargaining to our setting. We show that the proposed axioms fully characterize a bargaining solution, which can be efficiently computed by solving a stochastic optimization problem. We characterize special cases where random payoffs of players are simple functions of overall project profit. In particular, we show that, for players with distortion risk functionals, the optimal bargaining solution can be represented by an exchange of standard options contracts with the project profit as the underlying asset. We illustrate the concepts in the paper with a detailed example of risk-averse households that jointly invest into a solar plant. Managerial implications: We demonstrate that there is no conflict of interest between players about management decisions and that risk aversion facilitates cooperation. Furthermore, our results on the structure of optimal contracts as a basket of option contracts provides valuable guidance for negotiators.
问题定义:讨价还价的情形在经济学和管理学中无处不在。我们考虑了对一组固定的风险厌恶者的合作产生的随机利润的公平事前分配进行讨价还价的问题。我们的方法将最优管理决策整合到具有随机结果的讨价还价情况中,并明确地模拟了风险厌恶的影响。所提出的解决方案建立在一个坚实的公理基础上,并且允许为广泛的实际相关问题计算具体的议价解决方案。方法/结果:我们使用连贯的可接受函数对风险偏好进行建模,并将我们的议价解决方案建立在一组公理的基础上,这些公理可以被认为是纳什议价对我们环境的自然延伸。我们证明了所提出的公理充分表征了议价解,它可以通过求解随机优化问题来有效地计算。我们描述了一些特殊情况,其中参与者的随机收益是整个项目利润的简单函数。特别是,我们表明,对于具有扭曲风险函数的参与者,最优议价解决方案可以用以项目利润为基础资产的标准期权合约交换来表示。我们用一个共同投资太阳能发电厂的规避风险家庭的详细例子来说明本文中的概念。管理启示:我们证明了参与者之间在管理决策方面不存在利益冲突,风险规避促进了合作。此外,我们关于最优契约结构作为一篮子期权契约的研究结果为谈判者提供了有价值的指导。
{"title":"Risk-Averse Bargaining in a Stochastic Optimization Context","authors":"W. Gutjahr, Raimund M. Kovacevic, D. Wozabal","doi":"10.1287/msom.2021.1076","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2021.1076","url":null,"abstract":"Problem definition: Bargaining situations are ubiquitous in economics and management. We consider the problem of bargaining for a fair ex ante distribution of random profits arising from a cooperative effort of a fixed set of risk-averse agents. Our approach integrates optimal managerial decision making into bargaining situations with random outcomes and explicitly models the impact of risk aversion. The proposed solution rests on a firm axiomatic foundation and yet allows to compute concrete bargaining solutions for a wide range of practically relevant problems. Methodology/results: We model risk preferences using coherent acceptability functionals and base our bargaining solution on a set of axioms that can be considered a natural extension of Nash bargaining to our setting. We show that the proposed axioms fully characterize a bargaining solution, which can be efficiently computed by solving a stochastic optimization problem. We characterize special cases where random payoffs of players are simple functions of overall project profit. In particular, we show that, for players with distortion risk functionals, the optimal bargaining solution can be represented by an exchange of standard options contracts with the project profit as the underlying asset. We illustrate the concepts in the paper with a detailed example of risk-averse households that jointly invest into a solar plant. Managerial implications: We demonstrate that there is no conflict of interest between players about management decisions and that risk aversion facilitates cooperation. Furthermore, our results on the structure of optimal contracts as a basket of option contracts provides valuable guidance for negotiators.","PeriodicalId":18108,"journal":{"name":"Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag.","volume":"4 1","pages":"323-340"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2022-02-04","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"73201993","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Donations for Refugee Crises: In-kind vs. Cash Assistance 难民危机的捐赠:实物与现金援助
Pub Date : 2022-02-03 DOI: 10.1287/msom.2021.1073
Telesilla O. Kotsi, Owen Q. Wu, Alfonso J. Pedraza Martinez
Problem definition: Six million refugees have been living in camps in 2021 due to multiple armed conflicts worldwide. Regulations often impede refugees’ integration into host countries; thus, refugees have to seek help from humanitarian organizations (HOs). HOs traditionally provide in-kind (e.g., food) assistance and now offer cash (monetary assistance) that refugees can spend at local retail stores. However, cash assistance can be exploited by local retailers’ market power, which challenges HOs’ mission of helping refugees while doing no harm to host communities. Practical relevance: Completely informed by field research in three refugee camps in northwestern Greece, we analyze the trade-off between in-kind and cash assistance from the perspective of an HO. We propose two cash assistance policies, implementable by a partnership between the HO and the local government, to curb the retailer’s market power and ensure that the refugees, the local residents, and the retailer are better off than if only in-kind assistance is provided. Methodology: We use field research to define our research setting and support our main modeling assumptions and parameters. Then, we use a game-theoretical model to analyze the interactions among multiple stakeholders in an ecosystem consisting of an HO, refugees, a monopolistic retailer, local residents, and a local government. Results: We demonstrate the effectiveness of our proposed cash assistance policies that benefit refugees and local residents while ensuring the retailer’s profitability. In particular, a price-dependent cash assistance (PDCA) policy aligns the incentives between the retailer and the HO-government partnership. This new policy for cash assistance acts as a lever for the retailer to voluntarily set desirable prices, which benefit both refugees and their host community. Managerial implications: We provide tools and implementable policies that guide HOs to improve their budget allocation between in-kind and cash assistance for refugees living in areas where local market power exists. Moreover, we clearly outline the roles of HOs and the local government in a partnership for cash assistance to refugees.
问题定义:由于全球多次武装冲突,2021年有600万难民生活在难民营。规章制度往往阻碍难民融入东道国;因此,难民不得不向人道主义组织寻求帮助。HOs传统上提供实物(例如粮食)援助,现在提供现金(货币援助),难民可以在当地零售商店消费。然而,现金援助可以被当地零售商的市场力量所利用,这挑战了HOs在不损害收容社区的情况下帮助难民的使命。实际意义:通过对希腊西北部三个难民营的实地研究,我们从一个HO的角度分析了实物援助和现金援助之间的权衡。我们提出了两项现金援助政策,由世界卫生组织和当地政府合作实施,以遏制零售商的市场力量,并确保难民、当地居民和零售商比只提供实物援助更好。方法:我们使用实地调查来定义我们的研究设置,并支持我们的主要建模假设和参数。在此基础上,运用博弈论模型分析了由移民、难民、垄断性零售商、当地居民和地方政府组成的生态系统中多个利益相关者之间的相互作用。结果:我们证明了我们提出的现金援助政策的有效性,使难民和当地居民受益,同时确保零售商的盈利能力。特别是,价格相关现金援助(PDCA)政策使零售商与卫生组织-政府伙伴关系之间的激励机制保持一致。这项现金援助的新政策作为零售商自愿设定理想价格的杠杆,这对难民和他们的收容社区都有利。管理方面的影响:我们提供工具和可实施的政策,指导难民组织改善对生活在当地市场力量存在的地区的难民的实物和现金援助之间的预算分配。此外,我们明确概述了居委会和地方政府在向难民提供现金援助的伙伴关系中的作用。
{"title":"Donations for Refugee Crises: In-kind vs. Cash Assistance","authors":"Telesilla O. Kotsi, Owen Q. Wu, Alfonso J. Pedraza Martinez","doi":"10.1287/msom.2021.1073","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2021.1073","url":null,"abstract":"Problem definition: Six million refugees have been living in camps in 2021 due to multiple armed conflicts worldwide. Regulations often impede refugees’ integration into host countries; thus, refugees have to seek help from humanitarian organizations (HOs). HOs traditionally provide in-kind (e.g., food) assistance and now offer cash (monetary assistance) that refugees can spend at local retail stores. However, cash assistance can be exploited by local retailers’ market power, which challenges HOs’ mission of helping refugees while doing no harm to host communities. Practical relevance: Completely informed by field research in three refugee camps in northwestern Greece, we analyze the trade-off between in-kind and cash assistance from the perspective of an HO. We propose two cash assistance policies, implementable by a partnership between the HO and the local government, to curb the retailer’s market power and ensure that the refugees, the local residents, and the retailer are better off than if only in-kind assistance is provided. Methodology: We use field research to define our research setting and support our main modeling assumptions and parameters. Then, we use a game-theoretical model to analyze the interactions among multiple stakeholders in an ecosystem consisting of an HO, refugees, a monopolistic retailer, local residents, and a local government. Results: We demonstrate the effectiveness of our proposed cash assistance policies that benefit refugees and local residents while ensuring the retailer’s profitability. In particular, a price-dependent cash assistance (PDCA) policy aligns the incentives between the retailer and the HO-government partnership. This new policy for cash assistance acts as a lever for the retailer to voluntarily set desirable prices, which benefit both refugees and their host community. Managerial implications: We provide tools and implementable policies that guide HOs to improve their budget allocation between in-kind and cash assistance for refugees living in areas where local market power exists. Moreover, we clearly outline the roles of HOs and the local government in a partnership for cash assistance to refugees.","PeriodicalId":18108,"journal":{"name":"Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag.","volume":"1 1","pages":"3001-3018"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2022-02-03","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"77237102","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
On a Variation of Two-Part Tariff Pricing of Services: A Data-Driven Approach 基于数据驱动的服务价格两部分定价的变化研究
Pub Date : 2022-02-01 DOI: 10.1287/msom.2021.1069
G. Perakis, Charles Thraves
Problem definition: We present a data-driven pricing problem motivated from our collaboration with a satellite service provider. In particular, we study a variant of the two-part tariff pricing scheme. The firm offers a set of data plans consisting of a bundle of data at a fixed price plus additional data at a variable price. Most literature on two-part tariff problems focuses on models that assume full information. However, little attention has been devoted to this problem from a data-driven perspective without full information. One of the main challenges when working with data comes from missing data. Methodology/results: First, we develop a new method to address the missing data problem, which comes from different sources: (i) the number of unobserved customers, (ii) customers’ willingness to pay (WTP), and (iii) demand from unobserved customers. We introduce an iteration procedure to maximize the likelihood by combining the expectation maximization algorithm with a gradient ascent method. We also formulate the pricing optimization problem as a dynamic program (DP) using a discretized set of prices. From applying Sample Average Approximation, the DP obtains a solution within 3.8% of the optimal solution of the sampled instances, on average, and within 18% with 95% confidence from the optimal solution of the exact problem. By extending the DP formulation, we show that it is better to optimize on prices rather than bundles, obtaining revenues close to optimizing jointly on both. Managerial implications: The sensitivity analysis of the problem parameters is key for decision makers to understand the risks of their pricing decisions. Indeed, assuming a higher variability of customers’ WTP induces higher revenue risks. In addition, revenues are barely (highly) sensitive to the customers’ assumed WTP variability when considering a high (low) number of unobserved customers. Finally, we extend the model to incorporate price-dependent consumption.
问题定义:我们提出了一个数据驱动的定价问题,这个问题源于我们与一家卫星服务提供商的合作。特别地,我们研究了两部分关税定价方案的一种变体。该公司提供了一套数据计划,包括固定价格的捆绑数据和可变价格的附加数据。大多数关于两部分关税问题的文献都集中在假设充分信息的模型上。然而,在没有充分信息的情况下,从数据驱动的角度对这一问题的关注很少。处理数据时的主要挑战之一来自丢失的数据。方法/结果:首先,我们开发了一种新的方法来解决来自不同来源的数据缺失问题:(i)未被观察到的客户数量,(ii)客户的支付意愿(WTP), (iii)未被观察到的客户的需求。将期望最大化算法与梯度上升法相结合,提出了一种求似然最大化的迭代方法。我们还将定价优化问题表述为使用离散价格集的动态规划(DP)。通过应用样本平均近似,DP平均在抽样实例的最优解的3.8%范围内获得解决方案,并且在精确问题的最优解的95%置信度范围内获得18%的解决方案。通过扩展DP公式,我们证明了在价格上进行优化比在捆绑上进行优化更好,从而获得接近于在两者上共同优化的收益。管理意义:问题参数的敏感性分析是决策者了解其定价决策风险的关键。事实上,假设客户WTP的变异性越大,收入风险就越大。此外,当考虑到大量(少量)未观察到的客户时,收入对客户假设的WTP可变性几乎(高度)不敏感。最后,我们将模型扩展到包含价格依赖消费。
{"title":"On a Variation of Two-Part Tariff Pricing of Services: A Data-Driven Approach","authors":"G. Perakis, Charles Thraves","doi":"10.1287/msom.2021.1069","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2021.1069","url":null,"abstract":"Problem definition: We present a data-driven pricing problem motivated from our collaboration with a satellite service provider. In particular, we study a variant of the two-part tariff pricing scheme. The firm offers a set of data plans consisting of a bundle of data at a fixed price plus additional data at a variable price. Most literature on two-part tariff problems focuses on models that assume full information. However, little attention has been devoted to this problem from a data-driven perspective without full information. One of the main challenges when working with data comes from missing data. Methodology/results: First, we develop a new method to address the missing data problem, which comes from different sources: (i) the number of unobserved customers, (ii) customers’ willingness to pay (WTP), and (iii) demand from unobserved customers. We introduce an iteration procedure to maximize the likelihood by combining the expectation maximization algorithm with a gradient ascent method. We also formulate the pricing optimization problem as a dynamic program (DP) using a discretized set of prices. From applying Sample Average Approximation, the DP obtains a solution within 3.8% of the optimal solution of the sampled instances, on average, and within 18% with 95% confidence from the optimal solution of the exact problem. By extending the DP formulation, we show that it is better to optimize on prices rather than bundles, obtaining revenues close to optimizing jointly on both. Managerial implications: The sensitivity analysis of the problem parameters is key for decision makers to understand the risks of their pricing decisions. Indeed, assuming a higher variability of customers’ WTP induces higher revenue risks. In addition, revenues are barely (highly) sensitive to the customers’ assumed WTP variability when considering a high (low) number of unobserved customers. Finally, we extend the model to incorporate price-dependent consumption.","PeriodicalId":18108,"journal":{"name":"Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag.","volume":"14 1","pages":"1369-1387"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2022-02-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"73197370","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Contracting Mechanisms for Stable Sourcing Networks 稳定采购网络的契约机制
Pub Date : 2022-01-31 DOI: 10.1287/msom.2021.1066
J. Ryan, Lusheng Shao, Daewon Sun
Problem definition: We study profit allocation for a sourcing network, in which a buyer sources from a set of differentiated suppliers with limited capacity under uncertain demand for the final product. Whereas the buyer takes the lead in forming the sourcing network and designing the contract mechanism, due to their substantial bargaining power, the suppliers take the lead in determining the terms of the contract. Academic/practical relevance: We identify contracting mechanisms that will ensure the stability of the sourcing network in the long term, where a stable sourcing network requires an effective profit-allocation scheme that motivates all members to join and stay in the network. Methodology: We apply methods from game theory to model the network and analyze the Nash equilibrium of a noncooperative game under a proposed contracting mechanism. We then use a cooperative game model to study the stability of the resulting equilibrium. Results: We show that the optimal network profit, as a set function of the set of suppliers, is submodular, which allows us to demonstrate that the core of the cooperative game is not empty. We also establish a set of conditions that are equivalent to, but much simpler than, the original conditions for the core. We use these results to demonstrate that the proposed fixed-fee contracting mechanism can implement a stable network in the competitive setting by achieving a profit allocation that is in the core of the cooperative game. We also demonstrate that the grand coalition is stable in a farsighted sense under the Shapley value allocation. Managerial implications: Under the fixed-fee mechanism, the buyer’s decisions maximize the network profit, and each supplier earns a profit equal to its marginal contribution. When the aggregate capacity of the supplier network is high relative to demand, or demand is more likely to be small, the fixed-fee mechanism is likely to outperform the Shapley value allocation from the perspective of the buyer.
问题定义:我们研究了一个采购网络的利润分配问题,在这个网络中,在最终产品需求不确定的情况下,买家从一组产能有限的差异化供应商处采购。买方在采购网络的形成和合同机制的设计上处于主导地位,而供应商由于其强大的议价能力,在合同条款的确定上处于主导地位。学术/实践相关性:我们确定了确保采购网络长期稳定的合同机制,其中稳定的采购网络需要有效的利润分配方案,以激励所有成员加入并留在网络中。研究方法:运用博弈论的方法对网络进行建模,并分析了一种契约机制下非合作博弈的纳什均衡。然后,我们使用合作博弈模型来研究最终均衡的稳定性。结果:我们证明了最优网络利润作为供应商集合的集合函数是子模块的,这使得我们证明了合作博弈的核心不是空的。我们还建立了一组条件,这些条件相当于核心的原始条件,但比原始条件简单得多。我们利用这些结果证明了所提出的固定费用契约机制可以通过实现合作博弈核心的利润分配来实现竞争环境下的稳定网络。我们还证明了在Shapley值分配下,大联合政府具有远见意义上的稳定性。管理启示:在固定费用机制下,买方的决策使网络利润最大化,每个供应商获得的利润等于其边际贡献。当供应商网络的总容量相对于需求较高,或者需求更有可能较小时,从买方的角度来看,固定费用机制更有可能优于Shapley价值分配。
{"title":"Contracting Mechanisms for Stable Sourcing Networks","authors":"J. Ryan, Lusheng Shao, Daewon Sun","doi":"10.1287/msom.2021.1066","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2021.1066","url":null,"abstract":"Problem definition: We study profit allocation for a sourcing network, in which a buyer sources from a set of differentiated suppliers with limited capacity under uncertain demand for the final product. Whereas the buyer takes the lead in forming the sourcing network and designing the contract mechanism, due to their substantial bargaining power, the suppliers take the lead in determining the terms of the contract. Academic/practical relevance: We identify contracting mechanisms that will ensure the stability of the sourcing network in the long term, where a stable sourcing network requires an effective profit-allocation scheme that motivates all members to join and stay in the network. Methodology: We apply methods from game theory to model the network and analyze the Nash equilibrium of a noncooperative game under a proposed contracting mechanism. We then use a cooperative game model to study the stability of the resulting equilibrium. Results: We show that the optimal network profit, as a set function of the set of suppliers, is submodular, which allows us to demonstrate that the core of the cooperative game is not empty. We also establish a set of conditions that are equivalent to, but much simpler than, the original conditions for the core. We use these results to demonstrate that the proposed fixed-fee contracting mechanism can implement a stable network in the competitive setting by achieving a profit allocation that is in the core of the cooperative game. We also demonstrate that the grand coalition is stable in a farsighted sense under the Shapley value allocation. Managerial implications: Under the fixed-fee mechanism, the buyer’s decisions maximize the network profit, and each supplier earns a profit equal to its marginal contribution. When the aggregate capacity of the supplier network is high relative to demand, or demand is more likely to be small, the fixed-fee mechanism is likely to outperform the Shapley value allocation from the perspective of the buyer.","PeriodicalId":18108,"journal":{"name":"Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag.","volume":"75 1","pages":"2558-2576"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2022-01-31","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"86392172","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Environment and Energy? The Impact of Environmental Management Systems on Energy Efficiency 环境与能源?环境管理系统对能源效率的影响
Pub Date : 2022-01-31 DOI: 10.1287/msom.2021.1057
Seong-Bae Jeong, Jaeseok Lee
Problem definition: Despite the widespread adoption of environmental management systems (EMS), their relationship with energy efficiency remains unclear. This study investigates whether and how EMS adoption lowers energy efficiency and, if so, how to mitigate the impact. Academic/practical relevance: Understanding the relationship between EMS and energy efficiency is important because any decrease in energy efficiency may eventually lead to undesired environmental outputs (e.g., CO2), potentially contributing to climate change. This study sheds light on energy as a necessary input required for environmental management, thereby elucidating the issue of environmental trade-offs in sustainable operations. Methodology: Using novel panel data on energy efficiency and EMS standards obtained from 2,690 South Korean plants operating between 2001 and 2014, this study empirically investigates the impact of EMS on energy efficiency at the plant level. Results: We provide evidence of a trade-off relationship between environmental performance and energy efficiency in relation to EMS adoption. We find that the adoption of ISO 14001, the representative EMS standard, results in approximately 6%–12% lower energy efficiency compared with nonadoption although it effectively reduces air, water, and waste pollution. More importantly, our results show that the trade-off, an unintended consequence of EMS implementation, can be moderated through quality management capability. Managerial implications: We suggest that sustainability managers take balancing actions to reduce trade-offs between environmental performance and energy efficiency. Specifically, when implementing EMS, managers are advised to (1) actively incorporate energy management activities, (2) employ more comprehensive measurements for energy efficiency, and (3) redesign incentive schemes to facilitate improvements in energy efficiency.
问题定义:尽管环境管理系统(EMS)被广泛采用,但其与能源效率的关系仍不清楚。本研究调查了EMS的采用是否以及如何降低能源效率,如果是,如何减轻影响。学术/实际意义:了解环境管理与能源效率之间的关系很重要,因为能源效率的任何降低都可能最终导致不希望的环境输出(如二氧化碳),从而可能导致气候变化。这项研究阐明了能源是环境管理所需的必要投入,从而阐明了可持续业务中的环境权衡问题。方法:本研究利用2001年至2014年间运营的2690家韩国工厂的能效和EMS标准的新面板数据,实证调查了EMS对工厂能效的影响。结果:我们提供了环境绩效和能源效率之间的权衡关系的证据,与环境管理体系的采用有关。我们发现,采用具有代表性的环境管理体系标准ISO 14001,虽然有效地减少了空气、水和废物污染,但与不采用相比,能源效率降低了约6%-12%。更重要的是,我们的结果表明,环境管理体系实施的一个意想不到的后果,可以通过质量管理能力得到缓和。管理启示:我们建议可持续发展管理者采取平衡行动,减少环境绩效和能源效率之间的权衡。具体而言,在实施环境管理体系时,建议管理者(1)积极纳入能源管理活动,(2)采用更全面的能源效率测量方法,以及(3)重新设计激励计划,以促进能源效率的改善。
{"title":"Environment and Energy? The Impact of Environmental Management Systems on Energy Efficiency","authors":"Seong-Bae Jeong, Jaeseok Lee","doi":"10.1287/msom.2021.1057","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2021.1057","url":null,"abstract":"Problem definition: Despite the widespread adoption of environmental management systems (EMS), their relationship with energy efficiency remains unclear. This study investigates whether and how EMS adoption lowers energy efficiency and, if so, how to mitigate the impact. Academic/practical relevance: Understanding the relationship between EMS and energy efficiency is important because any decrease in energy efficiency may eventually lead to undesired environmental outputs (e.g., CO2), potentially contributing to climate change. This study sheds light on energy as a necessary input required for environmental management, thereby elucidating the issue of environmental trade-offs in sustainable operations. Methodology: Using novel panel data on energy efficiency and EMS standards obtained from 2,690 South Korean plants operating between 2001 and 2014, this study empirically investigates the impact of EMS on energy efficiency at the plant level. Results: We provide evidence of a trade-off relationship between environmental performance and energy efficiency in relation to EMS adoption. We find that the adoption of ISO 14001, the representative EMS standard, results in approximately 6%–12% lower energy efficiency compared with nonadoption although it effectively reduces air, water, and waste pollution. More importantly, our results show that the trade-off, an unintended consequence of EMS implementation, can be moderated through quality management capability. Managerial implications: We suggest that sustainability managers take balancing actions to reduce trade-offs between environmental performance and energy efficiency. Specifically, when implementing EMS, managers are advised to (1) actively incorporate energy management activities, (2) employ more comprehensive measurements for energy efficiency, and (3) redesign incentive schemes to facilitate improvements in energy efficiency.","PeriodicalId":18108,"journal":{"name":"Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag.","volume":"26 1","pages":"1311-1328"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2022-01-31","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"81749199","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 3
COVID-19 and E-commerce Operations: Evidence from Alibaba COVID-19与电子商务运营:来自阿里巴巴的证据
Pub Date : 2022-01-27 DOI: 10.1287/msom.2021.1075
Brian Rongqing Han, Tianshu Sun, Leon Yang Chu, Lixia Wu
Problem definition: This paper investigates the impact of COVID-19 on e-commerce sales and the underlying operational driver. Academic/practical relevance: As COVID-19 continues to disrupt offline retail, anecdotal evidence suggests a rapid growth of e-commerce. However, the pandemic may also significantly decrease offline logistics capacity, which in turn decreases e-commerce sales. Then, how does e-commerce respond to COVID-19, and what are the corresponding opportunities and challenges? Methodology: We leverage e-commerce sales data from Alibaba and construct a city-day panel across three years, representing sales for all buyers and sellers on the platform across 339 cities in mainland China. We develop three identification strategies to estimate the overall impact of COVID-19 (based on a year-on-year comparison), the impact of COVID-19 intensity (based on the different number of cases across cities), and the impact of corresponding containment measures (leveraging policy changes of checkpoint, partial shutdown, and complete shutdown measures across cities). Results: We provide two key findings. First, across different identification strategies, we observe a common drop and recovery pattern, which illustrates the digital resilience of e-commerce during the pandemic. For example, we estimate an overall decrease of 22% in e-commerce sales during the period of the Wuhan shutdown (January 23–April 7, 2020). However, it recovers in most cities within five weeks. Second, we identify a key operational driver—logistics capacity—that significantly explains the decline and recovery of e-commerce sales during and after the outbreak. Managerial implications: We provide important evidence on how e-commerce responds to and recovers from COVID-19, contrary to the common perception. The evidence in the recovery phase can also inform platforms and policymakers to design digital strategies and invest in logistics infrastructure.
问题定义:本文研究新冠肺炎疫情对电子商务销售的影响以及潜在的运营驱动因素。学术/实践相关性:随着COVID-19继续扰乱线下零售,坊间证据表明电子商务正在快速增长。然而,疫情也可能大幅降低线下物流能力,从而减少电子商务销售。那么,电子商务如何应对新冠肺炎疫情,有哪些机遇和挑战?方法:我们利用阿里巴巴的电子商务销售数据,构建了一个为期三年的城市日面板,代表了中国大陆339个城市平台上所有买家和卖家的销售情况。我们制定了三种识别策略来估计COVID-19的总体影响(基于同比比较)、COVID-19强度的影响(基于不同城市的不同病例数)以及相应的遏制措施的影响(利用不同城市的检查站、部分关闭和完全关闭措施的政策变化)。结果:我们提供了两个关键发现。首先,在不同的识别策略中,我们观察到一个共同的下降和恢复模式,这说明了大流行期间电子商务的数字复原力。例如,我们估计在武汉关闭期间(2020年1月23日至4月7日),电子商务销售额总体下降了22%。然而,在大多数城市,它会在五周内恢复。其次,我们确定了一个关键的运营驱动因素——物流能力——这在很大程度上解释了疫情期间和之后电子商务销售的下降和复苏。管理启示:我们为电子商务如何应对COVID-19并从中恢复提供了重要证据,这与普遍看法相反。恢复阶段的证据还可以为平台和政策制定者提供信息,以设计数字战略并投资物流基础设施。
{"title":"COVID-19 and E-commerce Operations: Evidence from Alibaba","authors":"Brian Rongqing Han, Tianshu Sun, Leon Yang Chu, Lixia Wu","doi":"10.1287/msom.2021.1075","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2021.1075","url":null,"abstract":"Problem definition: This paper investigates the impact of COVID-19 on e-commerce sales and the underlying operational driver. Academic/practical relevance: As COVID-19 continues to disrupt offline retail, anecdotal evidence suggests a rapid growth of e-commerce. However, the pandemic may also significantly decrease offline logistics capacity, which in turn decreases e-commerce sales. Then, how does e-commerce respond to COVID-19, and what are the corresponding opportunities and challenges? Methodology: We leverage e-commerce sales data from Alibaba and construct a city-day panel across three years, representing sales for all buyers and sellers on the platform across 339 cities in mainland China. We develop three identification strategies to estimate the overall impact of COVID-19 (based on a year-on-year comparison), the impact of COVID-19 intensity (based on the different number of cases across cities), and the impact of corresponding containment measures (leveraging policy changes of checkpoint, partial shutdown, and complete shutdown measures across cities). Results: We provide two key findings. First, across different identification strategies, we observe a common drop and recovery pattern, which illustrates the digital resilience of e-commerce during the pandemic. For example, we estimate an overall decrease of 22% in e-commerce sales during the period of the Wuhan shutdown (January 23–April 7, 2020). However, it recovers in most cities within five weeks. Second, we identify a key operational driver—logistics capacity—that significantly explains the decline and recovery of e-commerce sales during and after the outbreak. Managerial implications: We provide important evidence on how e-commerce responds to and recovers from COVID-19, contrary to the common perception. The evidence in the recovery phase can also inform platforms and policymakers to design digital strategies and invest in logistics infrastructure.","PeriodicalId":18108,"journal":{"name":"Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag.","volume":"21 1","pages":"1388-1405"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2022-01-27","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"80577571","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 24
Seeing the Bigger Picture? Ramping up Production with the Use of Augmented Reality 看大局?利用增强现实技术提高生产效率
Pub Date : 2022-01-27 DOI: 10.1287/msom.2021.1070
David A. Wuttke, Ankit Upadhyay, Enno Siemsen, A. Wuttke-Linnemann
Problem definition: Firms increasingly use augmented reality (AR) devices to improve their production ramp-up processes. These devices appear useful, yet little is known about their broader impact on worker productivity and behavior. Academic/practical relevance: Efficient production ramp-ups are particularly important when product life cycles are short. An ongoing debate among academics and practitioners pertains to how Industry 4.0, and AR devices in particular, can accelerate the ramp-up. The current study provides empirical evidence related to AR in the production ramp-up context, examines the strengths and weaknesses of AR, and tests four hypotheses, leading to a more nuanced view of AR use in the manufacturing ramp-up. Methodology: A framed field experiment in a manufacturing plant provides a test of how quickly workers can perform new tasks with and without AR support and how the use of AR affects their ability to suggest process improvements. Results: When faced with a new task, workers instructed by AR smart glasses use 43.8% less time to complete the task compared with a control group that relies on paper-based instructions. However, workers that use AR glasses consistently use 23% more time than the control group when both groups repeat the task without either AR or paper-based instructions. Task difficulty moderates this relationship; workers assigned to a more difficult task benefit the most from AR instructions. After the devices are removed, workers instructed based on paper improve their productivity faster through learning than those instructed by AR. In addition, the former group suggests better process improvements than the latter one. Managerial implications: Although these results indicate substantially higher productivity resulting from AR devices, they also support the view that, once instructed through AR devices, workers come to rely on this new technology without fully internalizing the task. This failure to internalize their task then leads workers to suggest less useful process improvements.
问题定义:企业越来越多地使用增强现实(AR)设备来改进其生产提升流程。这些设备看起来很有用,但它们对工人生产力和行为的更广泛影响却鲜为人知。学术/实践相关性:当产品生命周期较短时,高效的生产提升尤为重要。学术界和实践者之间正在进行的争论涉及工业4.0,特别是AR设备如何加速增长。目前的研究提供了与生产加速背景下增强现实相关的经验证据,检查了增强现实的优势和劣势,并测试了四个假设,从而对增强现实在生产加速中的使用产生了更细致的看法。方法:在一家制造工厂进行了一项有框架的现场实验,测试工人在有和没有AR支持的情况下执行新任务的速度,以及AR的使用如何影响他们提出流程改进建议的能力。结果:当面对一项新任务时,与依赖纸质指令的对照组相比,由AR智能眼镜指导的工人完成任务的时间减少了43.8%。然而,当两组在没有AR或纸质指示的情况下重复任务时,使用AR眼镜的员工比对照组持续多花23%的时间。任务难度调节了这种关系;被分配到更困难任务的员工从AR指令中受益最大。移除设备后,基于纸张的员工通过学习提高生产率的速度比基于AR的员工更快。此外,前者提出的流程改进建议比后者更好。管理意义:尽管这些结果表明AR设备大大提高了生产力,但它们也支持这样一种观点,即一旦通过AR设备进行指导,工人就会依赖这项新技术,而不会完全内化这项任务。这种内化任务的失败会导致员工提出不太有用的流程改进建议。
{"title":"Seeing the Bigger Picture? Ramping up Production with the Use of Augmented Reality","authors":"David A. Wuttke, Ankit Upadhyay, Enno Siemsen, A. Wuttke-Linnemann","doi":"10.1287/msom.2021.1070","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2021.1070","url":null,"abstract":"Problem definition: Firms increasingly use augmented reality (AR) devices to improve their production ramp-up processes. These devices appear useful, yet little is known about their broader impact on worker productivity and behavior. Academic/practical relevance: Efficient production ramp-ups are particularly important when product life cycles are short. An ongoing debate among academics and practitioners pertains to how Industry 4.0, and AR devices in particular, can accelerate the ramp-up. The current study provides empirical evidence related to AR in the production ramp-up context, examines the strengths and weaknesses of AR, and tests four hypotheses, leading to a more nuanced view of AR use in the manufacturing ramp-up. Methodology: A framed field experiment in a manufacturing plant provides a test of how quickly workers can perform new tasks with and without AR support and how the use of AR affects their ability to suggest process improvements. Results: When faced with a new task, workers instructed by AR smart glasses use 43.8% less time to complete the task compared with a control group that relies on paper-based instructions. However, workers that use AR glasses consistently use 23% more time than the control group when both groups repeat the task without either AR or paper-based instructions. Task difficulty moderates this relationship; workers assigned to a more difficult task benefit the most from AR instructions. After the devices are removed, workers instructed based on paper improve their productivity faster through learning than those instructed by AR. In addition, the former group suggests better process improvements than the latter one. Managerial implications: Although these results indicate substantially higher productivity resulting from AR devices, they also support the view that, once instructed through AR devices, workers come to rely on this new technology without fully internalizing the task. This failure to internalize their task then leads workers to suggest less useful process improvements.","PeriodicalId":18108,"journal":{"name":"Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag.","volume":"49 5 1","pages":"2349-2366"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2022-01-27","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"89069667","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 6
期刊
Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag.
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1