首页 > 最新文献

Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag.最新文献

英文 中文
The Microstructure of Work: Understanding Productivity Benefits and Costs of Interruptions 工作的微观结构:理解中断的生产力收益和成本
Pub Date : 2022-01-25 DOI: 10.1287/msom.2021.1053
Pradeep K. Pendem, Paul I. Green, B. Staats
Problem definition: We examine the impact of four classes of workplace interruptions on short-term (working hours) and long-term (across-shifts) worker performance in an agribusiness setting. The interruptions are organized in a two-by-two framework in which they result (or do not result) in a physical task requirement and lead to a varying degree of attention shift from the primary task. Academic/practical relevance: Prior operations management literature primarily examines the long-term effects of a single class of interruption that reduces performance. Our study contributes to this literature by examining multiple classes of interruptions that lead to positive and negative outcomes over the short-term in addition to the long-term. Further, our study also contributes to understanding the impact of general task transitions (interruptions) on worker performance, and the interrupting tasks include tasks that are not part of workers’ primary job duties. Our study is relevant to work settings that envelop high manual labor and experience interruptions regularly. Finally, we offer strategies to improve operational performance. Methodology: Using a granular data set on worker productivity from 211 harvesters yielding 117,581 truckloads of fruit harvested for 9,819 worker shifts, we utilize an instrumental variable approach with two-stage residual inclusion estimation on a mix of linear and nonlinear models to examine and quantify the impact of interruptions on both short- and long-term worker productivity. Results: We identify a new interruption class, a pause—interruptions that provide the physical respite and limit the degree of attention shift from the primary task. We find that pauses improve worker productivity in the short- and long-term. Next, we find that scheduled breaks hurt (improve) the worker’s productivity in the short-term (long-term). Finally, we find that harvester breakdown and travel across field interruptions that drain physical resources and cause attention shift hurt worker productivity in the short- and long-term. We quantify the impact (in our field context) of a five-minute increase in each of these work interruptions on average worker productivity. Managerial implications: Our study demonstrates that various work interruptions can have positive or negative effects on workers’ productivity. We suggest that introducing brief pauses in a workday and simultaneously reminding (before initiating the pause) employees about the tasks yet to be completed or goals to be achieved for the rest of the shift can help maintain their focus on the work and yield high-performance benefits. We also suggest strategies that limit the restart costs and increase the predictability of interruptions that hurt performance. For example, in regards to scheduled breaks, planning the break after completing a subtask or reaching a subgoal can limit their adverse effects. Further, informing workers on the possibility of interruption circumstances at the beg
问题定义:我们研究了四类工作场所中断对农业综合企业中短期(工作时间)和长期(跨班次)工人绩效的影响。这些中断被组织成一个二乘二的框架,在这个框架中,它们导致(或不导致)物理任务要求,并导致不同程度的注意力从主要任务转移。学术/实践相关性:先前的运营管理文献主要研究单一类型的中断对降低绩效的长期影响。我们的研究通过研究多种类型的干扰,为这一文献做出了贡献,这些干扰在短期和长期之外都会导致积极和消极的结果。此外,我们的研究还有助于理解一般任务转换(中断)对员工绩效的影响,中断任务包括不属于员工主要工作职责的任务。我们的研究与高体力劳动和经常经历中断的工作环境有关。最后,我们提出了提高运营绩效的策略。方法:使用211台收割机的工人生产率的颗粒数据集,收获了9,819个工人班次的117,581卡车水果,我们利用工具变量方法,在线性和非线性模型的混合上使用两阶段残差包含估计来检查和量化中断对短期和长期工人生产率的影响。结果:我们确定了一种新的中断类,暂停中断,它提供了身体上的喘息,并限制了注意力从主要任务转移的程度。我们发现,从短期和长期来看,暂停都能提高工人的生产率。接下来,我们发现计划的休息在短期(长期)内损害(提高)了工人的生产力。最后,我们发现收割机的故障和穿越田地的中断会消耗物理资源并导致注意力转移,从而在短期和长期内损害工人的生产力。我们量化了这些工作中断每增加五分钟对平均工人生产力的影响(在我们的领域背景下)。管理启示:我们的研究表明,各种工作中断可以对工人的生产力产生积极或消极的影响。我们建议,在工作日中引入短暂的休息,同时(在暂停之前)提醒员工在接下来的轮班中还有哪些任务需要完成或目标需要实现,这有助于保持他们对工作的专注,并产生高效的效益。我们还提出了限制重启成本和提高影响性能的中断的可预测性的策略。例如,关于计划休息,在完成一个子任务或达到一个子目标后计划休息可以限制它们的不利影响。此外,在轮班开始时告知员工可能出现的中断情况,可以帮助他们为这些事件做好计划,提高他们在主要工作上的参与度和表现。
{"title":"The Microstructure of Work: Understanding Productivity Benefits and Costs of Interruptions","authors":"Pradeep K. Pendem, Paul I. Green, B. Staats","doi":"10.1287/msom.2021.1053","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2021.1053","url":null,"abstract":"Problem definition: We examine the impact of four classes of workplace interruptions on short-term (working hours) and long-term (across-shifts) worker performance in an agribusiness setting. The interruptions are organized in a two-by-two framework in which they result (or do not result) in a physical task requirement and lead to a varying degree of attention shift from the primary task. Academic/practical relevance: Prior operations management literature primarily examines the long-term effects of a single class of interruption that reduces performance. Our study contributes to this literature by examining multiple classes of interruptions that lead to positive and negative outcomes over the short-term in addition to the long-term. Further, our study also contributes to understanding the impact of general task transitions (interruptions) on worker performance, and the interrupting tasks include tasks that are not part of workers’ primary job duties. Our study is relevant to work settings that envelop high manual labor and experience interruptions regularly. Finally, we offer strategies to improve operational performance. Methodology: Using a granular data set on worker productivity from 211 harvesters yielding 117,581 truckloads of fruit harvested for 9,819 worker shifts, we utilize an instrumental variable approach with two-stage residual inclusion estimation on a mix of linear and nonlinear models to examine and quantify the impact of interruptions on both short- and long-term worker productivity. Results: We identify a new interruption class, a pause—interruptions that provide the physical respite and limit the degree of attention shift from the primary task. We find that pauses improve worker productivity in the short- and long-term. Next, we find that scheduled breaks hurt (improve) the worker’s productivity in the short-term (long-term). Finally, we find that harvester breakdown and travel across field interruptions that drain physical resources and cause attention shift hurt worker productivity in the short- and long-term. We quantify the impact (in our field context) of a five-minute increase in each of these work interruptions on average worker productivity. Managerial implications: Our study demonstrates that various work interruptions can have positive or negative effects on workers’ productivity. We suggest that introducing brief pauses in a workday and simultaneously reminding (before initiating the pause) employees about the tasks yet to be completed or goals to be achieved for the rest of the shift can help maintain their focus on the work and yield high-performance benefits. We also suggest strategies that limit the restart costs and increase the predictability of interruptions that hurt performance. For example, in regards to scheduled breaks, planning the break after completing a subtask or reaching a subgoal can limit their adverse effects. Further, informing workers on the possibility of interruption circumstances at the beg","PeriodicalId":18108,"journal":{"name":"Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag.","volume":"28 1","pages":"2202-2220"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2022-01-25","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"75906229","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2
Collaboration Structures in Integrated Healthcare Delivery Systems: An Exploratory Study of Accountable Care Organizations 整合医疗服务系统中的协作结构:负责任医疗组织的探索性研究
Pub Date : 2022-01-24 DOI: 10.1287/msom.2021.1038
Yingchao Lan, Aravind Chandrasekaran, D. Goradia, D. Walker
Problem definition: This study explores the performance implications of collaboration structures in an integrated healthcare delivery system, namely, an accountable care organization (ACO). ACOs consist of providers from various stages of the care continuum (preacute, acute, and postacute) that voluntarily assume collective responsibility for the quality and cost of care for a defined patient population. Academic/practical relevance: ACOs’ unsatisfied outcomes are largely due to a lack of provider collaboration. There is a dearth of empirical studies on how to develop collaboration structures. Studies in the healthcare operations management primarily have focused on collaboration within a single organization, shedding little light on this problem. We address this issue by exploring two distinct dimensions of collaboration: partnership scope and scale. Partnership scope measures the presence of providers from the preacute, acute, and/or postacute care-continuum stages, whereas partnership scale measures the presence of providers within a single care-continuum stage. Methodology: We assemble a unique data set of provider types, collaboration structures, and system-level performance for 528 Medicare Shared Savings Program (MSSP) ACOs from 2013–2016. To investigate the impact of partnership scope and scale on ACO performance, we then use econometric estimation approaches that account for endogeneity in collaboration structure decisions. ACO performance is measured by experiential quality and 30-day readmission rates. As additional tests, we also investigate our research questions by assembling data sets at both the hospital level (20,975 hospital-year panel data spanning 2009 to 2015) and patient level (859,145 Medicare patients admitted to 39 California hospitals over a four-year period from 2012 to 2015). Results: We find that synergies exist between partnership scope and scale with respect to ACO performance. Specifically, an average-sized ACO can realize 3.2% more improvement in experiential quality and a 6.6% greater reduction in 30-day readmission rates through partnership scope and scale synergies in the preacute care stage. We also show that the benefits of increasing partnership scope are consistent across providers and patient-level analysis. Further, we find that these benefits come at some cost, suggesting an initial cost-quality trade-off when developing collaboration structures. Managerial implications: Our results offer important insights into the healthcare operations management literature on designing effective healthcare delivery systems extending beyond a single organization.
问题定义:本研究探讨了协作结构对综合医疗服务系统的绩效影响,即一个负责任的医疗组织(ACO)。ACOs由来自护理连续体不同阶段(急性前、急性和急性后)的提供者组成,他们自愿对特定患者群体的护理质量和费用承担集体责任。学术/实践相关性:ACOs不满意的结果主要是由于缺乏提供者合作。关于如何发展协作结构的实证研究缺乏。医疗保健运营管理方面的研究主要集中在单个组织内的协作上,对这个问题的研究很少。我们通过探索合作的两个不同维度来解决这个问题:伙伴关系的范围和规模。伙伴关系范围衡量急性前、急性期和/或急性期后护理连续阶段的提供者的存在,而伙伴关系规模衡量单一护理连续阶段内提供者的存在。方法:我们收集了2013-2016年528个医疗保险共享储蓄计划(MSSP) ACOs的提供商类型、协作结构和系统级绩效的独特数据集。为了研究合作伙伴范围和规模对蚁群管理绩效的影响,我们使用计量经济学估计方法来解释协作结构决策中的内生性。ACO性能是通过体验质量和30天再入院率来衡量的。作为附加测试,我们还通过收集医院层面(2009年至2015年期间20,975家医院年度面板数据)和患者层面(2012年至2015年期间39家加州医院住院的859,145名医疗保险患者)的数据集来调查我们的研究问题。结果:我们发现在合作伙伴范围和规模之间存在协同效应。具体而言,通过伙伴关系范围和规模协同效应,平均规模的ACO可以在急性前护理阶段实现3.2%的体验质量提高和6.6%的30天再入院率降低。我们还表明,增加合作范围的好处在提供者和患者层面的分析中是一致的。此外,我们发现这些好处是有一定代价的,这表明在开发协作结构时需要进行初始的成本-质量权衡。管理意义:我们的研究结果提供了重要的见解,为设计有效的医疗服务系统延伸到一个单一的组织的医疗运营管理文献。
{"title":"Collaboration Structures in Integrated Healthcare Delivery Systems: An Exploratory Study of Accountable Care Organizations","authors":"Yingchao Lan, Aravind Chandrasekaran, D. Goradia, D. Walker","doi":"10.1287/msom.2021.1038","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2021.1038","url":null,"abstract":"Problem definition: This study explores the performance implications of collaboration structures in an integrated healthcare delivery system, namely, an accountable care organization (ACO). ACOs consist of providers from various stages of the care continuum (preacute, acute, and postacute) that voluntarily assume collective responsibility for the quality and cost of care for a defined patient population. Academic/practical relevance: ACOs’ unsatisfied outcomes are largely due to a lack of provider collaboration. There is a dearth of empirical studies on how to develop collaboration structures. Studies in the healthcare operations management primarily have focused on collaboration within a single organization, shedding little light on this problem. We address this issue by exploring two distinct dimensions of collaboration: partnership scope and scale. Partnership scope measures the presence of providers from the preacute, acute, and/or postacute care-continuum stages, whereas partnership scale measures the presence of providers within a single care-continuum stage. Methodology: We assemble a unique data set of provider types, collaboration structures, and system-level performance for 528 Medicare Shared Savings Program (MSSP) ACOs from 2013–2016. To investigate the impact of partnership scope and scale on ACO performance, we then use econometric estimation approaches that account for endogeneity in collaboration structure decisions. ACO performance is measured by experiential quality and 30-day readmission rates. As additional tests, we also investigate our research questions by assembling data sets at both the hospital level (20,975 hospital-year panel data spanning 2009 to 2015) and patient level (859,145 Medicare patients admitted to 39 California hospitals over a four-year period from 2012 to 2015). Results: We find that synergies exist between partnership scope and scale with respect to ACO performance. Specifically, an average-sized ACO can realize 3.2% more improvement in experiential quality and a 6.6% greater reduction in 30-day readmission rates through partnership scope and scale synergies in the preacute care stage. We also show that the benefits of increasing partnership scope are consistent across providers and patient-level analysis. Further, we find that these benefits come at some cost, suggesting an initial cost-quality trade-off when developing collaboration structures. Managerial implications: Our results offer important insights into the healthcare operations management literature on designing effective healthcare delivery systems extending beyond a single organization.","PeriodicalId":18108,"journal":{"name":"Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag.","volume":"39 1","pages":"1796-1820"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2022-01-24","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"85884911","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 5
Competition Between Hospitals Under Bundled Payments and Fee-for-Service: An Equilibrium Analysis of Insurer's Choice 医院在捆绑支付和按服务收费下的竞争:保险公司选择的均衡分析
Pub Date : 2022-01-19 DOI: 10.1287/msom.2021.1039
Zheng Han, Mazhar Arikan, S. Mallik
Problem definition: We consider the quality competition between two hospitals under the plan of one insurer. The insurer aims to maximize the overall achievable quality in the system by selecting either the fee-for-service (FFS) or the bundled payment (BP) scheme to compensate each hospital. The demand, the costs, and the probability of successfully treating patients depend on a hospital’s chosen quality. Under such a setting, we use game theoretic models to study the choice of insurer and the impact of payment schemes on the equilibrium qualities of hospitals. Our models seek answers to the following questions. Is BP (FFS) payment scheme always associated with high (low) equilibrium quality? What factors affect the equilibrium qualities of competing hospitals and the choice of the insurer and how? Academic/practical relevance: Competing hospitals under same or different payment models from an insurer is rather common for healthcare delivery in the United States. However, there is a lack of understanding about the impact of payment schemes on quality outcomes from both the hospital’s and the insurer’s perspective. To the best of our knowledge, ours is the first paper to incorporate competition and the insurer’s perspective to study the impact of different payment models on quality. Methodology: Game theory, equilibrium analysis. Results: We show that BP (FFS) is not always associated with high (low) equilibrium quality and that the equilibrium qualities of the two hospitals are strategic complements. We characterize when the insurer might assign the BP to both hospitals, the FFS to both hospitals, or the BP to one and the FFS to the other hospital. Managerial implications: Our findings provide prescriptive guidelines to an insurer choosing payment models. We also show that a specific quality outcome is achievable not by choosing any payment model but by a careful design of its parameters. Our numerical studies show that hospital readmission reduction initiatives are most effective when run in conjunction with cost reduction initiatives.
问题定义:考虑同一保险公司旗下两家医院的质量竞争。保险公司的目标是通过选择按服务收费(FFS)或捆绑付款(BP)计划来补偿每家医院,从而最大限度地提高系统中可实现的整体质量。需求、成本和成功治疗病人的可能性取决于医院所选择的质量。在这种情况下,我们运用博弈论模型研究了保险公司的选择以及支付方案对医院均衡质量的影响。我们的模型寻求以下问题的答案。BP (FFS)支付方案是否总是与高(低)平衡质量相关?什么因素影响竞争医院的均衡质量和保险公司的选择,以及如何影响?学术/实践相关性:在同一或不同的支付模式下与保险公司竞争的医院在美国的医疗保健服务中相当普遍。然而,从医院和保险公司的角度来看,人们对支付方案对质量结果的影响缺乏了解。据我们所知,我们的论文是第一篇结合竞争和保险公司的角度来研究不同支付模式对质量影响的论文。方法论:博弈论,均衡分析。结果:我们发现BP (FFS)并不总是与高(低)均衡质量相关,两家医院的均衡质量是战略互补的。我们描述了保险人可能将BP分配给两家医院,将FFS分配给两家医院,或将BP分配给一家医院而将FFS分配给另一家医院的情况。管理启示:我们的研究结果为保险公司选择支付模式提供了规范性指导。我们还表明,特定的质量结果不是通过选择任何付费模式,而是通过仔细设计其参数来实现的。我们的数值研究表明,减少医院再入院的举措是最有效的,当运行与降低成本的举措。
{"title":"Competition Between Hospitals Under Bundled Payments and Fee-for-Service: An Equilibrium Analysis of Insurer's Choice","authors":"Zheng Han, Mazhar Arikan, S. Mallik","doi":"10.1287/msom.2021.1039","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2021.1039","url":null,"abstract":"Problem definition: We consider the quality competition between two hospitals under the plan of one insurer. The insurer aims to maximize the overall achievable quality in the system by selecting either the fee-for-service (FFS) or the bundled payment (BP) scheme to compensate each hospital. The demand, the costs, and the probability of successfully treating patients depend on a hospital’s chosen quality. Under such a setting, we use game theoretic models to study the choice of insurer and the impact of payment schemes on the equilibrium qualities of hospitals. Our models seek answers to the following questions. Is BP (FFS) payment scheme always associated with high (low) equilibrium quality? What factors affect the equilibrium qualities of competing hospitals and the choice of the insurer and how? Academic/practical relevance: Competing hospitals under same or different payment models from an insurer is rather common for healthcare delivery in the United States. However, there is a lack of understanding about the impact of payment schemes on quality outcomes from both the hospital’s and the insurer’s perspective. To the best of our knowledge, ours is the first paper to incorporate competition and the insurer’s perspective to study the impact of different payment models on quality. Methodology: Game theory, equilibrium analysis. Results: We show that BP (FFS) is not always associated with high (low) equilibrium quality and that the equilibrium qualities of the two hospitals are strategic complements. We characterize when the insurer might assign the BP to both hospitals, the FFS to both hospitals, or the BP to one and the FFS to the other hospital. Managerial implications: Our findings provide prescriptive guidelines to an insurer choosing payment models. We also show that a specific quality outcome is achievable not by choosing any payment model but by a careful design of its parameters. Our numerical studies show that hospital readmission reduction initiatives are most effective when run in conjunction with cost reduction initiatives.","PeriodicalId":18108,"journal":{"name":"Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag.","volume":"1 1","pages":"1821-1842"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2022-01-19","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"83090555","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 3
Do Managers Overreact When in Backlog? Evidence of Scope Neglect from a Supply Chain Experiment 经理在待办事项积压时是否反应过度?供应链实验中范围忽视的证据
Pub Date : 2022-01-19 DOI: 10.1287/msom.2021.1072
Rogelio Oliva, Huseyn Abdulla, Paulo Gonçalves
Problem definition: We empirically examine a complementary behavioral source of the bullwhip effect that has been previously overlooked in the literature: that individuals order more aggressively (i.e., overreact) when they face shortages than when they hold inventory. Methodology/Results: We conduct a behavioral experiment using the beer distribution game. We estimate decision rules using multilevel modeling approaches that overcome several drawbacks of the estimation methods used in the earlier literature. We find robust evidence that, contrary to the overreaction when in backlog hypothesis and reports from popular press, decision makers order less aggressively and become insensitive to the scope of the problem when in backlog—a scope neglect phenomenon. Managerial implications: We propose a dual-process theoretical account predicated on affective reactions to explain this scope neglect. Our results suggest that affective reactions under novel operating conditions or dramatic events in supply chains, such as the COVID-19 pandemic, can overwhelm cognitive processing of managers and make them fail to recognize the full scope of the problems faced and update decision models accordingly. Understanding the cognitive-affective drivers of ordering behaviors that generate supply chain instability is important in designing interventions to mitigate their negative effects.
问题定义:我们从经验上考察了牛鞭效应的一个互补的行为来源,这在以前的文献中被忽视了:当个人面临短缺时,他们会比拥有库存时更积极地订购(即反应过度)。方法/结果:我们使用啤酒分配游戏进行行为实验。我们使用多层建模方法来估计决策规则,克服了早期文献中使用的估计方法的几个缺点。我们发现有力的证据表明,与积压时的过度反应假说和大众媒体的报道相反,决策者在积压时不那么积极地订购,对问题的范围不敏感——这是一种范围忽视现象。管理意义:我们提出了一种基于情感反应的双过程理论解释,以解释这种范围忽视。我们的研究结果表明,在新的操作条件或供应链中的戏剧性事件(如COVID-19大流行)下,情感反应可能会淹没管理者的认知处理,使他们无法认识到所面临问题的全部范围,并相应地更新决策模型。了解产生供应链不稳定的订购行为的认知情感驱动因素对于设计干预措施以减轻其负面影响非常重要。
{"title":"Do Managers Overreact When in Backlog? Evidence of Scope Neglect from a Supply Chain Experiment","authors":"Rogelio Oliva, Huseyn Abdulla, Paulo Gonçalves","doi":"10.1287/msom.2021.1072","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2021.1072","url":null,"abstract":"Problem definition: We empirically examine a complementary behavioral source of the bullwhip effect that has been previously overlooked in the literature: that individuals order more aggressively (i.e., overreact) when they face shortages than when they hold inventory. Methodology/Results: We conduct a behavioral experiment using the beer distribution game. We estimate decision rules using multilevel modeling approaches that overcome several drawbacks of the estimation methods used in the earlier literature. We find robust evidence that, contrary to the overreaction when in backlog hypothesis and reports from popular press, decision makers order less aggressively and become insensitive to the scope of the problem when in backlog—a scope neglect phenomenon. Managerial implications: We propose a dual-process theoretical account predicated on affective reactions to explain this scope neglect. Our results suggest that affective reactions under novel operating conditions or dramatic events in supply chains, such as the COVID-19 pandemic, can overwhelm cognitive processing of managers and make them fail to recognize the full scope of the problems faced and update decision models accordingly. Understanding the cognitive-affective drivers of ordering behaviors that generate supply chain instability is important in designing interventions to mitigate their negative effects.","PeriodicalId":18108,"journal":{"name":"Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag.","volume":"29 1","pages":"1997-2009"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2022-01-19","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"82258685","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 4
Outcome-Based Reimbursement: The Solution to High Drug Spending? 基于结果的报销:高药费的解决方案?
Pub Date : 2022-01-19 DOI: 10.1287/msom.2021.1051
Liang Xu, Hongmin Li, H Zhao
Problem definition: The continuously soaring prices of new drugs and their uncertain effectiveness in clinical practice have put substantial risks on insurers/payers. To induce insurer coverage of their new drugs, manufacturers start to propose an innovative outcome-based reimbursement (OBR) scheme under which manufacturers refund insurers (and possibly patients) if the drugs fail to achieve a prespecified treatment target. We investigate the impact of OBR on insurers, manufacturers, and patients. Academic/practical relevance: Although OBR sounds intuitively appealing, its true impact is under much debate and depends particularly on the design of OBR. Our study sheds light on the optimal design of OBR and the debate around OBR, considering key trade-offs and key elements not covered in prior literature. Methodology: We develop a Stackelberg game under which the manufacturer designs a rebate scheme for its drug, either non-OBR or OBR, considering the trade-off between a favorable formulary position and the rebate provided. The insurer subsequently determines its formulary for the drug as well as other alternative drugs within the same disease category considering the trade-off between its spending and patient health benefits. Using data on 14 drugs treating a common disease, hyperlipidemia, we estimate through a multinomial logit model the demand of the 14 drugs and conduct counterfactual analyses on the impact of OBR. Results: Under the optimal OBR, the manufacturer lowers the insurer’s risk but inflates the wholesale price (hence, may not reduce insurer spending). OBR also induces a better formulary position for the manufacturer, which, hence, improves patient access to new drugs. Further, rebates to the insurer and patients affect demand through different mechanisms. Including patient rebates in OBR lowers patient expenses and increases drug demand but further increases insurer spending. Managerial implications: We demonstrate the structure of an optimal formulary and its application in practice. We caution insurers/payers who are seeking OBR to reduce their spending.
问题定义:新药价格的持续飙升及其在临床实践中的不确定有效性给保险公司/付款人带来了巨大的风险。为了吸引保险公司为他们的新药提供保险,制造商开始提出一种创新的基于结果的报销(OBR)计划,根据该计划,如果药物未能达到预定的治疗目标,制造商将退款给保险公司(可能还有患者)。我们调查了OBR对保险公司、制造商和患者的影响。学术/实践相关性:尽管OBR听起来很吸引人,但其真正的影响仍存在很多争议,尤其是取决于OBR的设计。我们的研究揭示了OBR的优化设计和围绕OBR的争论,考虑了先前文献中未涉及的关键权衡和关键因素。方法:我们开发了一个Stackelberg游戏,在这个游戏中,制造商为其药物设计一个回扣方案,无论是非OBR还是OBR,考虑到有利的处方位置和提供的回扣之间的权衡。随后,保险公司考虑到其支出与患者健康利益之间的权衡,确定其药物处方以及同一疾病类别内的其他替代药物。利用治疗高脂血症这一常见疾病的14种药物的数据,我们通过多项逻辑模型估计了这14种药物的需求,并对OBR的影响进行了反事实分析。结果:在最优OBR下,制造商降低了保险公司的风险,但提高了批发价格(因此,可能不会减少保险公司的支出)。OBR还为制造商提供了更好的处方位置,从而改善了患者获得新药的途径。此外,对保险公司和患者的回扣通过不同的机制影响需求。将患者回扣纳入OBR降低了患者费用,增加了药品需求,但进一步增加了保险公司的支出。管理意义:我们展示了最优公式的结构及其在实践中的应用。我们提醒寻求OBR的保险公司/付款人减少他们的支出。
{"title":"Outcome-Based Reimbursement: The Solution to High Drug Spending?","authors":"Liang Xu, Hongmin Li, H Zhao","doi":"10.1287/msom.2021.1051","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2021.1051","url":null,"abstract":"Problem definition: The continuously soaring prices of new drugs and their uncertain effectiveness in clinical practice have put substantial risks on insurers/payers. To induce insurer coverage of their new drugs, manufacturers start to propose an innovative outcome-based reimbursement (OBR) scheme under which manufacturers refund insurers (and possibly patients) if the drugs fail to achieve a prespecified treatment target. We investigate the impact of OBR on insurers, manufacturers, and patients. Academic/practical relevance: Although OBR sounds intuitively appealing, its true impact is under much debate and depends particularly on the design of OBR. Our study sheds light on the optimal design of OBR and the debate around OBR, considering key trade-offs and key elements not covered in prior literature. Methodology: We develop a Stackelberg game under which the manufacturer designs a rebate scheme for its drug, either non-OBR or OBR, considering the trade-off between a favorable formulary position and the rebate provided. The insurer subsequently determines its formulary for the drug as well as other alternative drugs within the same disease category considering the trade-off between its spending and patient health benefits. Using data on 14 drugs treating a common disease, hyperlipidemia, we estimate through a multinomial logit model the demand of the 14 drugs and conduct counterfactual analyses on the impact of OBR. Results: Under the optimal OBR, the manufacturer lowers the insurer’s risk but inflates the wholesale price (hence, may not reduce insurer spending). OBR also induces a better formulary position for the manufacturer, which, hence, improves patient access to new drugs. Further, rebates to the insurer and patients affect demand through different mechanisms. Including patient rebates in OBR lowers patient expenses and increases drug demand but further increases insurer spending. Managerial implications: We demonstrate the structure of an optimal formulary and its application in practice. We caution insurers/payers who are seeking OBR to reduce their spending.","PeriodicalId":18108,"journal":{"name":"Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag.","volume":"18 1","pages":"2029-2047"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2022-01-19","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"89058677","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2
Improving Tuberculosis Treatment Adherence Support: The Case for Targeted Behavioral Interventions 改善结核病治疗依从性支持:针对性行为干预的案例
Pub Date : 2021-12-20 DOI: 10.1287/msom.2021.1046
J. Boutilier, J. Jónasson, Erez Yoeli
Problem definition: Lack of patient adherence to treatment protocols is a main barrier to reducing the global disease burden of tuberculosis (TB). We study the operational design of a treatment adherence support (TAS) platform that requires patients to verify their treatment adherence on a daily basis. Academic/practical relevance: Experimental results on the effectiveness of TAS programs have been mixed; and rigorous research is needed on how to structure these motivational programs, particularly in resource-limited settings. Our analysis establishes that patient engagement can be increased by personal sponsor outreach and that patient behavior data can be used to identify at-risk patients for targeted outreach. Methodology: We partner with a TB TAS provider and use data from a completed randomized controlled trial. We use administrative variation in the timing of peer sponsor outreach to evaluate the impact of personal messages on subsequent patient verification behavior. We then develop a rolling-horizon machine learning (ML) framework to generate dynamic risk predictions for patients enrolled on the platform. Results: We find that, on average, sponsor outreach to patients increases the odds ratio of next-day treatment adherence verification by 35%. Furthermore, patients’ prior verification behavior can be used to accurately predict short-term (treatment adherence verification) and long-term (successful treatment completion) outcomes. These results allow the provider to target and implement behavioral interventions to at-risk patients. Managerial implications: Our results indicate that, compared with a benchmark policy, the TAS platform could reach the same number of at-risk patients with 6%–40% less capacity, or reach 2%–20% more at-risk patients with the same capacity, by using various ML-based prioritization policies that leverage patient engagement data. Personal sponsor outreach to all patients is likely to be very costly, so targeted TAS may substantially improve the cost-effectiveness of TAS programs.
问题定义:患者缺乏对治疗方案的遵守是减少结核病全球疾病负担的主要障碍。我们研究了治疗依从性支持(TAS)平台的操作设计,该平台要求患者每天验证其治疗依从性。学术/实践相关性:关于助教计划有效性的实验结果喜忧参半;需要对如何构建这些激励计划进行严格的研究,特别是在资源有限的情况下。我们的分析表明,患者参与可以通过个人赞助者的外展来提高,患者行为数据可以用来识别有风险的患者,进行有针对性的外展。方法:我们与TB TAS提供者合作,使用来自一项完成的随机对照试验的数据。我们使用行政变化的时间在同行赞助者外展评估个人信息对后续患者验证行为的影响。然后,我们开发了一个滚动地平线机器学习(ML)框架,为在平台上注册的患者生成动态风险预测。结果:我们发现,平均而言,赞助商对患者的外展使第二天治疗依从性验证的优势比增加了35%。此外,患者的先前验证行为可以准确预测短期(治疗依从性验证)和长期(成功完成治疗)的结果。这些结果使提供者能够针对高危患者实施行为干预。管理意义:我们的结果表明,与基准政策相比,通过使用各种基于ml的优先级政策,利用患者参与数据,TAS平台可以在容量减少6%-40%的情况下覆盖相同数量的高危患者,或者在容量相同的情况下覆盖2%-20%的高危患者。个人赞助者对所有患者的外展可能非常昂贵,因此有针对性的TAS可能会大大提高TAS计划的成本效益。
{"title":"Improving Tuberculosis Treatment Adherence Support: The Case for Targeted Behavioral Interventions","authors":"J. Boutilier, J. Jónasson, Erez Yoeli","doi":"10.1287/msom.2021.1046","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2021.1046","url":null,"abstract":"Problem definition: Lack of patient adherence to treatment protocols is a main barrier to reducing the global disease burden of tuberculosis (TB). We study the operational design of a treatment adherence support (TAS) platform that requires patients to verify their treatment adherence on a daily basis. Academic/practical relevance: Experimental results on the effectiveness of TAS programs have been mixed; and rigorous research is needed on how to structure these motivational programs, particularly in resource-limited settings. Our analysis establishes that patient engagement can be increased by personal sponsor outreach and that patient behavior data can be used to identify at-risk patients for targeted outreach. Methodology: We partner with a TB TAS provider and use data from a completed randomized controlled trial. We use administrative variation in the timing of peer sponsor outreach to evaluate the impact of personal messages on subsequent patient verification behavior. We then develop a rolling-horizon machine learning (ML) framework to generate dynamic risk predictions for patients enrolled on the platform. Results: We find that, on average, sponsor outreach to patients increases the odds ratio of next-day treatment adherence verification by 35%. Furthermore, patients’ prior verification behavior can be used to accurately predict short-term (treatment adherence verification) and long-term (successful treatment completion) outcomes. These results allow the provider to target and implement behavioral interventions to at-risk patients. Managerial implications: Our results indicate that, compared with a benchmark policy, the TAS platform could reach the same number of at-risk patients with 6%–40% less capacity, or reach 2%–20% more at-risk patients with the same capacity, by using various ML-based prioritization policies that leverage patient engagement data. Personal sponsor outreach to all patients is likely to be very costly, so targeted TAS may substantially improve the cost-effectiveness of TAS programs.","PeriodicalId":18108,"journal":{"name":"Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag.","volume":"06 1","pages":"2925-2943"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2021-12-20","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"86516267","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 6
Product Flexibility Strategy Under Supply and Demand Risk 供需风险下的产品柔性策略
Pub Date : 2021-12-14 DOI: 10.1287/msom.2021.1037
Yimin Wang, S. Webster
Problem definition: With heightened global uncertainty, supply chain managers are under increasing pressure to craft strategies that accommodate both supply and demand risks. Although product flexibility is a well-understood strategy to accommodate risk, there is no clear guidance on the optimal flexibility configuration of a supply network that comprises both unreliable primary suppliers and reliable backup suppliers. Academic/practical relevance: Existing literature examines the value of flexibility with primary and backup suppliers independently. For a risk-neutral firm, research shows that (a) incorporating flexibility in a primary supplier by replacing two dedicated ones (in absence of backup supply) is always beneficial and that (b) adding flexibility to a reliable backup supplier (in absence of product flexibility in primary suppliers) is always valuable. It is unclear, however, how flexibility should be incorporated into a supply network with both unreliable primary suppliers and reliable backup suppliers. This research studies whether flexibility should be incorporated in a primary supplier, a backup supplier, or both. Methodology: We develop a normative model to analyze when flexibility benefits and when it hurts. Results: Compared with a base case of no flexibility, we prove that incorporating flexibility in either primary or backup suppliers is always beneficial. However, incorporating flexibility in both primary and backup suppliers can be counterproductive because the supply chain performance can decline with saturated flexibility, even if flexibility is costless. A key reason is that the risk-aggregation effect of consolidating flexibility in an unreliable supplier becomes more salient when flexibility is already embedded in a backup supplier. Managerial implications: This research refines the existing understanding of flexibility by illustrating that flexibility is not always beneficial. When there is a choice, a firm should prioritize incorporating flexibility in a reliable backup supplier.
问题定义:随着全球不确定性的增加,供应链管理人员面临着越来越大的压力,他们需要制定适应供需风险的战略。虽然产品灵活性是一种众所周知的适应风险的策略,但对于由不可靠的主要供应商和可靠的备用供应商组成的供应网络的最佳灵活性配置,没有明确的指导。学术/实践相关性:现有文献独立考察了主要和备用供应商的灵活性价值。对于一个风险中性的公司,研究表明:(a)通过替换两个专用供应商(在没有备用供应的情况下)来增加主要供应商的灵活性总是有益的,(b)增加可靠的备用供应商的灵活性(在主要供应商缺乏产品灵活性的情况下)总是有价值的。然而,目前尚不清楚如何将灵活性纳入一个既有不可靠的主要供应商又有可靠的备用供应商的供应网络。本研究探讨是否应将弹性纳入主要供应商、备用供应商或两者。方法:我们开发了一个规范模型来分析灵活性何时有益,何时有害。结果:与没有灵活性的基本情况相比,我们证明了在主要或备用供应商中加入灵活性总是有益的。然而,将灵活性纳入主要和备用供应商可能会适得其反,因为即使灵活性是无成本的,供应链的性能也会随着灵活性的饱和而下降。一个关键的原因是,在一个不可靠的供应商中整合灵活性的风险聚集效应会在一个备用供应商中嵌入灵活性时变得更加突出。管理意义:本研究通过说明灵活性并不总是有益的,从而改进了对灵活性的现有理解。当有选择时,公司应该优先考虑将灵活性纳入可靠的备用供应商。
{"title":"Product Flexibility Strategy Under Supply and Demand Risk","authors":"Yimin Wang, S. Webster","doi":"10.1287/msom.2021.1037","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2021.1037","url":null,"abstract":"Problem definition: With heightened global uncertainty, supply chain managers are under increasing pressure to craft strategies that accommodate both supply and demand risks. Although product flexibility is a well-understood strategy to accommodate risk, there is no clear guidance on the optimal flexibility configuration of a supply network that comprises both unreliable primary suppliers and reliable backup suppliers. Academic/practical relevance: Existing literature examines the value of flexibility with primary and backup suppliers independently. For a risk-neutral firm, research shows that (a) incorporating flexibility in a primary supplier by replacing two dedicated ones (in absence of backup supply) is always beneficial and that (b) adding flexibility to a reliable backup supplier (in absence of product flexibility in primary suppliers) is always valuable. It is unclear, however, how flexibility should be incorporated into a supply network with both unreliable primary suppliers and reliable backup suppliers. This research studies whether flexibility should be incorporated in a primary supplier, a backup supplier, or both. Methodology: We develop a normative model to analyze when flexibility benefits and when it hurts. Results: Compared with a base case of no flexibility, we prove that incorporating flexibility in either primary or backup suppliers is always beneficial. However, incorporating flexibility in both primary and backup suppliers can be counterproductive because the supply chain performance can decline with saturated flexibility, even if flexibility is costless. A key reason is that the risk-aggregation effect of consolidating flexibility in an unreliable supplier becomes more salient when flexibility is already embedded in a backup supplier. Managerial implications: This research refines the existing understanding of flexibility by illustrating that flexibility is not always beneficial. When there is a choice, a firm should prioritize incorporating flexibility in a reliable backup supplier.","PeriodicalId":18108,"journal":{"name":"Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag.","volume":"7 1","pages":"1779-1795"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2021-12-14","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"89752976","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 5
Omnichannel Assortment Optimization Under the Multinomial Logit Model with a Features Tree 特征树多项式Logit模型下的全渠道分类优化
Pub Date : 2021-12-03 DOI: 10.1287/msom.2021.1001
Venus Lo, Huseyin Topaloglu
Problem definition: We consider the assortment optimization problem of a retailer that operates a physical store and an online store. The products that can be offered are described by their features. Customers purchase among the products that are offered in their preferred store. However, customers who purchase from the online store can first test out products offered in the physical store. These customers revise their preferences for online products based on the features that are shared with the in-store products. The full assortment is offered online, and the goal is to select an assortment for the physical store to maximize the retailer’s total expected revenue. Academic/practical relevance: The physical store’s assortment affects preferences for online products. Unlike traditional assortment optimization, the physical store’s assortment influences revenue from both stores. Methodology: We introduce a features tree to organize products by features. The nonleaf vertices on the tree correspond to features, and the leaf vertices correspond to products. The ancestors of a leaf correspond to features of the product. Customers choose among the products within their store’s assortment according to the multinomial logit model. We consider two settings; either all customers purchase online after viewing products in the physical store, or we have a mix of customers purchasing from each store. Results: When all customers purchase online, we give an efficient algorithm to find the optimal assortment to display in the physical store. With a mix of customers, the problem becomes NP-hard, and we give a fully polynomial-time approximation scheme. We numerically demonstrate that we can closely approximate the case where products have arbitrary combinations of features without a tree structure and that our fully polynomial-time approximation scheme performs remarkably well. Managerial implications: We characterize conditions under which it is optimal to display expensive products with underrated features and expose inexpensive products with overrated features.
问题定义:我们考虑经营实体店和网上商店的零售商的分类优化问题。可以提供的产品是通过它们的特性来描述的。顾客在他们喜欢的商店提供的产品中购买。然而,从网上商店购买的顾客可以先试用实体店提供的产品。这些客户根据与实体店产品共享的特性来修改他们对在线产品的偏好。在线提供完整的分类,目标是为实体店选择分类,以最大化零售商的总预期收入。学术/实践相关性:实体店的分类会影响人们对在线产品的偏好。与传统的分类优化不同,实体店的分类会影响两家店的收入。方法:我们引入了一个功能树来按功能组织产品。树的非叶顶点对应特征,叶顶点对应产品。叶子的祖先对应于产品的特征。顾客根据多项logit模型在商店的产品分类中进行选择。我们考虑两种情况;所有客户在实体店查看产品后在线购买,或者我们有从每个商店购买的混合客户。结果:当所有顾客都在网上购物时,我们给出了一种有效的算法来找到在实体店展示的最佳分类。对于混合客户,问题变得np困难,我们给出了一个完全多项式时间近似格式。我们在数值上证明,我们可以近似地逼近产品具有任意特征组合而没有树结构的情况,并且我们的完全多项式时间近似方案执行得非常好。管理意义:我们描述了在哪些条件下展示功能被低估的昂贵产品和暴露功能被高估的廉价产品是最佳的。
{"title":"Omnichannel Assortment Optimization Under the Multinomial Logit Model with a Features Tree","authors":"Venus Lo, Huseyin Topaloglu","doi":"10.1287/msom.2021.1001","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2021.1001","url":null,"abstract":"Problem definition: We consider the assortment optimization problem of a retailer that operates a physical store and an online store. The products that can be offered are described by their features. Customers purchase among the products that are offered in their preferred store. However, customers who purchase from the online store can first test out products offered in the physical store. These customers revise their preferences for online products based on the features that are shared with the in-store products. The full assortment is offered online, and the goal is to select an assortment for the physical store to maximize the retailer’s total expected revenue. Academic/practical relevance: The physical store’s assortment affects preferences for online products. Unlike traditional assortment optimization, the physical store’s assortment influences revenue from both stores. Methodology: We introduce a features tree to organize products by features. The nonleaf vertices on the tree correspond to features, and the leaf vertices correspond to products. The ancestors of a leaf correspond to features of the product. Customers choose among the products within their store’s assortment according to the multinomial logit model. We consider two settings; either all customers purchase online after viewing products in the physical store, or we have a mix of customers purchasing from each store. Results: When all customers purchase online, we give an efficient algorithm to find the optimal assortment to display in the physical store. With a mix of customers, the problem becomes NP-hard, and we give a fully polynomial-time approximation scheme. We numerically demonstrate that we can closely approximate the case where products have arbitrary combinations of features without a tree structure and that our fully polynomial-time approximation scheme performs remarkably well. Managerial implications: We characterize conditions under which it is optimal to display expensive products with underrated features and expose inexpensive products with overrated features.","PeriodicalId":18108,"journal":{"name":"Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag.","volume":"17 1","pages":"1220-1240"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2021-12-03","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"86344863","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 7
Effective Online Order Acceptance Policies for Omnichannel Fulfillment 有效的在线订单接受政策的全渠道履行
Pub Date : 2021-12-01 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3932692
Su Jia, Jeremy Karp, R. Ravi, S. Tayur
Problem definition: Omnichannel retailing has led to the use of traditional stores as fulfillment centers for online orders. Omnichannel fulfillment problems have two components: (1) accepting a certain number of online orders prior to seeing store demands and (2) satisfying (or filling) some of these accepted online demands as efficiently as possible with any leftover inventory after store demands have been met. Hence, there is a fundamental trade-off between store cancellations of accepted online orders and potentially increased profits because of more acceptances of online orders. We study this joint problem of online order acceptance and fulfillment (including cancellations) to minimize total costs, including shipping charges and cancellation penalties in single-period and limited multiperiod settings. Academic/practical relevance: Despite the growing importance of omnichannel fulfillment via online orders, our work provides the first study incorporating cancellation penalties along with fulfillment costs. Methodology: We build a two-stage stochastic model. In the first stage, the retailer sets a policy specifying which online orders it will accept. The second stage represents the process of fulfilling online orders after the uncertain quantities of in-store purchases are revealed. We analyze threshold policies that accept online orders as long as the inventories are above a global threshold, a local threshold per region, or a hybrid. Results: For a single period, total costs are unimodal as a function of the global threshold and unimodal as a function of a single local threshold holding all other local thresholds at constant values, motivating a gradient search algorithm. Reformulating as an appropriate linear program with network flow structure, we estimate the derivative (using infinitesimal perturbation analysis) of the total cost as a function of the thresholds. We validate the performance of the threshold policies empirically using data from a high-end North American retailer. Our two-location experiments demonstrate that local thresholds perform better than global thresholds in a wide variety of settings. Conversely, in a narrow region with negatively correlated online demand between locations and very low shipping costs, global threshold outperforms local thresholds. A hybrid policy only marginally improves on the better of the two. In multiple periods, we study one- and two-location models and provide insights into effective solution methods for the general case. Managerial implications: Our methods provide effective algorithms to manage fulfillment costs for online orders, demonstrating a significant reduction over policies that treat each location separately and reflecting the significant advantage of incorporating shipping in computing thresholds. Numerical studies provide insights as to why local thresholds perform well in a wide variety of situations.
问题定义:全渠道零售导致使用传统商店作为在线订单的履行中心。全渠道履行问题有两个组成部分:(1)在看到商店需求之前接受一定数量的在线订单;(2)在满足商店需求之后,尽可能有效地满足(或填补)这些接受的在线需求中的一些剩余库存。因此,在商店取消接受的在线订单和由于接受更多的在线订单而潜在增加的利润之间存在一个基本的权衡。我们研究了在线订单接受和履行(包括取消)的联合问题,以最小化总成本,包括单周期和有限多周期设置下的运费和取消罚款。学术/实践相关性:尽管通过在线订单实现全渠道履行的重要性日益增加,但我们的工作提供了第一个将取消处罚与履行成本结合起来的研究。方法:建立两阶段随机模型。在第一阶段,零售商设置一个策略,指定它将接受哪些在线订单。第二阶段是在发现店内购买数量不确定后,完成在线订单的过程。我们分析阈值策略,只要库存高于全局阈值、每个区域的本地阈值或混合阈值,就接受在线订单。结果:对于单个周期,总成本作为全局阈值的单峰函数,作为单个局部阈值的单峰函数,将所有其他局部阈值保持在恒定值,从而激发梯度搜索算法。作为一个适当的线性规划与网络流结构,我们估计的导数(使用无穷小摄动分析)的总成本作为阈值的函数。我们使用来自北美高端零售商的数据验证阈值策略的性能。我们的双位置实验表明,在各种设置下,局部阈值比全局阈值表现得更好。相反,在地理位置之间在线需求呈负相关且运输成本非常低的狭窄区域,全球阈值优于本地阈值。混合政策只在两者中较好的方面有所改善。在多个时期,我们研究了一个和两个位置模型,并为一般情况提供了有效的解决方法。管理意义:我们的方法提供了有效的算法来管理在线订单的履行成本,与单独处理每个位置的策略相比,显示了显著的降低,并反映了将运输纳入计算阈值的显著优势。数值研究提供了关于为什么局部阈值在各种情况下表现良好的见解。
{"title":"Effective Online Order Acceptance Policies for Omnichannel Fulfillment","authors":"Su Jia, Jeremy Karp, R. Ravi, S. Tayur","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3932692","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3932692","url":null,"abstract":"Problem definition: Omnichannel retailing has led to the use of traditional stores as fulfillment centers for online orders. Omnichannel fulfillment problems have two components: (1) accepting a certain number of online orders prior to seeing store demands and (2) satisfying (or filling) some of these accepted online demands as efficiently as possible with any leftover inventory after store demands have been met. Hence, there is a fundamental trade-off between store cancellations of accepted online orders and potentially increased profits because of more acceptances of online orders. We study this joint problem of online order acceptance and fulfillment (including cancellations) to minimize total costs, including shipping charges and cancellation penalties in single-period and limited multiperiod settings. Academic/practical relevance: Despite the growing importance of omnichannel fulfillment via online orders, our work provides the first study incorporating cancellation penalties along with fulfillment costs. Methodology: We build a two-stage stochastic model. In the first stage, the retailer sets a policy specifying which online orders it will accept. The second stage represents the process of fulfilling online orders after the uncertain quantities of in-store purchases are revealed. We analyze threshold policies that accept online orders as long as the inventories are above a global threshold, a local threshold per region, or a hybrid. Results: For a single period, total costs are unimodal as a function of the global threshold and unimodal as a function of a single local threshold holding all other local thresholds at constant values, motivating a gradient search algorithm. Reformulating as an appropriate linear program with network flow structure, we estimate the derivative (using infinitesimal perturbation analysis) of the total cost as a function of the thresholds. We validate the performance of the threshold policies empirically using data from a high-end North American retailer. Our two-location experiments demonstrate that local thresholds perform better than global thresholds in a wide variety of settings. Conversely, in a narrow region with negatively correlated online demand between locations and very low shipping costs, global threshold outperforms local thresholds. A hybrid policy only marginally improves on the better of the two. In multiple periods, we study one- and two-location models and provide insights into effective solution methods for the general case. Managerial implications: Our methods provide effective algorithms to manage fulfillment costs for online orders, demonstrating a significant reduction over policies that treat each location separately and reflecting the significant advantage of incorporating shipping in computing thresholds. Numerical studies provide insights as to why local thresholds perform well in a wide variety of situations.","PeriodicalId":18108,"journal":{"name":"Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag.","volume":"29 1","pages":"1650-1663"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2021-12-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"89985884","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 10
Before It's Too Late: Product Recall Delays and Policy Design 为时未晚:产品召回延迟与政策设计
Pub Date : 2021-11-23 DOI: 10.1287/msom.2021.1042
W. Mao, Zhanyu Dong, Hsiao-Hui Lee
Problem definition: We examine a firm’s investigation and recall decisions when a defect occurs and provide policy implications on how to deter long delayed recalls. Practical relevance: When a safety defect occurs, manufacturers often use product recalls to mitigate potential consequences. Although consumers expect on-time recalls for product defects, anecdotal examples suggest that firms may be passive in investigating potential defects and/or severely delay their recall decisions. Understanding how firms make their recall timing decisions has important business and social implications. Methodology: We study decisions on investigation efforts and recall timings for a profit-maximizing manufacturer by incorporating a Bass diffusion model to capture sales patterns for products with long life cycles. We then test our implications using data from the automobile industry and find supporting evidence. Results: We first find that a firm will consider a delayed recall when the defect is noticed early, when sales suffer more negative impacts from (external) media exposure on a recall, and when the product has a relatively high margin-to-recall-cost ratio. Second, a firm that will consider a delayed recall exerts a smaller investigation effort, and it will further reduce the effort when the defect is more likely to lead to a recall. When we consider the case in which a firm’s learning effect and information updating occur in an investigation and recall process, our results remain consistent. Managerial implications: Our model not only helps us understand how firms make their decisions when defects occur but also offers governments and regulatory bodies new instruments (e.g., investigation efforts, penalty design, information disclosure, firm supervision) to help firms be proactive should a defect occur, thereby reducing potential casualties associated with delays in a recall progress.
问题定义:当缺陷发生时,我们检查公司的调查和召回决定,并提供如何阻止长时间延迟召回的政策含义。实际相关性:当安全缺陷发生时,制造商通常使用产品召回来减轻潜在的后果。虽然消费者期望产品缺陷及时召回,但坊间的例子表明,公司在调查潜在缺陷时可能会被动,并且/或者严重推迟召回决定。了解企业如何做出召回时机决策具有重要的商业和社会意义。方法:我们通过结合Bass扩散模型来捕捉具有长生命周期产品的销售模式,研究利润最大化制造商的调查努力和召回时间决策。然后,我们使用来自汽车行业的数据来测试我们的含义,并找到支持证据。结果:我们首先发现,当缺陷被早期发现,当销售受到(外部)媒体曝光对召回的负面影响更大,以及当产品具有相对较高的边际召回成本比时,公司会考虑延迟召回。其次,考虑延迟召回的公司会施加较小的调查努力,并且当缺陷更有可能导致召回时,它将进一步减少努力。当我们考虑企业的学习效应和信息更新发生在调查和召回过程中的情况时,我们的结果是一致的。管理意义:我们的模型不仅帮助我们了解公司在缺陷发生时如何做出决策,而且还为政府和监管机构提供了新的工具(例如,调查努力、处罚设计、信息披露、公司监督),以帮助公司在缺陷发生时积极主动,从而减少与召回过程延迟相关的潜在伤亡。
{"title":"Before It's Too Late: Product Recall Delays and Policy Design","authors":"W. Mao, Zhanyu Dong, Hsiao-Hui Lee","doi":"10.1287/msom.2021.1042","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2021.1042","url":null,"abstract":"Problem definition: We examine a firm’s investigation and recall decisions when a defect occurs and provide policy implications on how to deter long delayed recalls. Practical relevance: When a safety defect occurs, manufacturers often use product recalls to mitigate potential consequences. Although consumers expect on-time recalls for product defects, anecdotal examples suggest that firms may be passive in investigating potential defects and/or severely delay their recall decisions. Understanding how firms make their recall timing decisions has important business and social implications. Methodology: We study decisions on investigation efforts and recall timings for a profit-maximizing manufacturer by incorporating a Bass diffusion model to capture sales patterns for products with long life cycles. We then test our implications using data from the automobile industry and find supporting evidence. Results: We first find that a firm will consider a delayed recall when the defect is noticed early, when sales suffer more negative impacts from (external) media exposure on a recall, and when the product has a relatively high margin-to-recall-cost ratio. Second, a firm that will consider a delayed recall exerts a smaller investigation effort, and it will further reduce the effort when the defect is more likely to lead to a recall. When we consider the case in which a firm’s learning effect and information updating occur in an investigation and recall process, our results remain consistent. Managerial implications: Our model not only helps us understand how firms make their decisions when defects occur but also offers governments and regulatory bodies new instruments (e.g., investigation efforts, penalty design, information disclosure, firm supervision) to help firms be proactive should a defect occur, thereby reducing potential casualties associated with delays in a recall progress.","PeriodicalId":18108,"journal":{"name":"Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag.","volume":"9 1","pages":"1926-1938"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2021-11-23","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"82566950","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2
期刊
Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag.
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1