首页 > 最新文献

Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag.最新文献

英文 中文
A Markov Decision Model for Managing Display-Advertising Campaigns 展示广告活动管理的马尔可夫决策模型
Pub Date : 2022-12-14 DOI: 10.1287/msom.2022.1142
N. Agrawal, Sami Najafi-Asadolahi, Stephen A. Smith
Problem definition: Managers in ad agencies are responsible for delivering digital ads to viewers on behalf of advertisers, subject to the terms specified in the ad campaigns. They need to develop bidding policies to obtain viewers on an ad exchange and allocate them to the campaigns to maximize the agency’s profits, subject to the goals of the ad campaigns. Academic/practical relevance: Determining a rigorous solution methodology is complicated by uncertainties in the arrival rates of viewers and campaigns, as well as uncertainty in the outcomes of bids on the ad exchange. In practice, ad hoc strategies are often deployed. Our methodology jointly determines optimal bidding and viewer-allocation strategies and obtains insights about the characteristics of the optimal policies. Methodology: New ad campaigns and viewers are treated as Poisson arrivals, and the resulting model is a Markov decision process, where the state of the system is the number of undelivered impressions in queue for each campaign type in each period. We develop solution methods for bid optimization and viewer allocation and perform a sensitivity analysis with respect to the key problem parameters. Results: We solve for the optimal dynamic, state-dependent bidding and allocation policies as a function of the number of ad impressions in queue, for both the finite horizon and steady-state cases. We show that the resulting optimization problems are strictly concave in the decision variables and develop and evaluate a heuristic method that can be applied to large problems. Managerial implications: Numerical analysis of our heuristic solution shows that its errors are generally small and that the optimal dynamic, state-dependent bidding policies obtained by our model are significantly better than optimal static policies. Our proposed approach is managerially attractive because it is easy to implement in practice. We identify the capacity of the impression queue as an important managerial control lever and show that it can be more effective than using higher bids to reduce delay penalties. We quantify potential operational benefits from the consolidation of ad campaigns, as well as merging ad exchanges. Supplemental Material: The online appendix is available at https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2022.1142 .
问题定义:广告代理公司的经理负责代表广告商向观众投放数字广告,并遵守广告活动中规定的条款。他们需要制定投标政策,在广告交易中获得观众,并将他们分配到广告活动中,以最大限度地提高代理机构的利润,这取决于广告活动的目标。学术/实践相关性:确定一个严格的解决方案方法是复杂的,因为观众和广告活动到达率的不确定性,以及广告交换投标结果的不确定性。在实践中,经常部署特别策略。我们的方法共同确定了最优竞价和观众分配策略,并获得了关于最优策略特征的见解。方法:新的广告活动和观众被视为泊松到达,结果模型是一个马尔可夫决策过程,其中系统的状态是每个时期每个活动类型队列中未交付的印象数量。我们开发了竞价优化和观众分配的解决方案方法,并对关键问题参数进行了敏感性分析。结果:在有限视界和稳态情况下,我们求解了最优动态、状态相关的竞价和分配策略作为队列中广告展示数的函数。我们证明了所得到的优化问题在决策变量中是严格凹的,并开发和评估了一种可应用于大型问题的启发式方法。管理启示:我们的启发式解决方案的数值分析表明,其误差通常很小,并且我们的模型获得的最优动态,依赖于状态的投标策略明显优于最优静态策略。我们提出的方法在管理上很有吸引力,因为它很容易在实践中实施。我们将印象队列的容量确定为一个重要的管理控制杠杆,并表明它可以比使用更高的出价更有效地减少延迟惩罚。我们量化了整合广告活动以及合并广告交易所带来的潜在运营效益。补充材料:在线附录可在https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2022.1142上获得。
{"title":"A Markov Decision Model for Managing Display-Advertising Campaigns","authors":"N. Agrawal, Sami Najafi-Asadolahi, Stephen A. Smith","doi":"10.1287/msom.2022.1142","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2022.1142","url":null,"abstract":"Problem definition: Managers in ad agencies are responsible for delivering digital ads to viewers on behalf of advertisers, subject to the terms specified in the ad campaigns. They need to develop bidding policies to obtain viewers on an ad exchange and allocate them to the campaigns to maximize the agency’s profits, subject to the goals of the ad campaigns. Academic/practical relevance: Determining a rigorous solution methodology is complicated by uncertainties in the arrival rates of viewers and campaigns, as well as uncertainty in the outcomes of bids on the ad exchange. In practice, ad hoc strategies are often deployed. Our methodology jointly determines optimal bidding and viewer-allocation strategies and obtains insights about the characteristics of the optimal policies. Methodology: New ad campaigns and viewers are treated as Poisson arrivals, and the resulting model is a Markov decision process, where the state of the system is the number of undelivered impressions in queue for each campaign type in each period. We develop solution methods for bid optimization and viewer allocation and perform a sensitivity analysis with respect to the key problem parameters. Results: We solve for the optimal dynamic, state-dependent bidding and allocation policies as a function of the number of ad impressions in queue, for both the finite horizon and steady-state cases. We show that the resulting optimization problems are strictly concave in the decision variables and develop and evaluate a heuristic method that can be applied to large problems. Managerial implications: Numerical analysis of our heuristic solution shows that its errors are generally small and that the optimal dynamic, state-dependent bidding policies obtained by our model are significantly better than optimal static policies. Our proposed approach is managerially attractive because it is easy to implement in practice. We identify the capacity of the impression queue as an important managerial control lever and show that it can be more effective than using higher bids to reduce delay penalties. We quantify potential operational benefits from the consolidation of ad campaigns, as well as merging ad exchanges. Supplemental Material: The online appendix is available at https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2022.1142 .","PeriodicalId":18108,"journal":{"name":"Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag.","volume":"30 1","pages":"489-507"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2022-12-14","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"80874054","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Impacts of Distributive Comparison Behavior on Corporate Social Responsibility in Supply Chains: The Role of Small Firms 供应链中分配比较行为对企业社会责任的影响:小企业的作用
Pub Date : 2022-12-14 DOI: 10.1287/msom.2022.1172
Mingzheng Wang, X. Fang, Zizhuo Wang, Ying‐ju Chen
Problem definition: In this paper, we explore how a firm’s concern about profit distribution and the size of downstream firms in supply chains affect corporate social responsibility (CSR) investment strategy. Methodology/results: In a supply chain consisting of one supplier and one manufacturer, both players decide whether to invest to reduce CSR violations, and they negotiate over a wholesale price. Distributive comparison behavior makes the manufacturer compare the profit with his equitable payoff, which is determined by the supplier’s profit. Advantageous (resp. disadvantageous) inequality occurs when the manufacturer’s profit is higher (resp. lower) than the manufacturer’s equitable payoff. We compare this supply chain to the one without distributive comparison behavior. We find that when advantageous inequality occurs, or when neither inequality occurs and the manufacturer’s sensitivity to the supplier’s profit is low, the manufacturer’s distributive comparison behavior makes the manufacturer less (resp. supplier more) likely to invest in CSR, which we call negative (resp. positive) impacts of distributive comparison behavior; otherwise, it makes the manufacturer more (resp. supplier less) likely to invest. In most cases, the weak bargaining power of the small manufacturer leads to larger positive or smaller negative impacts of distributive comparison behavior. Also, the low efficiency of the small manufacturer to reduce CSR violations leads to smaller negative impacts of distributive comparison behavior. Managerial implications: Our results show that governments and nongovernmental organizations (NGOs) should investigate firms’ distributive comparison behavior in supply chains. When downstream firms show the aversion to lower (resp. higher) profits than ones from upstream firms, the measures to monitor and support upstream (resp. downstream) firms’ CSR investments should be taken to avoid CSR violations. In the supply chains with small downstream firms, extra efforts should be made to induce firms’ distributive comparison behavior. Funding: M. Wang was supported partially by the National Natural Science Foundation of China [Grants 71931009 and 71671023]; X. Fang is grateful for the support under a Lee Kong Chian Fellowship and Retail Centre of Excellence Research Grant; Z. Wang was supported partially by the National Natural Science Foundation of China [Grants 72010107002, 71671023, and 72171212]; and Y. Chen was supported partially by the Research Grants Council of the Hong Kong Special Administrative Region, China [HKUST C6020-21GF]. Supplemental Material: The e-companion is available at https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2022.1172 .
问题定义:本文探讨企业对利润分配和供应链下游企业规模的关注如何影响企业社会责任(CSR)投资策略。方法/结果:在由一个供应商和一个制造商组成的供应链中,双方决定是否投资以减少违反CSR的行为,并就批发价格进行谈判。分配比较行为是指制造商将利润与其公平报酬进行比较,而公平报酬是由供应商的利润决定的。优势(分别地。不利的)不平等发生在制造商的利润较高时(如:低于制造商的公平报酬。我们将这个供应链与没有分配比较行为的供应链进行比较。我们发现,当优势不平等发生时,或不存在优势不平等且制造商对供应商利润的敏感性较低时,制造商的分配比较行为使制造商较少(p < 0.05)。供应商更有可能投资于企业社会责任,我们称之为负(负)责任。分配比较行为的正向影响;否则,它会使制造商更有责任感。供应商不太可能投资。在大多数情况下,小制造商的议价能力较弱导致分配比较行为的积极影响较大或消极影响较小。同时,小型制造商减少企业社会责任违规行为的效率较低,导致分配比较行为的负面影响较小。管理启示:我们的研究结果表明,政府和非政府组织(ngo)应该调查企业在供应链中的分配比较行为。当下游企业表现出对低利率的厌恶时。高于上游企业的利润,监控和支持上游企业的措施(如:下游企业应采取企业社会责任投资来避免违反企业社会责任。在下游企业规模较小的供应链中,应额外努力诱导企业的分配比较行为。基金资助:王先生部分得到国家自然科学基金资助[基金项目:71931009和71671023];方先贤感谢李光前奖学金及零售卓越研究中心资助;王志强获国家自然科学基金项目(项目编号:72010107002、71671023、72171212)部分资助;及陈毅获中国香港特别行政区研究资助局的部分资助[HKUST C6020-21GF]。补充材料:电子伴侣可在https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2022.1172上获得。
{"title":"Impacts of Distributive Comparison Behavior on Corporate Social Responsibility in Supply Chains: The Role of Small Firms","authors":"Mingzheng Wang, X. Fang, Zizhuo Wang, Ying‐ju Chen","doi":"10.1287/msom.2022.1172","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2022.1172","url":null,"abstract":"Problem definition: In this paper, we explore how a firm’s concern about profit distribution and the size of downstream firms in supply chains affect corporate social responsibility (CSR) investment strategy. Methodology/results: In a supply chain consisting of one supplier and one manufacturer, both players decide whether to invest to reduce CSR violations, and they negotiate over a wholesale price. Distributive comparison behavior makes the manufacturer compare the profit with his equitable payoff, which is determined by the supplier’s profit. Advantageous (resp. disadvantageous) inequality occurs when the manufacturer’s profit is higher (resp. lower) than the manufacturer’s equitable payoff. We compare this supply chain to the one without distributive comparison behavior. We find that when advantageous inequality occurs, or when neither inequality occurs and the manufacturer’s sensitivity to the supplier’s profit is low, the manufacturer’s distributive comparison behavior makes the manufacturer less (resp. supplier more) likely to invest in CSR, which we call negative (resp. positive) impacts of distributive comparison behavior; otherwise, it makes the manufacturer more (resp. supplier less) likely to invest. In most cases, the weak bargaining power of the small manufacturer leads to larger positive or smaller negative impacts of distributive comparison behavior. Also, the low efficiency of the small manufacturer to reduce CSR violations leads to smaller negative impacts of distributive comparison behavior. Managerial implications: Our results show that governments and nongovernmental organizations (NGOs) should investigate firms’ distributive comparison behavior in supply chains. When downstream firms show the aversion to lower (resp. higher) profits than ones from upstream firms, the measures to monitor and support upstream (resp. downstream) firms’ CSR investments should be taken to avoid CSR violations. In the supply chains with small downstream firms, extra efforts should be made to induce firms’ distributive comparison behavior. Funding: M. Wang was supported partially by the National Natural Science Foundation of China [Grants 71931009 and 71671023]; X. Fang is grateful for the support under a Lee Kong Chian Fellowship and Retail Centre of Excellence Research Grant; Z. Wang was supported partially by the National Natural Science Foundation of China [Grants 72010107002, 71671023, and 72171212]; and Y. Chen was supported partially by the Research Grants Council of the Hong Kong Special Administrative Region, China [HKUST C6020-21GF]. Supplemental Material: The e-companion is available at https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2022.1172 .","PeriodicalId":18108,"journal":{"name":"Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag.","volume":"292 1","pages":"686-703"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2022-12-14","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"77170710","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 3
Order Fulfillment Under Pick Failure in Omnichannel Ship-From-Store Programs 全渠道提货失败情况下的订单履行
Pub Date : 2022-12-09 DOI: 10.1287/msom.2022.1164
Sagnik Das, R. Ravi, S. Sridhar
Problem definition: We consider the setting where a retailer with many physical stores and an online presence seeks to fulfill online orders using an omnichannel fulfillment program, such as buy-online ship-from-store. These fulfillment strategies try to minimize cost while fulfilling orders within acceptable service times. We focus on single-item orders. Typically, all online orders for the item are sent to a favorable set of locations to be filled. Failed trials are sent back for further stages of trial fulfillment until the process times out. The multistage order fulfillment problem is thus an interplay of the pick-failure probabilities at the stores where they may be shipped from and the picking, shipping, and cancellation costs from these locations. Methodology: We model the problem as one of sequencing the stores from which an order is attempted to be picked and shipped in the most cost-effective way over multiple stages. We solve the fulfillment problem optimally by taking into account the changing pick-failure probabilities as a result of other online order fulfillment trials by casting it as a network flow problem with convex costs. We incorporate this as the second stage of a two-stage online order acceptance problem and generalize earlier results to the case with pick failures at stores. Results: We investigate the real-world performance of our methods and models on real order data of several of the top U.S. retailers that use our collaborating e-commerce solutions provider to optimize their fulfillment strategies. Academic/Practical Relevance: Our work enables retailers to incorporate pick failure in their order management systems for ship-from-store programs. Our new online order-acceptance policies that take into account pick failures can thus create significant savings for omnichannel retailers. Supplemental Material: The online appendices are available at https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2022.1164 .
问题定义:我们考虑这样的设置:拥有许多实体店和在线业务的零售商试图使用全渠道履行程序(例如从商店在线购买货物)来完成在线订单。这些执行策略试图在可接受的服务时间内完成订单的同时最小化成本。我们专注于单品订单。通常,该商品的所有在线订单都被发送到一组有利的位置进行填充。失败的试验将被发送回进一步的试验执行阶段,直到流程超时。因此,多阶段订单履行问题是货物可能来自的商店的取货失败概率与这些地点的取货、运输和取消成本之间的相互作用。方法:我们将该问题建模为对商店进行排序的问题之一,在多个阶段中,试图以最具成本效益的方式从商店中挑选和运送订单。我们通过考虑由于其他在线订单履行试验而导致的取货失败概率的变化,将其视为具有凸成本的网络流问题,从而最优地解决了履行问题。我们将此合并为两阶段在线订单接受问题的第二阶段,并将早期结果推广到商店取货失败的情况。结果:我们调查了我们的方法和模型在真实订单数据上的实际性能,这些数据来自几家美国顶级零售商,这些零售商使用我们的合作电子商务解决方案提供商来优化他们的履行策略。学术/实际意义:我们的工作使零售商能够将挑选失败纳入他们的订单管理系统,从商店发货计划。我们新的在线订单接受政策考虑到挑选失败,因此可以为全渠道零售商创造显著的节省。补充材料:在线附录可在https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2022.1164上获得。
{"title":"Order Fulfillment Under Pick Failure in Omnichannel Ship-From-Store Programs","authors":"Sagnik Das, R. Ravi, S. Sridhar","doi":"10.1287/msom.2022.1164","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2022.1164","url":null,"abstract":"Problem definition: We consider the setting where a retailer with many physical stores and an online presence seeks to fulfill online orders using an omnichannel fulfillment program, such as buy-online ship-from-store. These fulfillment strategies try to minimize cost while fulfilling orders within acceptable service times. We focus on single-item orders. Typically, all online orders for the item are sent to a favorable set of locations to be filled. Failed trials are sent back for further stages of trial fulfillment until the process times out. The multistage order fulfillment problem is thus an interplay of the pick-failure probabilities at the stores where they may be shipped from and the picking, shipping, and cancellation costs from these locations. Methodology: We model the problem as one of sequencing the stores from which an order is attempted to be picked and shipped in the most cost-effective way over multiple stages. We solve the fulfillment problem optimally by taking into account the changing pick-failure probabilities as a result of other online order fulfillment trials by casting it as a network flow problem with convex costs. We incorporate this as the second stage of a two-stage online order acceptance problem and generalize earlier results to the case with pick failures at stores. Results: We investigate the real-world performance of our methods and models on real order data of several of the top U.S. retailers that use our collaborating e-commerce solutions provider to optimize their fulfillment strategies. Academic/Practical Relevance: Our work enables retailers to incorporate pick failure in their order management systems for ship-from-store programs. Our new online order-acceptance policies that take into account pick failures can thus create significant savings for omnichannel retailers. Supplemental Material: The online appendices are available at https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2022.1164 .","PeriodicalId":18108,"journal":{"name":"Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag.","volume":"75 1","pages":"508-523"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2022-12-09","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"86144964","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Manage Inventories with Learning on Demands and Buy-up Substitution Probability 利用需求学习和购买替代概率管理库存
Pub Date : 2022-12-08 DOI: 10.1287/msom.2022.1169
Zhenwei Luo, Pengfei Guo, Yulan Wang
Problem Definition: This paper considers a setting in which an airline company sells seats periodically, and each period consists of two selling phases, an early-bird discount phase and a regular-price phase. In each period, when the early-bird discount seat is stocked out, an early-bird customer who comes for the discounted seat either purchases the regular-price seat as a substitute (called buy-up substitution) or simply leaves. Methodology/Results: The optimal inventory level of the discounted seats reserved for the early-bird sale is a critical decision for the airline company to maximize its revenue. The airline company learns about the demands for both discounted and regular-price seats and the buy-up substitution probability from historical sales data, which, in turn, are affected by past inventory allocation decisions. In this paper, we investigate two information scenarios based on whether lost sales are observable, and we provide the corresponding Bayesian updating mechanism for learning about demand parameters and substitution probability. We then construct a dynamic programming model to derive the Bayesian optimal inventory level decisions in a multiperiod setting. The literature finds that the unobservability of lost sales drives the inventory manager to stock more (i.e., the Bayesian optimal inventory level should be kept higher than the myopic inventory level) to observe and learn more about demand distributions. Here, we show that when the buy-up substitution probability is known, one may stock less, because one can infer some information about the primary demand for the discounted seat from the customer substitution behavior. We also find that to learn about the unknown buy-up substitution probability drives the inventory manager to stock less so as to induce more substitution trials. Finally, we develop a SoftMax algorithm to solve our dynamic programming problem. We show that the obtained stock more (less) result can be utilized to speed up the convergence of the algorithm to the optimal solution. Managerial Implications: Our results shed light on the airline seat protection level decision with learning about demand parameters and buy-up substitution probability. Compared with myopic optimization, Bayesian inventory decisions that consider the exploration-exploitation tradeoff can avoid getting stuck in local optima and improve the revenue. We also identify new driving forces behind the stock more (less) result that complement the Bayesian inventory management literature. Funding: Z. Luo acknowledges the financial support by the Internal Start-up Fund of The Hong Kong Polytechnic University [Grant P0039035]. P. Guo acknowledges the financial support from the Research Grants Council of Hong Kong [Grant 15508518]. Y. Wang’s work was supported by the Research Grants Council of Hong Kong [Grant 15505318] and the National Natural Science Foundation of China [Grant 71971184]. Supplemental Material: The e-companion is available at htt
问题定义:本文考虑一个航空公司定期销售座位的设定,每个时期包括两个销售阶段,一个是早鸟折扣阶段,一个是正价阶段。在每个时期,当早到的折扣座位被卖光时,一个早到的顾客要么购买正价座位作为替代(称为买断替代),要么干脆离开。方法/结果:对于航空公司而言,为早鸟销售预留折扣座位的最优库存水平是实现收益最大化的关键决策。航空公司从历史销售数据中了解到对折扣和正价座位的需求以及购买替代概率,而历史销售数据又受到过去库存分配决策的影响。本文研究了基于销售损失是否可观察的两种信息情景,并提供了相应的贝叶斯更新机制来学习需求参数和替代概率。在此基础上,构建了一个动态规划模型,推导出多周期环境下的贝叶斯最优库存水平决策。文献发现,销售损失的不可观察性促使库存管理者增加库存(即贝叶斯最优库存水平应高于近视库存水平),以观察和了解更多的需求分布。在此,我们证明了当购买替代概率已知时,人们可能会减少库存,因为人们可以从顾客替代行为中推断出对折扣座位的主要需求的一些信息。我们还发现,了解未知的购买替代概率会促使库存管理者减少库存,从而引发更多的替代试验。最后,我们开发了一个SoftMax算法来解决我们的动态规划问题。我们证明了所得到的库存多(少)结果可以用来加快算法收敛到最优解的速度。管理启示:我们的研究结果揭示了航空公司座位保护水平的决策,了解了需求参数和购买替代概率。与短视优化相比,考虑勘探开发权衡的贝叶斯库存决策可以避免陷入局部最优,提高收益。我们还确定了库存多(少)结果背后的新驱动力,以补充贝叶斯库存管理文献。基金资助:罗铮感谢香港理工大学内部创业基金的资助[Grant P0039035]。郭培平感谢香港研究资助局的资助[拨款号15508518]。Wang Y.的研究得到香港研究资助局[Grant 15505318]和中国国家自然科学基金[Grant 71971184]的资助。补充材料:电子伴侣可在https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2022.1169上获得。
{"title":"Manage Inventories with Learning on Demands and Buy-up Substitution Probability","authors":"Zhenwei Luo, Pengfei Guo, Yulan Wang","doi":"10.1287/msom.2022.1169","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2022.1169","url":null,"abstract":"Problem Definition: This paper considers a setting in which an airline company sells seats periodically, and each period consists of two selling phases, an early-bird discount phase and a regular-price phase. In each period, when the early-bird discount seat is stocked out, an early-bird customer who comes for the discounted seat either purchases the regular-price seat as a substitute (called buy-up substitution) or simply leaves. Methodology/Results: The optimal inventory level of the discounted seats reserved for the early-bird sale is a critical decision for the airline company to maximize its revenue. The airline company learns about the demands for both discounted and regular-price seats and the buy-up substitution probability from historical sales data, which, in turn, are affected by past inventory allocation decisions. In this paper, we investigate two information scenarios based on whether lost sales are observable, and we provide the corresponding Bayesian updating mechanism for learning about demand parameters and substitution probability. We then construct a dynamic programming model to derive the Bayesian optimal inventory level decisions in a multiperiod setting. The literature finds that the unobservability of lost sales drives the inventory manager to stock more (i.e., the Bayesian optimal inventory level should be kept higher than the myopic inventory level) to observe and learn more about demand distributions. Here, we show that when the buy-up substitution probability is known, one may stock less, because one can infer some information about the primary demand for the discounted seat from the customer substitution behavior. We also find that to learn about the unknown buy-up substitution probability drives the inventory manager to stock less so as to induce more substitution trials. Finally, we develop a SoftMax algorithm to solve our dynamic programming problem. We show that the obtained stock more (less) result can be utilized to speed up the convergence of the algorithm to the optimal solution. Managerial Implications: Our results shed light on the airline seat protection level decision with learning about demand parameters and buy-up substitution probability. Compared with myopic optimization, Bayesian inventory decisions that consider the exploration-exploitation tradeoff can avoid getting stuck in local optima and improve the revenue. We also identify new driving forces behind the stock more (less) result that complement the Bayesian inventory management literature. Funding: Z. Luo acknowledges the financial support by the Internal Start-up Fund of The Hong Kong Polytechnic University [Grant P0039035]. P. Guo acknowledges the financial support from the Research Grants Council of Hong Kong [Grant 15508518]. Y. Wang’s work was supported by the Research Grants Council of Hong Kong [Grant 15505318] and the National Natural Science Foundation of China [Grant 71971184]. Supplemental Material: The e-companion is available at htt","PeriodicalId":18108,"journal":{"name":"Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag.","volume":"24 1","pages":"563-580"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2022-12-08","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"89145526","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Optimal Enrollment in Late-Stage New Drug Development with Learning of Drug's Efficacy for Group-Sequential Clinical Trials 群体序贯临床试验中药物疗效学习的新药开发后期最佳入组
Pub Date : 2022-12-05 DOI: 10.1287/msom.2022.1162
Zhili Tian, Gordon B. Hazen, Hong Li
Problem definition: The cost for developing a new drug ranged from $1 billion to more than $2 billion between 2010 and 2019. In addition to high development costs, the efficacy of the candidate drug, patient enrollment, the market exclusivity period (MEP), and the planning horizon are uncertain. Moreover, slow enrollment leads to increased costs, canceled clinical trials, and lost potential revenue. Many firms, hoping to detect efficacy versus futility of the candidate drug early to save development costs, plan interim analyses of patient-response data in their clinical trials. Academic/practical relevance: The problem for optimizing patient-enrollment rates has an uncertain planning horizon. We developed a continuous-time dynamic programming (DP) model with learning of a drug’s efficacy and MEP to assist firms in developing optimal enrollment policies in their clinical trials. We also established the optimality equation for this DP model. Through a clinical trial for testing a cancer drug developed by a leading pharmaceutical firm, we demonstrate that our DP model can help firms effectively manage their trials with a sizable profit gain (as large as $270 million per drug). Firms can also use our model in simulation to select their trial design parameters (e.g., the sample sizes of interim analyses). Methodology: We update a drug’s efficacy by Bayes’ rules. Using the stochastic order and the likelihood-ratio order of distribution functions, we prove the monotonic properties of the value function and an optimal policy. Results: We established that the value of the drug-development project increases as the average response from patients using the candidate drug increases. For drugs having low annual revenue or a strong market brand or treating rare diseases, we also established that the optimal enrollment policy is monotonic in the average patient response. Moreover, the optimal enrollment rate increases as the variance of the MEP decreases. Managerial implications: Firms can use the properties of the value function to select late-stage clinical trials for their drug-development project portfolios. Firms can also use our optimal policy to guide patient recruitment in their clinical trials considering competition from other drugs in the marketplace. Supplemental Material: The online appendix is available at https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2022.1162 .
问题定义:2010年至2019年间,开发一种新药的成本从10亿美元到20多亿美元不等。除了高昂的开发成本外,候选药物的疗效、患者入组、市场独占期(MEP)和规划范围都不确定。此外,注册缓慢导致成本增加,临床试验取消,潜在收入损失。许多公司希望尽早发现候选药物的有效性和无效性,以节省开发成本,计划在临床试验中对患者反应数据进行中期分析。学术/实践相关性:优化患者入组率的问题具有不确定的规划范围。我们开发了一个具有药物疗效和MEP学习的连续时间动态规划(DP)模型,以帮助公司在其临床试验中制定最佳入组政策。并建立了该模型的最优性方程。通过对一家领先制药公司开发的癌症药物的临床试验,我们证明了我们的DP模型可以帮助公司有效地管理他们的试验,并获得可观的利润(每种药物高达2.7亿美元)。企业也可以在模拟中使用我们的模型来选择他们的试验设计参数(例如,中期分析的样本量)。方法:我们通过贝叶斯规则更新药物的疗效。利用分布函数的随机阶和似然比阶,证明了值函数的单调性和最优策略。结果:我们确定了药物开发项目的价值随着使用候选药物的患者平均反应的增加而增加。对于年收入较低或市场品牌较强或治疗罕见疾病的药物,我们也确定了最优入组政策是患者平均反应单调。最优入学率随着MEP方差的减小而增大。管理意义:公司可以使用价值函数的属性来为他们的药物开发项目组合选择后期临床试验。考虑到市场上其他药物的竞争,公司也可以使用我们的最优政策来指导临床试验中的患者招募。补充材料:在线附录可在https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2022.1162上获得。
{"title":"Optimal Enrollment in Late-Stage New Drug Development with Learning of Drug's Efficacy for Group-Sequential Clinical Trials","authors":"Zhili Tian, Gordon B. Hazen, Hong Li","doi":"10.1287/msom.2022.1162","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2022.1162","url":null,"abstract":"Problem definition: The cost for developing a new drug ranged from $1 billion to more than $2 billion between 2010 and 2019. In addition to high development costs, the efficacy of the candidate drug, patient enrollment, the market exclusivity period (MEP), and the planning horizon are uncertain. Moreover, slow enrollment leads to increased costs, canceled clinical trials, and lost potential revenue. Many firms, hoping to detect efficacy versus futility of the candidate drug early to save development costs, plan interim analyses of patient-response data in their clinical trials. Academic/practical relevance: The problem for optimizing patient-enrollment rates has an uncertain planning horizon. We developed a continuous-time dynamic programming (DP) model with learning of a drug’s efficacy and MEP to assist firms in developing optimal enrollment policies in their clinical trials. We also established the optimality equation for this DP model. Through a clinical trial for testing a cancer drug developed by a leading pharmaceutical firm, we demonstrate that our DP model can help firms effectively manage their trials with a sizable profit gain (as large as $270 million per drug). Firms can also use our model in simulation to select their trial design parameters (e.g., the sample sizes of interim analyses). Methodology: We update a drug’s efficacy by Bayes’ rules. Using the stochastic order and the likelihood-ratio order of distribution functions, we prove the monotonic properties of the value function and an optimal policy. Results: We established that the value of the drug-development project increases as the average response from patients using the candidate drug increases. For drugs having low annual revenue or a strong market brand or treating rare diseases, we also established that the optimal enrollment policy is monotonic in the average patient response. Moreover, the optimal enrollment rate increases as the variance of the MEP decreases. Managerial implications: Firms can use the properties of the value function to select late-stage clinical trials for their drug-development project portfolios. Firms can also use our optimal policy to guide patient recruitment in their clinical trials considering competition from other drugs in the marketplace. Supplemental Material: The online appendix is available at https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2022.1162 .","PeriodicalId":18108,"journal":{"name":"Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag.","volume":"21 1","pages":"88-107"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2022-12-05","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"81898518","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Appointment Scheduling Under a Service-Level Constraint 服务水平约束下的预约调度
Pub Date : 2022-11-28 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3548348
S. Benjaafar, David Chen, Rowan Wang, Zhenzhen Yan
Problem definition: This paper studies an appointment system where a finite number of customers are scheduled to arrive in such a way that (1) the expected waiting time of each individual customer cannot exceed a given threshold; and (2) the appointment times are set as early as possible (without breaking the waiting time constraint). Methodology/results: First, we show that, under the service-level constraint, a prospective schedule can be obtained from a sequential scheduling approach. In particular, we can schedule the appointment time of the next customer based on the scheduled appointment times of the previous customers. Then, we use a transient queueing-analysis approach and apply the theory of majorization to analytically characterize the structure of the optimal appointment schedule. We prove that, to keep the expected waiting time of each customer below a certain threshold, the minimum inter-appointment time required increases with the arrival sequence. We further identify additional properties of the optimal schedule. For example, a later arrival has a higher chance of finding an empty system and is more likely to wait less than the duration of his expected service time. We show the convergence of the service-level-constrained system to the D/M/1 queueing system as the number of arrivals approaches infinity and propose a simple, yet practical, heuristic schedule that is asymptotically optimal. We also develop algorithms that can help system managers determine the number of customers that can be scheduled in a fixed time window. We compare the service-level-constrained appointment system with other widely studied systems (including the equal-space and cost-minimization systems). We show that the service-level-constrained system leads to a lower upper bound on each customer’s waiting time; ensures a fair waiting experience among customers; and performs quite well in terms of system overtime. Finally, we investigate various extended settings of our analysis, including customer no-shows; mixed Erlang service times; multiple servers; and probability-based service-level constraints. Managerial implications: Our results provide guidelines on how to design appointment schedules with individual service-level constraints. Such a design ensures fairness and incorporates the threshold-type waiting perception of customers. It is also free from cost estimation and can be easily applied in practice. In addition, under the service-level-constrained appointment system, customers with later appointment times can have better waiting experiences, in contrast to the situation under other commonly studied systems. Funding: Z. Yan was partly supported by a Nanyang Technological University startup grant; the Ministry of Education Academic Research Fund Tier 1 [Grant RG17/21] and Tier 2 [Grant MOE2019-T2-1-045]; and Neptune Orient Lines [Fellowship Grant NOL21RP04]. Supplemental Material: The online supplement is available at https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2022.1
问题定义:本文研究了一个预约系统,其中有限数量的顾客被安排到达,并且:(1)每个顾客的期望等待时间不能超过给定的阈值;(2)尽早设置预约时间(不打破等待时间限制)。方法/结果:首先,我们证明了在服务水平约束下,可以通过顺序调度方法获得预期调度。特别是,我们可以根据前一个客户的预约时间来安排下一个客户的预约时间。然后,利用暂态排队分析方法,运用多数化理论对最优预约调度的结构进行了解析表征。我们证明,为了使每个顾客的期望等待时间低于某一阈值,所需的最小预约间隔时间随着到达顺序的增加而增加。我们进一步确定了最优调度的附加性质。例如,较晚到达的人更有可能找到空系统,并且等待的时间更有可能少于他预期的服务时间。我们展示了服务水平约束系统对D/M/1排队系统趋近于无穷时的收敛性,并提出了一个简单而实用的启发式渐近最优调度。我们还开发了算法,可以帮助系统管理人员确定在固定时间窗口内可以安排的客户数量。我们将服务水平约束的预约系统与其他广泛研究的系统(包括等空间和成本最小化系统)进行了比较。我们证明了服务水平约束的系统会导致每个顾客等待时间的下上界;确保顾客有公平的等待体验;在系统加班方面表现得很好。最后,我们调查了我们分析的各种扩展设置,包括客户缺席;混合Erlang服务时间;多个服务器;以及基于概率的服务水平约束。管理意义:我们的结果为如何设计具有个人服务水平约束的预约安排提供了指导。这样的设计既保证了公平性,又融入了顾客阈值式的等待感知。它也不需要成本估算,可以很容易地在实践中应用。此外,在服务水平约束的预约制度下,预约时间较晚的客户可以获得更好的等待体验,而不是在其他常见的研究制度下。项目资助:Yan获得了南洋理工大学创业基金的部分资助;教育部学术研究基金一级[资助RG17/21]和二级[资助MOE2019-T2-1-045];和Neptune Orient Lines [Fellowship Grant NOL21RP04]。补充材料:在线补充材料可在https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2022.1159上获得。
{"title":"Appointment Scheduling Under a Service-Level Constraint","authors":"S. Benjaafar, David Chen, Rowan Wang, Zhenzhen Yan","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3548348","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3548348","url":null,"abstract":"Problem definition: This paper studies an appointment system where a finite number of customers are scheduled to arrive in such a way that (1) the expected waiting time of each individual customer cannot exceed a given threshold; and (2) the appointment times are set as early as possible (without breaking the waiting time constraint). Methodology/results: First, we show that, under the service-level constraint, a prospective schedule can be obtained from a sequential scheduling approach. In particular, we can schedule the appointment time of the next customer based on the scheduled appointment times of the previous customers. Then, we use a transient queueing-analysis approach and apply the theory of majorization to analytically characterize the structure of the optimal appointment schedule. We prove that, to keep the expected waiting time of each customer below a certain threshold, the minimum inter-appointment time required increases with the arrival sequence. We further identify additional properties of the optimal schedule. For example, a later arrival has a higher chance of finding an empty system and is more likely to wait less than the duration of his expected service time. We show the convergence of the service-level-constrained system to the D/M/1 queueing system as the number of arrivals approaches infinity and propose a simple, yet practical, heuristic schedule that is asymptotically optimal. We also develop algorithms that can help system managers determine the number of customers that can be scheduled in a fixed time window. We compare the service-level-constrained appointment system with other widely studied systems (including the equal-space and cost-minimization systems). We show that the service-level-constrained system leads to a lower upper bound on each customer’s waiting time; ensures a fair waiting experience among customers; and performs quite well in terms of system overtime. Finally, we investigate various extended settings of our analysis, including customer no-shows; mixed Erlang service times; multiple servers; and probability-based service-level constraints. Managerial implications: Our results provide guidelines on how to design appointment schedules with individual service-level constraints. Such a design ensures fairness and incorporates the threshold-type waiting perception of customers. It is also free from cost estimation and can be easily applied in practice. In addition, under the service-level-constrained appointment system, customers with later appointment times can have better waiting experiences, in contrast to the situation under other commonly studied systems. Funding: Z. Yan was partly supported by a Nanyang Technological University startup grant; the Ministry of Education Academic Research Fund Tier 1 [Grant RG17/21] and Tier 2 [Grant MOE2019-T2-1-045]; and Neptune Orient Lines [Fellowship Grant NOL21RP04]. Supplemental Material: The online supplement is available at https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2022.1","PeriodicalId":18108,"journal":{"name":"Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag.","volume":"22 1","pages":"70-87"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2022-11-28","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"84944156","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2
Distance-Based Service Priority: An Innovative Mechanism to Increase System Throughput and Social Welfare 基于距离的服务优先:一种提高系统吞吐量和社会福利的创新机制
Pub Date : 2022-10-26 DOI: 10.1287/msom.2022.1157
Zhongbin Wang, Shiliang Cui, Lei Fang
Problem definition: The main goal of many nonprofit or nongovernmental organizations is to increase the number of customers who receive service (i.e., service coverage) and social welfare. However, the limited number of employees, volunteers, and service locations results in long service wait. In addition, getting customers living in remote areas to receive services by traveling long distances is difficult. We propose an innovative distance-based service priority policy that would reduce the service waiting time for customers who must travel farther for the service by giving them higher service priority, thereby providing them with a new incentive to seek service. Methodology/results: Using a game-theoretic queueing model, we show that the proposed policy can significantly attract more customers to a service. The increase can be up to 50% compared with the ordinary first-come-first-served service discipline. The policy can also achieve higher social welfare, however, that may come at the cost of reduced customer welfare. We therefore propose a possible remedy for a social planner to coordinate welfare under such circumstance. It ensures all stakeholders, including the service provider, customers, and society, can benefit from the policy at the same time. Finally, we compare our distance-based service priority policy with two existing strategies from the literature—namely, the price discrimination strategy and the probabilistic priority strategy. Managerial implications: Our proposed policy can play a pivotal role in a nonprofit service provider’s mission to increase service coverage and social welfare, especially when customers’ travel costs to obtain service are significant. Furthermore, our policy may create fewer implementation and fairness concerns compared with related strategies.
问题定义:许多非营利组织或非政府组织的主要目标是增加接受服务的客户数量(即服务覆盖率)和社会福利。然而,有限的员工、志愿者和服务地点导致了漫长的服务等待。此外,让生活在偏远地区的客户长途跋涉接受服务也很困难。我们提出了一种创新的基于距离的服务优先政策,通过给予客户更高的服务优先级,减少那些必须走得更远的客户的服务等待时间,从而为他们提供新的寻求服务的动力。方法/结果:利用博弈论的排队模型,我们证明了所提出的策略可以显著地吸引更多的顾客。与普通的先到先得服务相比,涨幅可达50%。该政策也可以实现更高的社会福利,然而,这可能是以降低客户福利为代价的。因此,我们提出了一种可能的补救办法,即社会计划者在这种情况下协调福利。它确保所有利益相关者,包括服务提供者、客户和社会,都能同时从政策中受益。最后,我们将基于距离的服务优先策略与文献中已有的两种策略(即价格歧视策略和概率优先策略)进行了比较。管理意义:我们提出的政策可以在非营利服务提供商的使命中发挥关键作用,以增加服务覆盖范围和社会福利,特别是当客户获得服务的旅行成本很高时。此外,与相关策略相比,我们的政策可能会产生更少的执行和公平问题。
{"title":"Distance-Based Service Priority: An Innovative Mechanism to Increase System Throughput and Social Welfare","authors":"Zhongbin Wang, Shiliang Cui, Lei Fang","doi":"10.1287/msom.2022.1157","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2022.1157","url":null,"abstract":"Problem definition: The main goal of many nonprofit or nongovernmental organizations is to increase the number of customers who receive service (i.e., service coverage) and social welfare. However, the limited number of employees, volunteers, and service locations results in long service wait. In addition, getting customers living in remote areas to receive services by traveling long distances is difficult. We propose an innovative distance-based service priority policy that would reduce the service waiting time for customers who must travel farther for the service by giving them higher service priority, thereby providing them with a new incentive to seek service. Methodology/results: Using a game-theoretic queueing model, we show that the proposed policy can significantly attract more customers to a service. The increase can be up to 50% compared with the ordinary first-come-first-served service discipline. The policy can also achieve higher social welfare, however, that may come at the cost of reduced customer welfare. We therefore propose a possible remedy for a social planner to coordinate welfare under such circumstance. It ensures all stakeholders, including the service provider, customers, and society, can benefit from the policy at the same time. Finally, we compare our distance-based service priority policy with two existing strategies from the literature—namely, the price discrimination strategy and the probabilistic priority strategy. Managerial implications: Our proposed policy can play a pivotal role in a nonprofit service provider’s mission to increase service coverage and social welfare, especially when customers’ travel costs to obtain service are significant. Furthermore, our policy may create fewer implementation and fairness concerns compared with related strategies.","PeriodicalId":18108,"journal":{"name":"Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag.","volume":"12 4 1","pages":"353-369"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2022-10-26","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"75688561","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Follow the Crowd with Uncertain Service Capacity 服务能力不确定的从众行为
Pub Date : 2022-10-22 DOI: 10.1287/msom.2022.1139
Liu Yang, Weixin Shang, Liming Liu
Problem definition: Customer joining behavior is of major concern for service systems where the service capacity is uncertain. Academic/practical relevance: It remains unclear whether customer inference of uncertain service capacity can lead to follow the crowd (FTC) behavior. Management can release capacity information, but how it affects system performance needs to be understood. Methodology: We use a single-server queue to analyze the joining behavior of customers who infer the actual service capacity based on the queue length upon arrival. We also characterize the impact of capacity information disclosure both analytically and numerically. Results: We find that when other customers’ tendency to join the service increases, a tagged customer can make more accurate inferences of service capacity based on queue length. This inference effect arises together with the congestion effect and can lead to FTC when it outweighs the latter. When multiple equilibria exist, we characterize the conditions under which the inference effect is significant at the aggregate customer level so that the joining equilibrium with a larger joining threshold is Pareto-optimal. Managerial implications: Management needs to be careful in setting the information disclosure policy, as the key problem parameters may affect its impact on system throughput and social welfare in opposite directions.
问题定义:在服务能力不确定的服务系统中,客户加入行为是主要关注的问题。学术/实践相关性:顾客对不确定服务能力的推断是否会导致随大流(FTC)行为尚不清楚。管理层可以发布容量信息,但需要了解它如何影响系统性能。方法:我们使用单服务器队列来分析客户的加入行为,客户根据到达时的队列长度来推断实际服务容量。我们还分析和数值表征了容量信息披露的影响。结果:我们发现当其他顾客加入服务的倾向增加时,被标记的顾客可以更准确地推断出基于队列长度的服务容量。这种推理效应与拥塞效应一起产生,当它超过后者时,可能导致FTC。当存在多个均衡时,我们刻画了在总客户层面上推理效果显著的条件,使得具有较大的联接阈值的联接均衡是帕累托最优的。管理启示:管理层在制定信息披露政策时需要谨慎,因为关键问题参数可能会对系统吞吐量和社会福利产生相反的影响。
{"title":"Follow the Crowd with Uncertain Service Capacity","authors":"Liu Yang, Weixin Shang, Liming Liu","doi":"10.1287/msom.2022.1139","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2022.1139","url":null,"abstract":"Problem definition: Customer joining behavior is of major concern for service systems where the service capacity is uncertain. Academic/practical relevance: It remains unclear whether customer inference of uncertain service capacity can lead to follow the crowd (FTC) behavior. Management can release capacity information, but how it affects system performance needs to be understood. Methodology: We use a single-server queue to analyze the joining behavior of customers who infer the actual service capacity based on the queue length upon arrival. We also characterize the impact of capacity information disclosure both analytically and numerically. Results: We find that when other customers’ tendency to join the service increases, a tagged customer can make more accurate inferences of service capacity based on queue length. This inference effect arises together with the congestion effect and can lead to FTC when it outweighs the latter. When multiple equilibria exist, we characterize the conditions under which the inference effect is significant at the aggregate customer level so that the joining equilibrium with a larger joining threshold is Pareto-optimal. Managerial implications: Management needs to be careful in setting the information disclosure policy, as the key problem parameters may affect its impact on system throughput and social welfare in opposite directions.","PeriodicalId":18108,"journal":{"name":"Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag.","volume":"42 1","pages":"341-352"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2022-10-22","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"86925449","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Beating the Algorithm: Consumer Manipulation, Personalized Pricing, and Big Data Management 击败算法:消费者操纵、个性化定价和大数据管理
Pub Date : 2022-10-18 DOI: 10.1287/msom.2022.1153
Xi Li, Krista J. Li
Problem definition: Firms heavily invest in big data technologies to collect consumer data and infer consumer preferences for price discrimination. However, consumers can use technological devices to manipulate their data and fool firms to obtain better deals. We examine how a firm invests in collecting consumer data and makes pricing decisions and whether it should disclose its scope of data collection to consumers who can manipulate their data. Methodology/results: We develop a game-theoretic model to consider a market in which a firm caters to consumers with heterogeneous preferences for a product. The firm collects consumer data to identify their types and issue an individualized price, whereas consumers can incur a cost to manipulate data and mimic the other type. We find that when the firm does not disclose its scope of data collection to consumers, it collects more consumer data. When the firm discloses its scope of data collection, it reduces data collection even when collecting more data is costless. The optimal scope of data collection increases when it is more costly for consumers to manipulate data but decreases when consumer demand becomes more heterogeneous. Moreover, a lower cost for consumers to manipulate data can be detrimental to both the firm and consumers. Lastly, disclosure of data collection scope increases firm profit, consumer surplus, and social welfare. Managerial implications: Our findings suggest that a firm should adjust its scope of data collection and prices based on whether the firm discloses the data collection scope, consumers’ manipulation cost, and demand heterogeneity. Public policies should require firms to disclose their data collection scope to increase consumer surplus and social welfare. Even without such a mandatory disclosure policy, firms should voluntarily disclose their data collection scope to increase profit. Moreover, public educational programs that train consumers to manipulate their data or raise their awareness of manipulation tools can ultimately hurt consumers and firms.
问题定义:企业大量投资于大数据技术,以收集消费者数据并推断消费者对价格歧视的偏好。然而,消费者可以使用技术设备来操纵他们的数据并欺骗公司以获得更好的交易。我们研究了一家公司如何投资于收集消费者数据并做出定价决策,以及它是否应该向可以操纵其数据的消费者披露其数据收集范围。方法/结果:我们开发了一个博弈论模型来考虑一个市场,在这个市场中,一个公司迎合了对产品有异质偏好的消费者。该公司收集消费者数据以确定其类型并发布个性化价格,而消费者可能会产生操纵数据并模仿其他类型的成本。我们发现,当公司不向消费者披露其数据收集范围时,它收集了更多的消费者数据。当公司披露其数据收集范围时,即使收集更多的数据是没有成本的,它也会减少数据收集。当消费者操作数据的成本更高时,数据收集的最佳范围就会增加,但当消费者需求变得更加异构时,数据收集的最佳范围就会减少。此外,消费者操纵数据的成本降低可能对公司和消费者都不利。最后,数据收集范围的披露增加了企业利润、消费者剩余和社会福利。管理启示:我们的研究结果表明,企业应该根据是否披露数据收集范围、消费者操纵成本和需求异质性来调整其数据收集范围和价格。公共政策应要求企业公开其数据收集范围,以增加消费者剩余和社会福利。即使没有这样的强制性披露政策,企业也应该自愿披露其数据收集范围,以增加利润。此外,培训消费者操纵他们的数据或提高他们对操纵工具的认识的公共教育项目最终会伤害消费者和公司。
{"title":"Beating the Algorithm: Consumer Manipulation, Personalized Pricing, and Big Data Management","authors":"Xi Li, Krista J. Li","doi":"10.1287/msom.2022.1153","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2022.1153","url":null,"abstract":"Problem definition: Firms heavily invest in big data technologies to collect consumer data and infer consumer preferences for price discrimination. However, consumers can use technological devices to manipulate their data and fool firms to obtain better deals. We examine how a firm invests in collecting consumer data and makes pricing decisions and whether it should disclose its scope of data collection to consumers who can manipulate their data. Methodology/results: We develop a game-theoretic model to consider a market in which a firm caters to consumers with heterogeneous preferences for a product. The firm collects consumer data to identify their types and issue an individualized price, whereas consumers can incur a cost to manipulate data and mimic the other type. We find that when the firm does not disclose its scope of data collection to consumers, it collects more consumer data. When the firm discloses its scope of data collection, it reduces data collection even when collecting more data is costless. The optimal scope of data collection increases when it is more costly for consumers to manipulate data but decreases when consumer demand becomes more heterogeneous. Moreover, a lower cost for consumers to manipulate data can be detrimental to both the firm and consumers. Lastly, disclosure of data collection scope increases firm profit, consumer surplus, and social welfare. Managerial implications: Our findings suggest that a firm should adjust its scope of data collection and prices based on whether the firm discloses the data collection scope, consumers’ manipulation cost, and demand heterogeneity. Public policies should require firms to disclose their data collection scope to increase consumer surplus and social welfare. Even without such a mandatory disclosure policy, firms should voluntarily disclose their data collection scope to increase profit. Moreover, public educational programs that train consumers to manipulate their data or raise their awareness of manipulation tools can ultimately hurt consumers and firms.","PeriodicalId":18108,"journal":{"name":"Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag.","volume":"90 1","pages":"36-49"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2022-10-18","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"80401963","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 6
Sequential Innovation in Mobile App Development 移动应用开发中的连续创新
Pub Date : 2022-10-13 DOI: 10.1287/msom.2022.1154
Nilam Kaushik, Bilal Gokpinar
Problem definition: In today’s highly dynamic and competitive app markets, a significant portion of development takes place after the initial product launch via the addition of new features and the enhancement of existing products. In managing the sequential innovation process in mobile app development, two key operational questions arise. (i) What features and attributes should be added to existing products in successive versions? (ii) How should these features and attributes be implemented for greater market success? We investigate the implications of three different types of mobile app development activities on market performance. Academic/practical relevance: Our study contributes to the operations management literature by providing an empirically based understanding of sequential innovation and its market performance implications in mobile app development, an important industry in terms of size, scope and potential. Methodology: Using a novel data set of mobile apps in the Productivity category, we leverage text-mining and information retrieval techniques to study the rich information in the release notes of apps. We then characterize product development activities at each version release and link these activities with app performance in a dynamic estimation model. We also incorporate an instrumental variables analysis to substantiate our findings. Results: We find that greater update dissimilarity (i.e., dissimilarity of the features and attributes of a new update from those of previous updates) is associated with higher performance, especially in mature apps. We also find that the greater the product update market orientation (i.e., the greater the similarity of the focal firm’s new features and attributes with respect to the recent additions of its competitors), the higher is the market performance. This finding suggests that the market rewards those developers who have a responsive policy to their competitors’ product innovation efforts. Our results also suggest that a rapid introduction of updates dampens the potential market benefits that the mobile app developers might gain from market orientation. We find no evidence of a beneficial effect of product update scope (i.e., incorporating features and attributes from other product subcategories) on market performance. Managerial implications: Our study offers managerial insights into mobile app development by exploring the sequential innovation characteristics that are associated with greater market success in pursuing and implementing new features and attributes.
问题定义:在当今高度动态和竞争激烈的应用市场中,很大一部分开发工作发生在最初的产品发布之后,即通过添加新功能和增强现有产品。在管理移动应用开发的连续创新过程中,出现了两个关键的操作问题。(i)在后续版本中,现有产品应增加哪些特性和属性?(ii)为了在市场上取得更大的成功,应该如何实施这些特征和属性?我们调查了三种不同类型的移动应用程序开发活动对市场表现的影响。学术/实践相关性:我们的研究通过提供基于经验的顺序创新及其在移动应用程序开发中的市场表现影响的理解,为运营管理文献做出了贡献,移动应用程序开发在规模、范围和潜力方面都是一个重要的行业。方法:使用生产力类别中的移动应用程序的新数据集,我们利用文本挖掘和信息检索技术来研究应用程序发布说明中的丰富信息。然后,我们在每个版本发布中描述产品开发活动,并将这些活动与动态评估模型中的应用程序性能联系起来。我们还纳入了工具变量分析来证实我们的发现。结果:我们发现更大的更新差异(即新更新与以前更新的功能和属性的差异)与更高的性能相关,特别是在成熟的应用程序中。我们还发现,产品更新的市场导向越大(即焦点企业的新特征和属性相对于其竞争对手最近增加的特征和属性的相似性越大),市场绩效就越高。这一发现表明,市场会奖励那些对竞争对手的产品创新努力做出反应的开发者。我们的研究结果还表明,快速推出更新会抑制手机应用开发者从市场导向中获得的潜在市场收益。我们没有发现任何证据表明产品更新范围(即整合其他产品子类别的功能和属性)对市场表现有有益影响。管理启示:我们的研究通过探索与追求和实施新功能和属性的更大市场成功相关的连续创新特征,为移动应用开发提供了管理见解。
{"title":"Sequential Innovation in Mobile App Development","authors":"Nilam Kaushik, Bilal Gokpinar","doi":"10.1287/msom.2022.1154","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2022.1154","url":null,"abstract":"Problem definition: In today’s highly dynamic and competitive app markets, a significant portion of development takes place after the initial product launch via the addition of new features and the enhancement of existing products. In managing the sequential innovation process in mobile app development, two key operational questions arise. (i) What features and attributes should be added to existing products in successive versions? (ii) How should these features and attributes be implemented for greater market success? We investigate the implications of three different types of mobile app development activities on market performance. Academic/practical relevance: Our study contributes to the operations management literature by providing an empirically based understanding of sequential innovation and its market performance implications in mobile app development, an important industry in terms of size, scope and potential. Methodology: Using a novel data set of mobile apps in the Productivity category, we leverage text-mining and information retrieval techniques to study the rich information in the release notes of apps. We then characterize product development activities at each version release and link these activities with app performance in a dynamic estimation model. We also incorporate an instrumental variables analysis to substantiate our findings. Results: We find that greater update dissimilarity (i.e., dissimilarity of the features and attributes of a new update from those of previous updates) is associated with higher performance, especially in mature apps. We also find that the greater the product update market orientation (i.e., the greater the similarity of the focal firm’s new features and attributes with respect to the recent additions of its competitors), the higher is the market performance. This finding suggests that the market rewards those developers who have a responsive policy to their competitors’ product innovation efforts. Our results also suggest that a rapid introduction of updates dampens the potential market benefits that the mobile app developers might gain from market orientation. We find no evidence of a beneficial effect of product update scope (i.e., incorporating features and attributes from other product subcategories) on market performance. Managerial implications: Our study offers managerial insights into mobile app development by exploring the sequential innovation characteristics that are associated with greater market success in pursuing and implementing new features and attributes.","PeriodicalId":18108,"journal":{"name":"Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag.","volume":"22 1","pages":"182-199"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2022-10-13","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"82631757","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
期刊
Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag.
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1