首页 > 最新文献

ERN: National最新文献

英文 中文
Tax Competition with Mobile Labor, Residents, and Capital 与流动劳动力、居民和资本的税收竞争
Pub Date : 2019-05-27 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3394617
David R. Agrawal, W. Hoyt, John D. Wilson
We construct a unifying model of tax competition that includes mobile workers, mobile residents, and mobile capital – and is therefore appropriate for the study of local government policy. Local governments are atomistic with respect to the world capital market, but are linked by commuting patterns, the cost of which is endogenously determined by congestion. Capital taxation creates fiscal externalities, which then alter decisions both about where to live and work. These fiscal externalities result from changing commuting patterns: when a jurisdiction increases its industrial capital tax rate, some workers change their work location to another jurisdiction, raising public good provision there. In this way, competition for workers affects competition for households. Commuting gives rise to “tax exporting,” with a higher capital tax in the (central) city partially borne by non-resident commuters from the suburbs, allowing the capital tax to remain optimal even when head taxes are available. We also consider taxes on labor, residents and property. Against, this backdrop, we show, consistent with the empirical literature, that even though jurisdictions are price-takers in the world capital market, they strategically react to the policies of other jurisdictions due to commuting linkages. This resolves an important inconsistency between the theoretical and empirical literature by making theoretical models of atomistic jurisdictions that are appropriate for local policy choice consistent with the empirical evidence that localities strategically interact in capital taxes.
我们构建了一个统一的税收竞争模型,其中包括流动工人、流动居民和流动资本,因此适用于地方政府政策的研究。地方政府相对于世界资本市场而言是原子式的,但它们与通勤模式联系在一起,而通勤模式的成本是由交通拥堵内生地决定的。资本税会产生财政外部性,进而改变人们在哪里生活和工作的决定。这些财政外部性源于通勤模式的改变:当一个司法管辖区提高其工业资本税率时,一些工人将他们的工作地点转移到另一个司法管辖区,从而增加了那里的公共产品供应。这样,对工人的竞争影响了对家庭的竞争。通勤导致了“税收输出”,(中心)城市较高的资本税部分由来自郊区的非居民通勤者承担,这使得资本税即使在人头税可用的情况下也能保持最佳水平。我们还考虑了劳工税、居民税和财产税。在此背景下,我们与实证文献一致表明,尽管司法管辖区是世界资本市场的价格接受者,但由于通勤联系,它们在战略上对其他司法管辖区的政策做出反应。这解决了理论和实证文献之间的重要不一致,使适合地方政策选择的原子管辖的理论模型与地方在资本税方面的战略互动的经验证据相一致。
{"title":"Tax Competition with Mobile Labor, Residents, and Capital","authors":"David R. Agrawal, W. Hoyt, John D. Wilson","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3394617","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3394617","url":null,"abstract":"We construct a unifying model of tax competition that includes mobile workers, mobile residents, and mobile capital – and is therefore appropriate for the study of local government policy. Local governments are atomistic with respect to the world capital market, but are linked by commuting patterns, the cost of which is endogenously determined by congestion. Capital taxation creates fiscal externalities, which then alter decisions both about where to live and work. These fiscal externalities result from changing commuting patterns: when a jurisdiction increases its industrial capital tax rate, some workers change their work location to another jurisdiction, raising public good provision there. In this way, competition for workers affects competition for households. Commuting gives rise to “tax exporting,” with a higher capital tax in the (central) city partially borne by non-resident commuters from the suburbs, allowing the capital tax to remain optimal even when head taxes are available. We also consider taxes on labor, residents and property. Against, this backdrop, we show, consistent with the empirical literature, that even though jurisdictions are price-takers in the world capital market, they strategically react to the policies of other jurisdictions due to commuting linkages. This resolves an important inconsistency between the theoretical and empirical literature by making theoretical models of atomistic jurisdictions that are appropriate for local policy choice consistent with the empirical evidence that localities strategically interact in capital taxes.","PeriodicalId":221919,"journal":{"name":"ERN: National","volume":"35 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2019-05-27","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"115273045","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 5
New Cooperative Medical Scheme and Medical Expenditure in Rural China 新型合作医疗与农村医疗支出
Pub Date : 2019-02-01 DOI: 10.1111/1468-0106.12228
Li Li
The New Cooperative Medical Scheme (NCMS) was launched in rural China in 2003, aiming to safeguard rural households against catastrophic medical expenditure. The implementation of the programme has been surrounded by the concern for the potential uncontrollable growth in medical expenditure due to moral hazard. Direct evidence on the relationship between the NCMS and total medical expenditure is still scant. Using a panel data set, the Rural Fixed-point Survey (RFPS) 2003–2006 and a supplementary NCMS survey conducted in 2007, we find that joining the NCMS does not affect household medical expenditure.
新合作医疗制度于2003年在中国农村启动,旨在保障农村家庭免受灾难性医疗支出的影响。在实施该方案的过程中,人们一直担心,由于道德风险,医疗支出可能出现无法控制的增长。关于新农合与医疗总支出之间关系的直接证据仍然很少。利用2003-2006年农村定点调查(RFPS)和2007年全国新农合补充调查的面板数据集,我们发现加入新农合对家庭医疗支出没有影响。
{"title":"New Cooperative Medical Scheme and Medical Expenditure in Rural China","authors":"Li Li","doi":"10.1111/1468-0106.12228","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1111/1468-0106.12228","url":null,"abstract":"The New Cooperative Medical Scheme (NCMS) was launched in rural China in 2003, aiming to safeguard rural households against catastrophic medical expenditure. The implementation of the programme has been surrounded by the concern for the potential uncontrollable growth in medical expenditure due to moral hazard. Direct evidence on the relationship between the NCMS and total medical expenditure is still scant. Using a panel data set, the Rural Fixed-point Survey (RFPS) 2003–2006 and a supplementary NCMS survey conducted in 2007, we find that joining the NCMS does not affect household medical expenditure.","PeriodicalId":221919,"journal":{"name":"ERN: National","volume":"26 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2019-02-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"125887752","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 3
Aging and Public Financing Costs: Evidence from U.S. Municipal Bond Markets 老龄化与公共融资成本:来自美国市政债券市场的证据
Pub Date : 2019-01-13 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3301648
Alexander W. Butler, Hanyi Yi
We examine the impact of population aging on municipal access to credit. A one standard deviation increase in a state’s population age leads to a 23 basis point increase in municipal bond issue spread. Three mechanisms drive this effect: income tax revenue, healthcare liabilities, and pension underfunding. Constitutional pension protections and securities with lower credit quality or longer maturity exacerbate the effect. To control for endogenous migration and mortality patterns, we exploit variation from historical state fertility trends. Our findings highlight the challenges municipalities face to cope with systemic demographic transition.
我们研究了人口老龄化对市政信贷获取的影响。一个州的人口年龄每增加一个标准差,市政债券发行利差就会增加23个基点。推动这种效应的机制有三种:所得税收入、医疗负债和养老金资金不足。宪法养老金保护和信用质量较低或期限较长的证券加剧了这种影响。为了控制内生迁移和死亡模式,我们利用了历史上各州生育趋势的变化。我们的研究结果突出了市政当局在应对系统性人口转型方面面临的挑战。
{"title":"Aging and Public Financing Costs: Evidence from U.S. Municipal Bond Markets","authors":"Alexander W. Butler, Hanyi Yi","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3301648","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3301648","url":null,"abstract":"We examine the impact of population aging on municipal access to credit. A one standard deviation increase in a state’s population age leads to a 23 basis point increase in municipal bond issue spread. Three mechanisms drive this effect: income tax revenue, healthcare liabilities, and pension underfunding. Constitutional pension protections and securities with lower credit quality or longer maturity exacerbate the effect. To control for endogenous migration and mortality patterns, we exploit variation from historical state fertility trends. Our findings highlight the challenges municipalities face to cope with systemic demographic transition.","PeriodicalId":221919,"journal":{"name":"ERN: National","volume":"36 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2019-01-13","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"126008883","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 15
Linking Social and Emotional Learning Standards to the Social Emotional Competency Assessment (SECA) 社会与情绪学习标准与社会情绪能力评估(SECA)的关联
Pub Date : 2019-01-09 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3890967
R. Gordon, Marisa K Crowder, Laura Davidson, C. Domitrovich
School districts across the United States are developing systemic, district-wide approaches to support students’ social and emotional learning (SEL), due to the increasingly recognized role that students’ social-emotional competencies (SECs) play in their academic success (Domitrovich et al., 2017; Kendziora & Osher, 2016; Mahoney et al., 2017). Such initiatives have increased the need for cost-effective measures of students’ SECs that are feasible for large-scale use, embedded in scholarly literature, and aligned to local needs (Stecher & Hamilton, 2014). This brief describes evidence for one such measure, the Social-Emotional Competency Assessment (SECA), which is a self-report assessment of students’ SECs that can be used from late elementary to high school (Crowder et al., 2018; Davidson et al., 2018; Schamberg et al., 2017). The measure was developed in the context of a researcher-practitioner partnership that provided the opportunity to align the measure not only with theory and literature about core SECs – and the widely-used Collaborative for Academic Social and Emotional Learning five broad domains (CASEL 5; Weissberg et al., 2015) – but also the school district’s SEL standards. This brief shows how such alignment informs us about how well the measure operates and also offers insights into the standards and underlying theory and practice (see Crowder et al., 2018 for the full paper on which this brief is based).
由于越来越多的人认识到学生的社会情感能力(SECs)在学业成功中的作用,美国各地的学区正在开发系统的、全区的方法来支持学生的社会和情感学习(SEL) (Domitrovich et al., 2017;Kendziora & Osher, 2016;Mahoney et al., 2017)。这些举措增加了对具有成本效益的学生安全措施的需求,这些措施可以大规模使用,嵌入学术文献,并与当地需求保持一致(Stecher & Hamilton, 2014)。本文简要描述了一种这样的测量方法的证据,即社会情感能力评估(SECA),这是一种对学生的社会情感能力的自我报告评估,可以从小学后期到高中使用(Crowder等人,2018;Davidson等人,2018;Schamberg et al., 2017)。该措施是在研究人员与从业人员合作的背景下开发的,该伙伴关系不仅提供了将该措施与核心sec的理论和文献以及广泛使用的学术社会和情感学习协作五大领域(CASEL 5;Weissberg et al., 2015),以及学区的SEL标准。本摘要展示了这种一致性如何告诉我们测量的运行情况,并提供了对标准和潜在理论和实践的见解(参见Crowder等人,2018年的本摘要所基于的完整论文)。
{"title":"Linking Social and Emotional Learning Standards to the Social Emotional Competency Assessment (SECA)","authors":"R. Gordon, Marisa K Crowder, Laura Davidson, C. Domitrovich","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3890967","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3890967","url":null,"abstract":"School districts across the United States are developing systemic, district-wide approaches to support students’ social and emotional learning (SEL), due to the increasingly recognized role that students’ social-emotional competencies (SECs) play in their academic success (Domitrovich et al., 2017; Kendziora & Osher, 2016; Mahoney et al., 2017). Such initiatives have increased the need for cost-effective measures of students’ SECs that are feasible for large-scale use, embedded in scholarly literature, and aligned to local needs (Stecher & Hamilton, 2014). This brief describes evidence for one such measure, the Social-Emotional Competency Assessment (SECA), which is a self-report assessment of students’ SECs that can be used from late elementary to high school (Crowder et al., 2018; Davidson et al., 2018; Schamberg et al., 2017). The measure was developed in the context of a researcher-practitioner partnership that provided the opportunity to align the measure not only with theory and literature about core SECs – and the widely-used Collaborative for Academic Social and Emotional Learning five broad domains (CASEL 5; Weissberg et al., 2015) – but also the school district’s SEL standards. This brief shows how such alignment informs us about how well the measure operates and also offers insights into the standards and underlying theory and practice (see Crowder et al., 2018 for the full paper on which this brief is based).","PeriodicalId":221919,"journal":{"name":"ERN: National","volume":"22 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2019-01-09","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"116947549","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Earmarked and Block Grants in Macedonia: Options for Reform 马其顿的专项拨款和整体拨款:改革的选择
Pub Date : 2019-01-01 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3403667
J. Herczyński
In the present report, after reviewing the allocation formulas of earmarked and block grants for decentralized institutions, five major problems of the system are identified:
• Underfunding of local governments in Macedonia (subsection 3.1). Shares of local revenues in terms of GDP are low compared to other Europeans countries, even those who like Slovenia did not entrust to municipalities the responsibility for paying teacher salaries.
• Decentralization is institutional, not functional (subsection 3.2). Back in 2005, Macedonia transferred to municipalities a large selection of public institutions, but the laws, and the financing instruments, indicate that the functions were not in fact transferred.
• Ineffective central control over employment levels (subsection 3.3). Macedonia maintains a strict and costly system of control over local employment, even in cases when an existing employee retires. The system hampers proper functioning of some of the decentralized institutions but allows employment expansion in other sectors.
• Very low local financial involvement in the financing of decentralized sectors (subsection 3.4). Most decentralized institutions, even preschools, are financed almost exclusively from grants from the national budget, with very little local contribution from own revenues. They are not seen as own institutions by most municipalities.
• Debts related to obligatory transport of students of secondary schools (subsection 3.5). For too long has Macedonia accepted without any intervention growing problem of blocked accounts of many secondary schools.
Three general scenarios, described in section 4, are proposed to address the identified problems and to reform the system of earmarked and block grants in Republic of Macedonia:
1. Continuation of institutional decentralization.
2. Introduction of sectoral decentralization.
3. Granting municipalities financial autonomy.
Nine specific recommendations are proposed (section 4) to implement these three scenarios:

1. VAT grant
Macedonian municipalities are relatively underfinanced in comparison to local governments in EU and in the Balkan region. For this reason, Macedonia needs a stronger equalization system. It is recommended (as part of the first scenario) that VAT grant is increased substantially, and that the increase be allocated as an equalization grant. A formula for this new equalization part of VAT grant is proposed in subsection 4.1.
2. Earmarked grant in primary education
Since 2012, only one municipality remains in the first phase of decentralization and receives earmarked grant for primary education (Plasnica). This is a clear anomaly, because it is the only instance of a Macedonian municipality still functioning within phase I of decentralization, 13 years after the start of the process. It is recommended (as part of the second scenario) that this anomaly be corrected, and that the earmarked grant should be discontinued from Janua
幼儿园整体补助金幼儿园整体补助金的分配基于一个公式,该公式除了每个学生的数量和入学儿童的数量外,还使用了一个城市系数,每个城市都单独使用。建议为学前教育整体补助金引入真实的每名学生分配公式,消除对工作人员人数的任何依赖。在第4.2节中提出了一个简单的公式草案,并附有模拟。老年人住房的整体补助金与文化的整体补助金类似,实际上是用于具体活动的专项补助金,因为它在全国范围内仅资助三家机构。这些房屋的集水区(服务区)远远超出了其所在的城市。所涉及的资金非常少,分配公式实际上是根据机构的实际成本,市政府在管理养老院方面的作用无助于根据国家需要有效地管理养老院。建议将三所养老院重新集中,并停止对它们的整体补助金。8.不过,随后可根据具体情况将其授权给个别市。消防专项拨款消防专项拨款用于资助消防单位,并于2005年移交给各市。建议将消防系统集中起来,并由一个中央机构直接提供资金。这将确保共同的技术、培训和纪律标准,并避免目前的争议。这项建议假定将停止为消防提供指定用途的赠款。9.然而,市政当局应该对位于其领土内的州消防队的管理保留一定程度的影响力。建议将所有以专项和整体赠款形式从国家预算转移到地方预算的资金集中起来,形成一个统一的转移(作为第三种方案的一部分)。第4.3款包括为统一拨款提出的分配公式,并模拟该公式将如何影响马其顿各市。
{"title":"Earmarked and Block Grants in Macedonia: Options for Reform","authors":"J. Herczyński","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3403667","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3403667","url":null,"abstract":"In the present report, after reviewing the allocation formulas of earmarked and block grants for decentralized institutions, five major problems of the system are identified:<br>• Underfunding of local governments in Macedonia (subsection 3.1). Shares of local revenues in terms of GDP are low compared to other Europeans countries, even those who like Slovenia did not entrust to municipalities the responsibility for paying teacher salaries.<br>• Decentralization is institutional, not functional (subsection 3.2). Back in 2005, Macedonia transferred to municipalities a large selection of public institutions, but the laws, and the financing instruments, indicate that the functions were not in fact transferred.<br>• Ineffective central control over employment levels (subsection 3.3). Macedonia maintains a strict and costly system of control over local employment, even in cases when an existing employee retires. The system hampers proper functioning of some of the decentralized institutions but allows employment expansion in other sectors.<br>• Very low local financial involvement in the financing of decentralized sectors (subsection 3.4). Most decentralized institutions, even preschools, are financed almost exclusively from grants from the national budget, with very little local contribution from own revenues. They are not seen as own institutions by most municipalities.<br>• Debts related to obligatory transport of students of secondary schools (subsection 3.5). For too long has Macedonia accepted without any intervention growing problem of blocked accounts of many secondary schools.<br>Three general scenarios, described in section 4, are proposed to address the identified problems and to reform the system of earmarked and block grants in Republic of Macedonia:<br>1. Continuation of institutional decentralization.<br>2. Introduction of sectoral decentralization.<br>3. Granting municipalities financial autonomy.<br>Nine specific recommendations are proposed (section 4) to implement these three scenarios:<br><br>1. VAT grant<br>Macedonian municipalities are relatively underfinanced in comparison to local governments in EU and in the Balkan region. For this reason, Macedonia needs a stronger equalization system. It is recommended (as part of the first scenario) that VAT grant is increased substantially, and that the increase be allocated as an equalization grant. A formula for this new equalization part of VAT grant is proposed in subsection 4.1.<br>2. Earmarked grant in primary education<br>Since 2012, only one municipality remains in the first phase of decentralization and receives earmarked grant for primary education (Plasnica). This is a clear anomaly, because it is the only instance of a Macedonian municipality still functioning within phase I of decentralization, 13 years after the start of the process. It is recommended (as part of the second scenario) that this anomaly be corrected, and that the earmarked grant should be discontinued from Janua","PeriodicalId":221919,"journal":{"name":"ERN: National","volume":"262 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2019-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"121896976","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Five European Systems of Local Government Finance 五种欧洲地方政府财政制度
Pub Date : 2018-12-17 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3382179
J. Herczyński
Local government finance, especially the systems of grants from the national to local budgets, and other revenues streams of municipalities, counties, and regions, are highly specific for each country, as they depend crucially on legislation in force, on recent history, on the political process that takes place between different levels of governance. The five case studies presented in the report identify some of these country-specific characteristics of financing of local governments, tailored to the different needs and serving different allocation of managerial and expenditure responsibilities. None of the reviewed systems can be transposed, in toto or in part, to Republic of Macedonia without a thorough review of required adaptations. At the same time, however, they provide some lessons which may be usefully considered by Macedonian reformers.

• The functioning of most European systems of local government finance is based on high degree of trust in local governments and in other users of public money. This trust, however, does not stop them from using are strict mechanisms of monitoring and control of local public finances. Any reforms considered for Macedonia should always include monitoring mechanisms, as well as procedures to intervene if lower levels of government do not follow prescribed rules.

• Some successful European countries have maintained, similarly to Macedonia, high dependence of municipalities on grants received from the national budget, with relatively reduced revenue from taxes and other sources. This indicates that efficiency of local provision of services is related not only to autonomy in generating local revenues, but also to allocation mechanisms and to effective monitoring. The efficiency and transparency of the Macedonian system may be improved even if grants remain the main revenue of municipalities.

• Every European system of local government finance uses a robust, formula-driven equalization mechanism. These systems attempt to ensure that citizens living in all municipalities may have access to services of the same high quality. In Macedonian conditions the need for strong equalization system is even more apparent than in wealthy countries of the European Union, due to large differences between municipalities. Prior to any reforms of the Macedonian equalization system, reformers should undertake an in-depth review of its strengths and weaknesses. Experience of Sweden suggests that it is better to begin with relatively simple equalization system, so that its formulas and its effects on municipalities are easy to understand and analyze.

• Taxes are an important source of revenues of European municipalities. Specific tax regime is decided differently in every country, it may include taxes on property or income. In every case, however, citizens of municipalities know that their taxes contribute to the operations of their local government, and demand accountability. This link becomes even st
•在一些国家,地方税由国家当局征收,然后根据纳税人的地理位置(个人和商业)分配给地方政府。这种方法可能会很好地发挥作用,而不管这些税的税率或保留在地方一级的份额是由地方还是全国设定的。在马其顿,征税对市政市长来说是一个严峻的挑战,他们经常发现自己在试图向邻居征税时处于不舒服的境地。在这种情况下,这一职能的全部或部分集中可能是解决低税收遵从问题的一部分。•许多欧洲国家在教育和卫生等重要社会领域赋予地方政府很大的自主权,允许市和县决定如何最好地组织和资助教育和卫生服务。然而,这些领域通过不同的规范和程序得到了很好的规范,并形成了对地方政府财政的监督体系。如果马其顿计划加强马其顿地方政府的自治权,就应该为每个部门提出类似的质量标准和监测规范,与利益相关者讨论并采用。•随着欧洲国家的权力下放,他们总是需要收集越来越多的关于地方政府的数据,关于他们提供的服务,关于公共部门不同领域的运作。随着时间的推移,开发了几个相互关联的数据库。马其顿得到的教训是,在地方行动者增加自治的同时,应在中央一级增加对该系统如何运作的认识和理解。
{"title":"Five European Systems of Local Government Finance","authors":"J. Herczyński","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3382179","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3382179","url":null,"abstract":"Local government finance, especially the systems of grants from the national to local budgets, and other revenues streams of municipalities, counties, and regions, are highly specific for each country, as they depend crucially on legislation in force, on recent history, on the political process that takes place between different levels of governance. The five case studies presented in the report identify some of these country-specific characteristics of financing of local governments, tailored to the different needs and serving different allocation of managerial and expenditure responsibilities. None of the reviewed systems can be transposed, in toto or in part, to Republic of Macedonia without a thorough review of required adaptations. At the same time, however, they provide some lessons which may be usefully considered by Macedonian reformers.<br><br>• The functioning of most European systems of local government finance is based on high degree of trust in local governments and in other users of public money. This trust, however, does not stop them from using are strict mechanisms of monitoring and control of local public finances. Any reforms considered for Macedonia should always include monitoring mechanisms, as well as procedures to intervene if lower levels of government do not follow prescribed rules.<br> <br>• Some successful European countries have maintained, similarly to Macedonia, high dependence of municipalities on grants received from the national budget, with relatively reduced revenue from taxes and other sources. This indicates that efficiency of local provision of services is related not only to autonomy in generating local revenues, but also to allocation mechanisms and to effective monitoring. The efficiency and transparency of the Macedonian system may be improved even if grants remain the main revenue of municipalities. <br><br>• Every European system of local government finance uses a robust, formula-driven equalization mechanism. These systems attempt to ensure that citizens living in all municipalities may have access to services of the same high quality. In Macedonian conditions the need for strong equalization system is even more apparent than in wealthy countries of the European Union, due to large differences between municipalities. Prior to any reforms of the Macedonian equalization system, reformers should undertake an in-depth review of its strengths and weaknesses. Experience of Sweden suggests that it is better to begin with relatively simple equalization system, so that its formulas and its effects on municipalities are easy to understand and analyze. <br><br>• Taxes are an important source of revenues of European municipalities. Specific tax regime is decided differently in every country, it may include taxes on property or income. In every case, however, citizens of municipalities know that their taxes contribute to the operations of their local government, and demand accountability. This link becomes even st","PeriodicalId":221919,"journal":{"name":"ERN: National","volume":"34 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2018-12-17","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"128727953","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2
Alberta's Long-Term Fiscal Future 艾伯塔省的长期财政前景
Pub Date : 2018-11-20 DOI: 10.11575/SPPP.V11I0.52965
Trevor Tombe
Alberta’s short-term fiscal challenges are well known, but its long-term ones are more significant. An aging population, a high reliance on non-renewable resource revenue, and rising debt levels will increasingly widen the current gap between spending and revenue. This paper estimates how large this gap is and where it is headed in the coming decades. Combining detailed data and projections for macroeconomic and demographic variables with a rich model of Alberta’s budget, this report quantifies the scale of the province’s fiscal challenge and explores potential ways to address it. Overall, I find the present value of the difference between spending and non-resource revenues is 4.2 per cent of GDP between 2018 and 2100. By 2040, the fiscal gap that year will be roughly 44 per cent of controllable government revenue, 29 per cent of program spending, and the equivalent of over 4 per cent of GDP. In present value terms, the fiscal gap between now and 2040 is equivalent to over $250 billion today. I further find that debt levels are not on a sustainable path, as the long-run debt obligations exceed the government’s future ability to service that debt without significant policy changes. Meaningful action on both spending and revenue can address the province’s financial challenges. I explore various potential options. Without sustained, disciplined, and transparent action today, Alberta faces a precarious fiscal future.
艾伯塔省的短期财政挑战是众所周知的,但其长期挑战更为重大。人口老龄化、对不可再生资源收入的高度依赖以及不断上升的债务水平将日益扩大目前的支出和收入差距。本文估计了这一差距有多大,以及未来几十年的发展方向。结合宏观经济和人口变量的详细数据和预测以及阿尔伯塔省预算的丰富模型,本报告量化了该省财政挑战的规模,并探讨了解决这一挑战的潜在方法。总体而言,我发现在2018年至2100年期间,支出与非资源收入之差的现值为GDP的4.2%。到2040年,当年的财政缺口将约占可控政府收入的44%,占计划支出的29%,相当于GDP的4%以上。按现值计算,从现在到2040年的财政缺口相当于今天超过2500亿美元。我进一步发现,债务水平并不在可持续的道路上,因为长期债务超过了政府未来在没有重大政策变化的情况下偿还债务的能力。在支出和收入方面采取有意义的行动可以解决该省的财政挑战。我探索各种可能的选择。如果今天不采取持续、有纪律和透明的行动,艾伯塔省将面临一个不稳定的财政未来。
{"title":"Alberta's Long-Term Fiscal Future","authors":"Trevor Tombe","doi":"10.11575/SPPP.V11I0.52965","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.11575/SPPP.V11I0.52965","url":null,"abstract":"Alberta’s short-term fiscal challenges are well known, but its long-term ones are more significant. An aging population, a high reliance on non-renewable resource revenue, and rising debt levels will increasingly widen the current gap between spending and revenue. This paper estimates how large this gap is and where it is headed in the coming decades. Combining detailed data and projections for macroeconomic and demographic variables with a rich model of Alberta’s budget, this report quantifies the scale of the province’s fiscal challenge and explores potential ways to address it. Overall, I find the present value of the difference between spending and non-resource revenues is 4.2 per cent of GDP between 2018 and 2100. By 2040, the fiscal gap that year will be roughly 44 per cent of controllable government revenue, 29 per cent of program spending, and the equivalent of over 4 per cent of GDP. In present value terms, the fiscal gap between now and 2040 is equivalent to over $250 billion today. I further find that debt levels are not on a sustainable path, as the long-run debt obligations exceed the government’s future ability to service that debt without significant policy changes. Meaningful action on both spending and revenue can address the province’s financial challenges. I explore various potential options. Without sustained, disciplined, and transparent action today, Alberta faces a precarious fiscal future.","PeriodicalId":221919,"journal":{"name":"ERN: National","volume":"169 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2018-11-20","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"122435782","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 3
With Amazon HQ2, the Losers Are the Winners: Why Economic Development Subsidies Hurt More than They Help 亚马逊第二总部,输家就是赢家:为什么经济发展补贴弊大于利
Pub Date : 2018-11-13 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3536640
Michael D. Farren, Anne Philpot
On September 7, 2017, Amazon, Inc., announced that it would open a second headquarters by building “HQ2,” a new office equal in size to its Seattle campus, that would involve $5 billion in local business investments over 15–17 years and would eventually employ 50,000 workers with an average compensation more than $100,000. Amazon requested that interested cities submit proposals making the case for why their community would be the best fit for this massive new endeavor, including information on the public subsidies the city and state governments would offer to sweeten the deal. Amazon’s six-week deadline created a mad scramble among the 238 North American cities that eventually submitted bids, each attempting to illustrate why it in particular would be the best location to host Amazon’s new headquarters.

Despite arguments from economic development officials justifying such subsidies, both economic theory and experience suggest that cities and states are throwing their money away when they court Amazon’s favor through subsidies. Even subsidies worth billions of dollars are unlikely to sway Amazon’s decision. Worse, these kinds of targeted economic development incentives fail to produce economic growth.

In this paper, we examine the publicly known subsidies offered to Amazon as enticements to locate its second headquarters. We show that these subsidies are unlikely to alter the location decision of the company or lead to economic growth for the communities that offer them. We illustrate the tradeoffs that these subsidies would require in terms of forgone tax cuts and alternative uses of these funds for public services, such as safety and education. Lastly, we offer examples of institutional reforms — constitutional gift clauses, direct democracy, and interstate compacts — that could reduce the number of corporate subsidies in the future.
2017年9月7日,亚马逊公司宣布将通过建设“第二总部”来开设第二总部,这是一个与西雅图园区相当的新办公室,将在15-17年内在当地投资50亿美元,最终将雇用5万名员工,平均薪酬超过10万美元。亚马逊要求感兴趣的城市提交提案,说明为什么他们的社区最适合这项大规模的新努力,包括市政府和州政府为增加交易提供的公共补贴的信息。亚马逊的最后期限是六周,这在最终提交投标的238个北美城市中引发了一场疯狂的争夺,每个城市都试图说明为什么自己是亚马逊新总部的最佳选址。尽管经济发展官员为这种补贴辩护,但经济理论和经验都表明,城市和州通过补贴来讨好亚马逊,是在浪费钱。即使是价值数十亿美元的补贴也不太可能影响亚马逊的决定。更糟糕的是,这种有针对性的经济发展激励措施无法产生经济增长。在本文中,我们研究了公开提供给亚马逊的补贴,作为其第二总部选址的诱惑。我们表明,这些补贴不太可能改变公司的选址决策,也不太可能为提供补贴的社区带来经济增长。我们从放弃减税和将这些资金用于公共服务(如安全和教育)的其他用途方面说明了这些补贴所需要的权衡。最后,我们提供了制度改革的例子——宪法赠与条款、直接民主和州际契约——这些可以在未来减少企业补贴的数量。
{"title":"With Amazon HQ2, the Losers Are the Winners: Why Economic Development Subsidies Hurt More than They Help","authors":"Michael D. Farren, Anne Philpot","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3536640","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3536640","url":null,"abstract":"On September 7, 2017, Amazon, Inc., announced that it would open a second headquarters by building “HQ2,” a new office equal in size to its Seattle campus, that would involve $5 billion in local business investments over 15–17 years and would eventually employ 50,000 workers with an average compensation more than $100,000. Amazon requested that interested cities submit proposals making the case for why their community would be the best fit for this massive new endeavor, including information on the public subsidies the city and state governments would offer to sweeten the deal. Amazon’s six-week deadline created a mad scramble among the 238 North American cities that eventually submitted bids, each attempting to illustrate why it in particular would be the best location to host Amazon’s new headquarters.<br><br>Despite arguments from economic development officials justifying such subsidies, both economic theory and experience suggest that cities and states are throwing their money away when they court Amazon’s favor through subsidies. Even subsidies worth billions of dollars are unlikely to sway Amazon’s decision. Worse, these kinds of targeted economic development incentives fail to produce economic growth.<br><br>In this paper, we examine the publicly known subsidies offered to Amazon as enticements to locate its second headquarters. We show that these subsidies are unlikely to alter the location decision of the company or lead to economic growth for the communities that offer them. We illustrate the tradeoffs that these subsidies would require in terms of forgone tax cuts and alternative uses of these funds for public services, such as safety and education. Lastly, we offer examples of institutional reforms — constitutional gift clauses, direct democracy, and interstate compacts — that could reduce the number of corporate subsidies in the future.","PeriodicalId":221919,"journal":{"name":"ERN: National","volume":"12 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2018-11-13","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"123940950","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2
Show Us the Numbers: Grading the Financial Reports of Canada’s Municipalities 给我们看数字:对加拿大市政当局的财务报告进行评级
Pub Date : 2018-11-13 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.3283947
W. Robson, Farah Omran
In nearly all larger Canadian municipalities, obscure financial reports – notably, inconsistent presentations of key numbers in budgets and end-of-year financial statements – hamper councillors, ratepayers and voters who seek to hold their municipal governments to account. Simple information, such as how much the municipality plans to spend this year or how its spending plan this year compares with the previous year’s, is hard or impossible for a non-expert citizen or councillor to find. The differences between how the numbers appear in budgets and in financial results have real-world consequences. For example, by presenting net, rather than gross, budget figures, municipalities exclude key services such as water and the fees that fund them, obscuring key activities and understating both their revenue and expense. By using cash, rather than accrual, accounting, they exaggerate infrastructure investment costs, hide the cost of pension obligations, and make it hard to match the costs and benefits of their activities. Moreover, many municipalities approve their budgets after significant money has already been committed or spent in the fiscal year, fail to publish their fiscal year-end financial results in a timely way and bury key numbers deep in their documents. This report card grades the financial presentations of major Canadian municipalities in their most recent budgets and financial statements. Of those we assessed, Toronto, Durham Region, Kitchener, Quebec City, Longueuil and Montreal failed, providing little information in reader-friendly form. More happily, Surrey garners an A+ for clarity and completeness of its financial presentation, York Region is a close second with an A, while Vancouver and Markham are also good performers. We have two key recommendations. First, municipal governments should present their annual budgets on the same accounting basis as their year-end financial statements. Their budgets should use accrual accounting, recording revenues and expenses as the relevant activities occur. For their part, provincial governments that impede the use of accrual-based budgets – by mandating that cities present separate operating and capital budgets, for example – should stop doing so. Indeed, provinces should mandate cities to present accrual budgets so the fiscal pictures of municipalities and the province use the same transparent standard. Even in cases where a province is an impediment, municipalities could release the relevant information on their own – and they should. Second, budgets, like financial statements, should show city-wide consolidated, gross revenue and spending figures that represent the city’s full claim on its citizens’ resources and the full scope of its activities. These changes would help raise the financial management of Canada’s municipalities to a level more commensurate with their importance in Canadians’ lives.
在加拿大几乎所有较大的市政当局中,模糊的财务报告——尤其是预算和年终财务报表中关键数字的不一致——阻碍了议员、纳税人和选民向市政府问责。简单的信息,比如市政当局今年计划花多少钱,或者今年的支出计划与前一年相比如何,对于非专家公民或议员来说很难或不可能找到。预算和财务结果中数字的差异会对现实世界产生影响。例如,通过提供净预算而不是毛额预算数字,市政当局排除了水等关键服务和为其提供资金的费用,从而模糊了关键活动并低估了其收入和支出。通过使用现金而非权责发生制会计,他们夸大了基础设施投资成本,隐藏了养老金义务的成本,并使其活动的成本和收益难以匹配。此外,许多市政当局在本财政年度已经投入或支出了大量资金后才批准预算,未能及时公布其财政年终财务结果,并将关键数字深埋在文件中。这份报告卡对加拿大主要市政当局最近的预算和财务报表的财务情况进行了评分。在我们评估的城市中,多伦多、达勒姆地区、基奇纳、魁北克市、朗格伊尔和蒙特利尔没有通过,它们提供的信息很少。更令人高兴的是,萨里在财务报表的清晰度和完整性方面获得了A+,约克地区以A的成绩紧随其后,而温哥华和万锦市也表现不错。我们有两个关键建议。第一,市政府应采用与年终财务报表相同的会计基础提交年度预算。它们的预算应采用权责发生制,在有关活动发生时记录收入和费用。对阻碍使用权责发生制预算的省级政府来说,它们应该停止这样做——例如,要求城市分别提交运营预算和资本预算。事实上,各省应该要求各市提交应计预算,以便各市和省的财政状况使用相同的透明标准。即使在一个省是一个障碍的情况下,市政当局也可以自己发布相关信息——他们应该这样做。其次,预算和财务报表一样,应该显示全市的综合总收入和支出数字,这些数字代表了该市对其公民资源的全部要求和其活动的全部范围。这些变化将有助于提高加拿大市政当局的财务管理水平,使其与它们在加拿大人生活中的重要性更相称。
{"title":"Show Us the Numbers: Grading the Financial Reports of Canada’s Municipalities","authors":"W. Robson, Farah Omran","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.3283947","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.3283947","url":null,"abstract":"In nearly all larger Canadian municipalities, obscure financial reports – notably, inconsistent presentations of key numbers in budgets and end-of-year financial statements – hamper councillors, ratepayers and voters who seek to hold their municipal governments to account. Simple information, such as how much the municipality plans to spend this year or how its spending plan this year compares with the previous year’s, is hard or impossible for a non-expert citizen or councillor to find. The differences between how the numbers appear in budgets and in financial results have real-world consequences. For example, by presenting net, rather than gross, budget figures, municipalities exclude key services such as water and the fees that fund them, obscuring key activities and understating both their revenue and expense. By using cash, rather than accrual, accounting, they exaggerate infrastructure investment costs, hide the cost of pension obligations, and make it hard to match the costs and benefits of their activities. Moreover, many municipalities approve their budgets after significant money has already been committed or spent in the fiscal year, fail to publish their fiscal year-end financial results in a timely way and bury key numbers deep in their documents. This report card grades the financial presentations of major Canadian municipalities in their most recent budgets and financial statements. Of those we assessed, Toronto, Durham Region, Kitchener, Quebec City, Longueuil and Montreal failed, providing little information in reader-friendly form. More happily, Surrey garners an A+ for clarity and completeness of its financial presentation, York Region is a close second with an A, while Vancouver and Markham are also good performers. We have two key recommendations. First, municipal governments should present their annual budgets on the same accounting basis as their year-end financial statements. Their budgets should use accrual accounting, recording revenues and expenses as the relevant activities occur. For their part, provincial governments that impede the use of accrual-based budgets – by mandating that cities present separate operating and capital budgets, for example – should stop doing so. Indeed, provinces should mandate cities to present accrual budgets so the fiscal pictures of municipalities and the province use the same transparent standard. Even in cases where a province is an impediment, municipalities could release the relevant information on their own – and they should. Second, budgets, like financial statements, should show city-wide consolidated, gross revenue and spending figures that represent the city’s full claim on its citizens’ resources and the full scope of its activities. These changes would help raise the financial management of Canada’s municipalities to a level more commensurate with their importance in Canadians’ lives.","PeriodicalId":221919,"journal":{"name":"ERN: National","volume":"1 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2018-11-13","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"128442834","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 6
Fiscal Federalism and Dynamic Credence Capital in the U.S. 美国财政联邦制与动态信用资本
Pub Date : 2018-11-06 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3279856
J. Merrifield, B. Poulson
In this study we argue that the U.S. should follow the Swiss precedent, restoring a strong fiscal federalist system, with fiscal autonomy for state and local governments. A ‘no-bailout’ principle should be restored, such that state as well as local governments are subject to bankruptcy laws. Like their Swiss counterparts, state and local governments would then have an incentive to enact effective fiscal rules, mandating a balanced budget and reduction in unsustainable levels of debt. Swiss style fiscal rules are proposed for the federal government as well as state and local governments. With these fiscal rules in place elected officials would have an incentive to address the debt crisis. With effective fiscal rules, and enforcement of a ‘no-bailout principle, citizens would gain confidence in the ability of elected officials to pursue prudent fiscal policies. However, after a half century of declining dynamic credence capital, enacting the institutional reforms required for effective fiscal rules in the U.S. will be a formidable challenge.
在本研究中,我们认为美国应该效仿瑞士的先例,恢复一个强大的财政联邦制,赋予州和地方政府财政自主权。应该恢复“不救助”原则,这样州和地方政府都要遵守破产法。与瑞士政府一样,各州和地方政府将有动力制定有效的财政规则,强制实现预算平衡,降低不可持续的债务水平。瑞士式的财政规则被提议适用于联邦政府以及州和地方政府。有了这些财政规则,民选官员将有动力解决债务危机。有了有效的财政规则和“不救助”原则的执行,民众就会对民选官员推行审慎财政政策的能力产生信心。然而,在经历了半个世纪的动态信用资本下降之后,在美国实施有效财政规则所需的制度改革将是一项艰巨的挑战。
{"title":"Fiscal Federalism and Dynamic Credence Capital in the U.S.","authors":"J. Merrifield, B. Poulson","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3279856","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3279856","url":null,"abstract":"In this study we argue that the U.S. should follow the Swiss precedent, restoring a strong fiscal federalist system, with fiscal autonomy for state and local governments. A ‘no-bailout’ principle should be restored, such that state as well as local governments are subject to bankruptcy laws. Like their Swiss counterparts, state and local governments would then have an incentive to enact effective fiscal rules, mandating a balanced budget and reduction in unsustainable levels of debt. Swiss style fiscal rules are proposed for the federal government as well as state and local governments. With these fiscal rules in place elected officials would have an incentive to address the debt crisis. With effective fiscal rules, and enforcement of a ‘no-bailout principle, citizens would gain confidence in the ability of elected officials to pursue prudent fiscal policies. However, after a half century of declining dynamic credence capital, enacting the institutional reforms required for effective fiscal rules in the U.S. will be a formidable challenge.","PeriodicalId":221919,"journal":{"name":"ERN: National","volume":"143 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2018-11-06","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"134411218","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
期刊
ERN: National
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1