首页 > 最新文献

Journal of Legal Analysis最新文献

英文 中文
Drawing the Legal Family Tree: An Empirical Comparative Study of 170 Dimensions of Property Law in 129 Jurisdictions 绘制法律家谱:129个司法管辖区物权法170个维度的实证比较研究
IF 2.2 1区 社会学 Q1 LAW Pub Date : 2020-03-22 DOI: 10.1093/JLA/LAAA004
Yun-chien Chang, Nuno Garoupa, M. Wells
Traditional comparative private law scholars have a firm grasp of laws in several countries, but rarely of those in more than one hundred countries. Quantitative comparative private law scholars have placed dozens of countries into a legal family genealogy, but not based on a systematic understanding of legal substance around the world. Using a unique, hand-coded data set on 108 property doctrines (transformed into 170 binary variables) in 129 jurisdictions, we ran supervised and unsupervised machine-learning algorithms. Some of our findings confirm the conventional wisdom: French and German property laws are influential; mixed jurisdictions like South Africa and Scotland are one of a kind; common law jurisdictions form a group of their own; and a handful of formerly socialist countries, led by Russia, cluster together. Unlike the prior literature, however, we do not find that East Asian jurisdictions warrant a category of their own; but belong to distant groups. Spain and many Latin American countries form a separate group. Rather than finding a clear-cut common versus civil law division, we observe that the France-inspired group is one supercluster, separate from other jurisdictions.
传统的比较私法学者对几个国家的法律掌握得很好,但对一百多个国家的法律掌握得很少。定量比较私法学者已经将几十个国家放入一个法律家谱中,但这并不是基于对世界各地法律实质的系统理解。我们使用129个司法管辖区的108个财产原则(转化为170个二元变量)的独特手工编码数据集,运行有监督和无监督的机器学习算法。我们的一些发现证实了传统观点:法国和德国的物权法很有影响力;南非和苏格兰这样的混合司法管辖区是独一无二的;普通法司法管辖区形成了自己的群体;以俄罗斯为首的几个前社会主义国家聚集在一起。然而,与先前的文献不同的是,我们没有发现东亚司法管辖区需要一个自己的类别;而是属于遥远的群体。西班牙和许多拉丁美洲国家组成了一个单独的集团。我们没有找到一个明确的普通法与民法的划分,而是观察到法国启发的群体是一个超级集群,与其他司法管辖区分开。
{"title":"Drawing the Legal Family Tree: An Empirical Comparative Study of 170 Dimensions of Property Law in 129 Jurisdictions","authors":"Yun-chien Chang, Nuno Garoupa, M. Wells","doi":"10.1093/JLA/LAAA004","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1093/JLA/LAAA004","url":null,"abstract":"Traditional comparative private law scholars have a firm grasp of laws in several countries, but rarely of those in more than one hundred countries. Quantitative comparative private law scholars have placed dozens of countries into a legal family genealogy, but not based on a systematic understanding of legal substance around the world. Using a unique, hand-coded data set on 108 property doctrines (transformed into 170 binary variables) in 129 jurisdictions, we ran supervised and unsupervised machine-learning algorithms. Some of our findings confirm the conventional wisdom: French and German property laws are influential; mixed jurisdictions like South Africa and Scotland are one of a kind; common law jurisdictions form a group of their own; and a handful of formerly socialist countries, led by Russia, cluster together. Unlike the prior literature, however, we do not find that East Asian jurisdictions warrant a category of their own; but belong to distant groups. Spain and many Latin American countries form a separate group. Rather than finding a clear-cut common versus civil law division, we observe that the France-inspired group is one supercluster, separate from other jurisdictions.","PeriodicalId":45189,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Legal Analysis","volume":"180 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":2.2,"publicationDate":"2020-03-22","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"77500732","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 10
Beyond Information Costs: Preference Formation and the Architecture of Property Law 超越信息成本:偏好形成与物权法架构
IF 2.2 1区 社会学 Q1 LAW Pub Date : 2020-02-10 DOI: 10.1093/jla/laz007
Zhang T.
Abstract
Contemporary property theory highlights information costs as the central determinant of exclusion rights and numerus clausus-type standardization: rising information costs lead to stronger exclusion rights and more standardization, whereas falling information costs have the opposite effect. This paradigmatic model lacks, however, a theory of how information costs change in the first place. By developing such a theory, this article demonstrates that, in prominent cases, the legal impact of information costs tends to be counterbalanced by concurrent changes in individual preference, and that preexisting predictions about the relationship between information costs, standardization, and exclusion are therefore partially wrong, and otherwise incomplete.
摘要当代产权理论强调信息成本是排他权和众多条款式标准化的核心决定因素:信息成本的上升导致排他权的增强和标准化程度的提高,而信息成本的下降则产生相反的效果。然而,这种范式模型首先缺乏一个关于信息成本如何变化的理论。通过发展这样一个理论,本文表明,在一些突出的案例中,信息成本的法律影响往往被个人偏好的同步变化所抵消,因此,先前关于信息成本、标准化和排斥之间关系的预测部分是错误的,否则就是不完整的。
{"title":"Beyond Information Costs: Preference Formation and the Architecture of Property Law","authors":"Zhang T.","doi":"10.1093/jla/laz007","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1093/jla/laz007","url":null,"abstract":"<span><div>Abstract</div>Contemporary property theory highlights information costs as the central determinant of exclusion rights and numerus clausus-type standardization: rising information costs lead to stronger exclusion rights and more standardization, whereas falling information costs have the opposite effect. This paradigmatic model lacks, however, a theory of how information costs change in the first place. By developing such a theory, this article demonstrates that, in prominent cases, the legal impact of information costs tends to be counterbalanced by concurrent changes in individual preference, and that preexisting predictions about the relationship between information costs, standardization, and exclusion are therefore partially wrong, and otherwise incomplete.</span>","PeriodicalId":45189,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Legal Analysis","volume":"37 5","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":2.2,"publicationDate":"2020-02-10","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"138520805","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Lockean Copyright versus Lockean Property 洛克版权与洛克财产
IF 2.2 1区 社会学 Q1 LAW Pub Date : 2020-01-01 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.3423423
Mala Chatterjee
Locke’s labor theory, the most familiar of property theories, has faced centuries of philosophical criticism. Nonetheless, recent legal scholars have applied it to intellectual property while overlooking these philosophical critiques. Philosophers, on the other hand, are largely absent in IP theorizing, thus not asking whether Locke’s resilient intuition is salvageable in copyright’s domain. This Article argues that Lockean copyright is actually far more plausible than Lockean property, for it avoids the most devastating objections the latter faces. It then defends a surprising doctrinal implication of this theoretical conclusion: a workable Lockean copyright favors rights far more limited than present law.
洛克的劳动理论是产权理论中最为人所熟知的,它面临着几个世纪以来的哲学批判。尽管如此,最近的法律学者将其应用于知识产权,而忽略了这些哲学批评。另一方面,哲学家们在知识产权理论化方面基本上是缺席的,因此没有问洛克的弹性直觉是否可以在版权领域得到拯救。本文认为,洛克式版权实际上比洛克式财产更合理,因为它避免了后者面临的最具破坏性的反对意见。然后,它为这一理论结论的一个令人惊讶的理论含义进行了辩护:一个可行的洛克版权支持的权利远比现行法律更有限。
{"title":"Lockean Copyright versus Lockean Property","authors":"Mala Chatterjee","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.3423423","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.3423423","url":null,"abstract":"Locke’s labor theory, the most familiar of property theories, has faced centuries of philosophical criticism. Nonetheless, recent legal scholars have applied it to intellectual property while overlooking these philosophical critiques. Philosophers, on the other hand, are largely absent in IP theorizing, thus not asking whether Locke’s resilient intuition is salvageable in copyright’s domain. This Article argues that Lockean copyright is actually far more plausible than Lockean property, for it avoids the most devastating objections the latter faces. It then defends a surprising doctrinal implication of this theoretical conclusion: a workable Lockean copyright favors rights far more limited than present law.","PeriodicalId":45189,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Legal Analysis","volume":"79 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":2.2,"publicationDate":"2020-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"88079292","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Building Coalitions Out of Thin Air: Transferable Development Rights and “Constituency Effects” in Land Use Law 无中生有地建立联盟:土地使用法中的可转让发展权和“选区效应”
IF 2.2 1区 社会学 Q1 LAW Pub Date : 2020-01-01 DOI: 10.1093/jla/laz008
R. Hills,, David Schleicher
Transferable Development Rights (TDRs) were supposed to be a solution to the intractable problems of land use, a bit of institutional design magic that married the interests of development and preservation at no cost to taxpayers and with no legal risk. Under a TDR program, development is limited or barred on properties targeted for preservation or other regulatory goals, but owners of those lots are allowed sell their unused development rights to other property owners. In theory, this allows the same amount of development to occur while preserving favored uses without tax subsidies or constitutional challenges. Reviewing their use over the last forty years, this Article shows that the traditional justifications for TDRs do not work. In practice, TDRs are not necessary to avoid takings litigation, are not costless to taxpayers, and do not balance the interests of preservation and development, but instead serve as yet another growth control in metropolitan areas where such controls have caused housing crises and major harms to the national economy. Assessed as a technocratic tool for solving problems in land use, TDRs are a failure. But this Article shows that there is a case for TDRs not as a technocratic but rather as a political tool. By giving valuable development rights to some popular or otherwise politically influential owners of regulated property, a city can build a coalition for re-zonings that might otherwise be politically impossible. The effect of TDRs on politics can be positive to the extent that TDRs strengthen constituencies or land use goals that local politics systematically undercounts, as we show through an analysis of New York City’s Special District Transfer TDR program. In particular, TDRs could help break Not In My Back Yard opposition to new development by building a competing pro-growth coalition. More generally, using TDRs as an example, the Article shows how land use law is the creator as well as creature of local politics. Existing property law helps cement anti-development coalitions, but savvy leaders could use moments in power to create stable pro-growth coalitions by enacting new laws that help mobilize new pro-growth constituencies. Understanding these “constituency effects” of land use law allows policymakers to redesign entitlements like TDRs to produce a healthier land use policies.
可转让发展权(tdr)被认为是解决棘手的土地使用问题的一种方法,是一种制度设计的魔法,它将发展和保护的利益结合在一起,不需要纳税人付出代价,也没有法律风险。根据TDR计划,为保护或其他监管目标而开发的物业受到限制或禁止,但这些地块的所有者可以将其未使用的开发权出售给其他业主。理论上,这允许在保留有利用途的同时进行同等数量的开发,而无需税收补贴或宪法挑战。本文回顾了过去四十年来tdr的使用情况,表明传统的tdr理由并不成立。在实践中,tdr并不是避免征收诉讼的必要条件,对纳税人来说也不是没有成本的,也没有平衡保护和发展的利益,而是在大都市地区作为另一种增长控制手段,这种控制已经造成了住房危机,并对国民经济造成了重大损害。作为解决土地使用问题的技术官僚工具,tdr是失败的。但这篇文章表明,tdr不是作为一种技术官僚,而是作为一种政治工具。通过将宝贵的开发权给予受监管房产的一些受欢迎的或在政治上有影响力的所有者,一个城市可以建立一个联盟来重新划分区域,否则这在政治上是不可能的。正如我们通过对纽约市特区转移TDR计划的分析所显示的那样,TDR对政治的影响可以是积极的,因为TDR加强了地方政治系统低估的选区或土地使用目标。特别是,tdr可以通过建立一个与之竞争的支持增长的联盟,帮助打破反对新开发的“不要在我的后院”(Not In My backyard)。更一般地说,本文以tdr为例,说明土地使用法既是地方政治的创造者,又是地方政治的创造者。现有的物权法有助于巩固反发展联盟,但精明的领导人可以利用掌权的时机,通过颁布新的法律,帮助动员新的支持增长的选民,来建立稳定的支持增长的联盟。理解了土地使用法的这些“选民效应”,政策制定者就可以重新设计像tdr这样的权利,从而制定更健康的土地使用政策。
{"title":"Building Coalitions Out of Thin Air: Transferable Development Rights and “Constituency Effects” in Land Use Law","authors":"R. Hills,, David Schleicher","doi":"10.1093/jla/laz008","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1093/jla/laz008","url":null,"abstract":"Transferable Development Rights (TDRs) were supposed to be a solution to the intractable problems of land use, a bit of institutional design magic that married the interests of development and preservation at no cost to taxpayers and with no legal risk. Under a TDR program, development is limited or barred on properties targeted for preservation or other regulatory goals, but owners of those lots are allowed sell their unused development rights to other property owners. In theory, this allows the same amount of development to occur while preserving favored uses without tax subsidies or constitutional challenges. Reviewing their use over the last forty years, this Article shows that the traditional justifications for TDRs do not work. In practice, TDRs are not necessary to avoid takings litigation, are not costless to taxpayers, and do not balance the interests of preservation and development, but instead serve as yet another growth control in metropolitan areas where such controls have caused housing crises and major harms to the national economy. Assessed as a technocratic tool for solving problems in land use, TDRs are a failure. But this Article shows that there is a case for TDRs not as a technocratic but rather as a political tool. By giving valuable development rights to some popular or otherwise politically influential owners of regulated property, a city can build a coalition for re-zonings that might otherwise be politically impossible. The effect of TDRs on politics can be positive to the extent that TDRs strengthen constituencies or land use goals that local politics systematically undercounts, as we show through an analysis of New York City’s Special District Transfer TDR program. In particular, TDRs could help break Not In My Back Yard opposition to new development by building a competing pro-growth coalition. More generally, using TDRs as an example, the Article shows how land use law is the creator as well as creature of local politics. Existing property law helps cement anti-development coalitions, but savvy leaders could use moments in power to create stable pro-growth coalitions by enacting new laws that help mobilize new pro-growth constituencies. Understanding these “constituency effects” of land use law allows policymakers to redesign entitlements like TDRs to produce a healthier land use policies.","PeriodicalId":45189,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Legal Analysis","volume":"65 1","pages":"79-135"},"PeriodicalIF":2.2,"publicationDate":"2020-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"77852399","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2
Free Speech and Cheap Talk 言论自由和廉价言论
IF 2.2 1区 社会学 Q1 LAW Pub Date : 2019-01-01 DOI: 10.1093/jla/laz004
Daniel Hemel,Ariel Porat
Abstract We present a new framework for analyzing defamation liability that serves both to clarify and complicate understandings of the law’s consequences for speakers, victims, and the marketplace of ideas. In addition to the familiar deterrence and chilling effects, we show how defamation liability can generate a “warming effect,” making statements more credible and potentially raising both the quality and quantity of speech. We also explain how a more plaintiff-friendly liability regime may exacerbate harms to defamation victims. We end by considering the possibility of “self-tailored” defamation law, with victims or speakers selecting the defamation liability regime that applies to them.
我们提出了一个分析诽谤责任的新框架,它既可以澄清也可以使法律对说话者、受害者和思想市场的后果的理解复杂化。除了常见的威慑和寒蝉效应外,我们还展示了诽谤责任如何产生“暖化效应”,使言论更加可信,并有可能提高言论的质量和数量。我们还解释了一个更有利于原告的责任制度如何可能加剧对诽谤受害者的伤害。最后,我们考虑了“量身定制”诽谤法的可能性,由受害者或说话者选择适用于他们的诽谤责任制度。
{"title":"Free Speech and Cheap Talk","authors":"Daniel Hemel,Ariel Porat","doi":"10.1093/jla/laz004","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1093/jla/laz004","url":null,"abstract":"Abstract We present a new framework for analyzing defamation liability that serves both to clarify and complicate understandings of the law’s consequences for speakers, victims, and the marketplace of ideas. In addition to the familiar deterrence and chilling effects, we show how defamation liability can generate a “warming effect,” making statements more credible and potentially raising both the quality and quantity of speech. We also explain how a more plaintiff-friendly liability regime may exacerbate harms to defamation victims. We end by considering the possibility of “self-tailored” defamation law, with victims or speakers selecting the defamation liability regime that applies to them.","PeriodicalId":45189,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Legal Analysis","volume":"15 12","pages":"46-103"},"PeriodicalIF":2.2,"publicationDate":"2019-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"138520852","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Data Pollution 数据污染
IF 2.2 1区 社会学 Q1 LAW Pub Date : 2019-01-01 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3191231
O. Ben‐Shahar
Digital information is the fuel of the new economy. But like the old economy’s carbon fuel, it also pollutes. Harmful “data emissions” are leaked into the digital ecosystem, disrupting social institutions and public interests. This article develops a novel framework—data pollution—to rethink the harms the data economy creates and the way they have to be regulated. It argues that social intervention should focus on the external harms from collection and misuse of personal data. The article challenges the hegemony of the prevailing view—that the injuries from digital data enterprise are exclusively private. That view has led lawmakers to focus solely on privacy protection as the regulatory objective. The article claims, instead, that a central problem in the digital economy has been largely ignored: how the information given by people affects others, and how it undermines and degrades public goods and interests. The data pollution concept offers a novel perspective why existing regulatory tools—torts, contracts, and disclosure law—are ineffective, mirroring their historical futility in curbing the harms from industrial pollution. The data pollution framework also opens up a rich roadmap for new regulatory devices—“an environmental law for data protection”—which focuses on controlling these external effects. The article examines how the tools used to control industrial pollution—production restrictions, carbon tax, and emissions liability—could be adapted to govern data pollution.
数字信息是新经济的燃料。但就像旧经济的碳燃料一样,它也会造成污染。有害的“数据排放”流入数字生态系统,扰乱社会制度和公共利益。本文提出了一个新的框架——数据污染——来重新思考数据经济造成的危害以及必须对其进行监管的方式。认为社会干预应侧重于个人数据收集和滥用的外部危害。这篇文章挑战了“数字数据企业的伤害完全是私人的”这一主流观点的霸权。这种观点导致立法者只把隐私保护作为监管目标。相反,这篇文章声称,数字经济中的一个核心问题在很大程度上被忽视了:人们提供的信息如何影响他人,以及它如何破坏和降低公共产品和利益。数据污染的概念提供了一个新的视角,为什么现有的监管工具——侵权、合同和信息披露法——是无效的,反映了它们在遏制工业污染危害方面的历史无效。数据污染框架还为新的监管手段——“数据保护环境法”——开辟了丰富的路线图,重点是控制这些外部影响。本文考察了用于控制工业污染的工具——生产限制、碳税和排放责任——如何适用于治理数据污染。
{"title":"Data Pollution","authors":"O. Ben‐Shahar","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3191231","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3191231","url":null,"abstract":"\u0000 Digital information is the fuel of the new economy. But like the old economy’s carbon fuel, it also pollutes. Harmful “data emissions” are leaked into the digital ecosystem, disrupting social institutions and public interests. This article develops a novel framework—data pollution—to rethink the harms the data economy creates and the way they have to be regulated. It argues that social intervention should focus on the external harms from collection and misuse of personal data. The article challenges the hegemony of the prevailing view—that the injuries from digital data enterprise are exclusively private. That view has led lawmakers to focus solely on privacy protection as the regulatory objective. The article claims, instead, that a central problem in the digital economy has been largely ignored: how the information given by people affects others, and how it undermines and degrades public goods and interests. The data pollution concept offers a novel perspective why existing regulatory tools—torts, contracts, and disclosure law—are ineffective, mirroring their historical futility in curbing the harms from industrial pollution. The data pollution framework also opens up a rich roadmap for new regulatory devices—“an environmental law for data protection”—which focuses on controlling these external effects. The article examines how the tools used to control industrial pollution—production restrictions, carbon tax, and emissions liability—could be adapted to govern data pollution.","PeriodicalId":45189,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Legal Analysis","volume":"5 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":2.2,"publicationDate":"2019-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"81793203","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 25
The Proportional Internalization Principle in Private Law 私法中的比例内部化原则
IF 2.2 1区 社会学 Q1 LAW Pub Date : 2019-01-01 DOI: 10.1093/jla/laz006
Omer Pelled
According to common conception, laws should make actors internalize all the costs and benefits of their actions to make them behave efficiently. This article shows that even when only partial internalization is possible, private law can create efficient incentives by ensuring that each actor internalizes an identical proportion of the costs and benefits.This proportional internalization principle has profound implications. In tort law, it offers a new mechanism for dividing liability between multiple parties. In contract law, it suggests a new default rule for joint ventures. And, in restitution law, it presents an alternative doctrinal formulation for restitution for unrequested benefit.
一般观念认为,法律应该使行为人将其行为的所有成本和收益内化,以使其行为有效。本文表明,即使只有部分内部化是可能的,私法也可以通过确保每个行为者内部化相同比例的成本和收益来创造有效的激励。这个比例内化原则具有深远的意义。在侵权行为法中,它提供了一种分担多方责任的新机制。在合同法中,它为合资企业提出了新的默认规则。而且,在赔偿法中,它提出了另一种理论公式,用于赔偿未请求的利益。
{"title":"The Proportional Internalization Principle in Private Law","authors":"Omer Pelled","doi":"10.1093/jla/laz006","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1093/jla/laz006","url":null,"abstract":"According to common conception, laws should make actors internalize all the costs and benefits of their actions to make them behave efficiently. This article shows that even when only partial internalization is possible, private law can create efficient incentives by ensuring that each actor internalizes an identical proportion of the costs and benefits.This proportional internalization principle has profound implications. In tort law, it offers a new mechanism for dividing liability between multiple parties. In contract law, it suggests a new default rule for joint ventures. And, in restitution law, it presents an alternative doctrinal formulation for restitution for unrequested benefit.","PeriodicalId":45189,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Legal Analysis","volume":"20 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":2.2,"publicationDate":"2019-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"89679140","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Recoupment and Predatory Pricing Analysis 补偿和掠夺性定价分析
IF 2.2 1区 社会学 Q1 LAW Pub Date : 2018-12-31 DOI: 10.1093/JLA/LAY003
L. Kaplow
Recoupment inquiries play an increasingly important role in antitrust analysis, yet they raise a number of conundrums: How can a failure of recoupment due to the plausible long-run profit recovery being dwarfed by short-run losses be reconciled with a defense of no predation that presupposes no short-run sacrifice to begin with? How can recoupment inquiries be diagnostic with respect to competing explanations for defendants’ behavior—such as product promotion or “legal” predation—that likewise require recoupment? This article addresses these questions and others by grounding recoupment and predatory pricing analysis more broadly in a decision framework that focuses on classification (distinguishing illegal predation from other explanations for firms’ pricing) and on the magnitudes of the deterrence benefits and chilling costs of imposing liability. Regarding the latter, although concerns for the chilling of procompetitive activity sensibly drive predatory pricing analysis, the great variation in chilling costs across competing explanations for alleged predation is unrecognized. Much of the analysis here is not particular to recoupment; the investigation aims to inform future research, policy, and practice regarding many aspects of predatory pricing as well as other forms of anticompetitive conduct. Forthcoming, Journal of Legal Analysis (2018)
补偿调查在反垄断分析中发挥着越来越重要的作用,但它们也带来了许多难题:由于短期损失使看似合理的长期利润恢复相形见绌而导致的补偿失败,如何与以不牺牲短期利益为前提的不掠夺辩护相协调?关于被告行为的竞争性解释,如产品促销或“合法”掠夺,同样需要赔偿,赔偿调查如何能够诊断?本文通过在一个决策框架中更广泛地对补偿和掠夺性定价进行分析来解决这些问题和其他问题,该决策框架侧重于分类(将非法掠夺与公司定价的其他解释区分开来)以及施加责任的威慑效益和冷却成本的大小。对于后者,尽管对促进竞争活动的寒蝉效应的关注合理地推动了掠夺性定价分析,但对所谓的掠夺性行为的不同解释中,寒蝉成本的巨大差异尚未得到承认。这里的许多分析并不是专门针对补偿的;调查旨在为未来的研究、政策和实践提供信息,涉及掠夺性定价以及其他形式的反竞争行为的许多方面。《法律分析》(2018)
{"title":"Recoupment and Predatory Pricing Analysis","authors":"L. Kaplow","doi":"10.1093/JLA/LAY003","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1093/JLA/LAY003","url":null,"abstract":"Recoupment inquiries play an increasingly important role in antitrust analysis, yet they raise a number of conundrums: How can a failure of recoupment due to the plausible long-run profit recovery being dwarfed by short-run losses be reconciled with a defense of no predation that presupposes no short-run sacrifice to begin with? How can recoupment inquiries be diagnostic with respect to competing explanations for defendants’ behavior—such as product promotion or “legal” predation—that likewise require recoupment? This article addresses these questions and others by grounding recoupment and predatory pricing analysis more broadly in a decision framework that focuses on classification (distinguishing illegal predation from other explanations for firms’ pricing) and on the magnitudes of the deterrence benefits and chilling costs of imposing liability. Regarding the latter, although concerns for the chilling of procompetitive activity sensibly drive predatory pricing analysis, the great variation in chilling costs across competing explanations for alleged predation is unrecognized. Much of the analysis here is not particular to recoupment; the investigation aims to inform future research, policy, and practice regarding many aspects of predatory pricing as well as other forms of anticompetitive conduct. Forthcoming, Journal of Legal Analysis (2018)","PeriodicalId":45189,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Legal Analysis","volume":"64 1","pages":"46-112"},"PeriodicalIF":2.2,"publicationDate":"2018-12-31","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"84469988","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2
Discrimination in the Age of Algorithms 算法时代的歧视
IF 2.2 1区 社会学 Q1 LAW Pub Date : 2018-01-01 DOI: 10.1093/jla/laz001
Jon Kleinberg,Jens Ludwig,Sendhil Mullainathan,Cass R Sunstein
Abstract The law forbids discrimination. But the ambiguity of human decision-making often makes it hard for the legal system to know whether anyone has discriminated. To understand how algorithms affect discrimination, we must understand how they affect the detection of discrimination. With the appropriate requirements in place, algorithms create the potential for new forms of transparency and hence opportunities to detect discrimination that are otherwise unavailable. The specificity of algorithms also makes transparent tradeoffs among competing values. This implies algorithms are not only a threat to be regulated; with the right safeguards, they can be a potential positive force for equity.
法律禁止歧视。但是,人类决策的模糊性往往使法律体系很难知道是否有人存在歧视。要了解算法如何影响歧视,我们必须了解它们如何影响歧视的检测。有了适当的要求,算法就有可能实现新形式的透明度,从而有机会发现在其他情况下无法发现的歧视。算法的特殊性也使得竞争价值之间的权衡变得透明。这意味着算法不仅是一种需要监管的威胁;有了适当的保障,它们可以成为促进公平的潜在积极力量。
{"title":"Discrimination in the Age of Algorithms","authors":"Jon Kleinberg,Jens Ludwig,Sendhil Mullainathan,Cass R Sunstein","doi":"10.1093/jla/laz001","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1093/jla/laz001","url":null,"abstract":"Abstract The law forbids discrimination. But the ambiguity of human decision-making often makes it hard for the legal system to know whether anyone has discriminated. To understand how algorithms affect discrimination, we must understand how they affect the detection of discrimination. With the appropriate requirements in place, algorithms create the potential for new forms of transparency and hence opportunities to detect discrimination that are otherwise unavailable. The specificity of algorithms also makes transparent tradeoffs among competing values. This implies algorithms are not only a threat to be regulated; with the right safeguards, they can be a potential positive force for equity.","PeriodicalId":45189,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Legal Analysis","volume":"199 1","pages":"113-174"},"PeriodicalIF":2.2,"publicationDate":"2018-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"138520804","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Unsettled: A Global Study of Settlements in Occupied Territories 未解决:被占领领土上定居点的全球研究
IF 2.2 1区 社会学 Q1 LAW Pub Date : 2017-12-01 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.2835908
E. Kontorovich
This Article provides the first comprehensive, global examination of state and international practice bearing on Article 49(6) of the Fourth Geneva Convention, which provides that an “Occupying Power shall not deport or transfer parts of its own civilian population into the territory it occupies.” This provision is a staple of legal and diplomatic international discussions of the Arab-Israeli conflict, and serves as the basis for criticism of Israeli settlement policy. Despite its frequent invocation in the Israeli context, scholars have never examined – or even considered – how the norm has been interpreted and applied in any other occupation context in the post-WWII era. For example, the International Committee of the Red Cross’s (ICRC) influential Study on Customary International Humanitarian Law lists 107 instances of national practice and UN practice applying or interpreting the prohibition, and all but two relate to Israel. Many questions exist about the scope and application of Art. 49(6)’s prohibition on “transfer,” but they have generally been answered on purely theoretically. To better understand what Art. 49(6) does in fact demand, this Article closely examines its application in all other cases in which it could apply. Many of the settlement enterprises studied in this Article have never been discussed or documented. All of these situations involved the movement of settlers into the occupied territory, in numbers ranging from thousands to hundreds of thousands. Indeed, perhaps every prolonged occupation of contiguous habitable territory has resulted in significant settlement activity.Clear patterns emerge from this systematic study of state practice. Strikingly, the state practice paints a picture that is significantly inconsistent with the prior conventional wisdom concerning Art. 49(6). First, the migration of people into occupied territory is a near-ubiquitous feature of extended belligerent occupations. Second, no occupying power has ever taken any measures to discourage or prevent such settlement activity, nor has any occupying power ever expressed opinio juris suggesting that it is bound to do so. Third, and perhaps most strikingly, in none of these situations have the international community or international organizations described the migration of persons into the occupied territory as a violation of Art. 49(6). Even in the rare cases in which such policies have met with international criticism, it has not been in legal terms. This suggests that the level of direct state involvement in “transfer” required to constitute an Art. 49(6) violation may be significantly greater than previously thought. Finally, neither international political bodies nor the new governments of previously occupied territories have ever embraced the removal of illegally transferred civilian settlers as an appropriate remedy.The deeper understanding – based on a systematic survey of all available state practice – of the prohibition on settlements should
本条第一次全面、全面地审查了与《日内瓦第四公约》第49条第6款有关的国家和国际惯例,该条规定“占领国不得将其本国平民的一部分驱逐或移送到其占领的领土”。这一规定是关于阿以冲突的法律和外交国际讨论的主要内容,也是批评以色列定居点政策的依据。尽管它经常在以色列的背景下被引用,但学者们从来没有研究过——甚至没有考虑过——在二战后的任何其他占领背景下,这一规范是如何被解释和应用的。例如,红十字国际委员会(ICRC)颇具影响力的《习惯国际人道主义法研究》(Study on Customary International Humanitarian Law)列出了107个国家实践和联合国实践适用或解释禁令的例子,除了两个以外,其余都与以色列有关。关于第49条第(6)款禁止“转让”的范围和适用,存在着许多问题,但一般都是在纯理论上得到了解答。为了更好地理解第49条第(6)款的实际要求,本文仔细审查了它在所有其他可能适用的情况下的适用情况。本文研究的许多聚落企业从未被讨论或文献记载。所有这些情况都涉及移民进入被占领领土,人数从数千到数十万不等。事实上,也许每一次对连续可居住领土的长期占领都会导致大量的定居活动。这种对国家实践的系统研究,形成了清晰的模式。引人注目的是,国家实践描绘了一幅与第49(6)条之前的传统智慧明显不一致的画面。首先,人民向被占领土的迁移是长期交战占领的一个几乎无处不在的特征。第二,没有任何占领国采取任何措施阻止或阻止这种定居活动,也没有任何占领国在法律上表示它必须这样做。第三,也许也是最引人注目的是,在所有这些情况下,国际社会或国际组织都没有将人员向被占领领土的移徙描述为违反第49(6)条。即使在少数情况下,这些政策遭到了国际社会的批评,但也不是在法律上。这表明,构成第49(6)条违反所要求的国家直接参与“转让”的程度可能比以前认为的要大得多。最后,无论是国际政治机构还是以前被占领领土的新政府,都从未把驱逐非法转移的平民定居者作为一种适当的补救办法。基于对所有现有国家实践的系统调查对禁止定居点的更深入了解,应该为关于阿拉伯-以色列冲突的法律讨论提供信息,包括国际刑事法院可能对这种活动进行的调查。更广泛地说,本文对第49条第6款的新理解也可以为如何正确对待几个正在进行的占领提供重要启示,从西撒哈拉和北塞浦路斯,到俄罗斯对乌克兰和格鲁吉亚的占领,本条首次记录了这些占领的解决政策。
{"title":"Unsettled: A Global Study of Settlements in Occupied Territories","authors":"E. Kontorovich","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.2835908","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.2835908","url":null,"abstract":"This Article provides the first comprehensive, global examination of state and international practice bearing on Article 49(6) of the Fourth Geneva Convention, which provides that an “Occupying Power shall not deport or transfer parts of its own civilian population into the territory it occupies.” This provision is a staple of legal and diplomatic international discussions of the Arab-Israeli conflict, and serves as the basis for criticism of Israeli settlement policy. Despite its frequent invocation in the Israeli context, scholars have never examined – or even considered – how the norm has been interpreted and applied in any other occupation context in the post-WWII era. For example, the International Committee of the Red Cross’s (ICRC) influential Study on Customary International Humanitarian Law lists 107 instances of national practice and UN practice applying or interpreting the prohibition, and all but two relate to Israel. Many questions exist about the scope and application of Art. 49(6)’s prohibition on “transfer,” but they have generally been answered on purely theoretically. To better understand what Art. 49(6) does in fact demand, this Article closely examines its application in all other cases in which it could apply. Many of the settlement enterprises studied in this Article have never been discussed or documented. All of these situations involved the movement of settlers into the occupied territory, in numbers ranging from thousands to hundreds of thousands. Indeed, perhaps every prolonged occupation of contiguous habitable territory has resulted in significant settlement activity.Clear patterns emerge from this systematic study of state practice. Strikingly, the state practice paints a picture that is significantly inconsistent with the prior conventional wisdom concerning Art. 49(6). First, the migration of people into occupied territory is a near-ubiquitous feature of extended belligerent occupations. Second, no occupying power has ever taken any measures to discourage or prevent such settlement activity, nor has any occupying power ever expressed opinio juris suggesting that it is bound to do so. Third, and perhaps most strikingly, in none of these situations have the international community or international organizations described the migration of persons into the occupied territory as a violation of Art. 49(6). Even in the rare cases in which such policies have met with international criticism, it has not been in legal terms. This suggests that the level of direct state involvement in “transfer” required to constitute an Art. 49(6) violation may be significantly greater than previously thought. Finally, neither international political bodies nor the new governments of previously occupied territories have ever embraced the removal of illegally transferred civilian settlers as an appropriate remedy.The deeper understanding – based on a systematic survey of all available state practice – of the prohibition on settlements should ","PeriodicalId":45189,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Legal Analysis","volume":"103 1","pages":"285-350"},"PeriodicalIF":2.2,"publicationDate":"2017-12-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"77757554","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 6
期刊
Journal of Legal Analysis
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1