首页 > 最新文献

Voprosy Ekonomiki最新文献

英文 中文
Austrian school of economics: Fundamental principles, methodology, institutional analysis and perspectives 奥地利经济学派:基本原则、方法论、制度分析和观点
IF 0.8 Q1 Arts and Humanities Pub Date : 2024-02-06 DOI: 10.32609/0042-8736-2024-2-67-83
A. Zaostrovtsev, V. V. Matveev
The article presents the main characteristics of the modern Austrian school. Its fundamental principles are shown, from which its remaining gap with the economic mainstream becomes obvious. The task is solved to demonstrate that the Austrian economics as its initial methodological foundation has not strict methodological individualism, but institutional individualism. It is not typical for it to see a person as the notorious homo economicus. The Austrian school is a kind of modern institutionalism, the historical roots of which go back to the writings of its founders. This is due to its inherent focus not on the allocation of resources, but on individual exchange (catallaxy). The latter needs good institutions. At the same time, informal institutions (beliefs, traditions) that determine the meaning of human actions are highlighted. The spontaneous order and one of its institutional forms — anarchy are considered. The article concludes with an appeal to the perspectives of Austrian economic thought — its potential contribution to various research programs.
文章介绍了现代奥地利学派的主要特点。文章展示了该学派的基本原则,由此可见该学派与主流经济学的差距。我们的任务是要证明,作为其最初方法论基础的奥地利经济学不是严格的方法论个人主义,而是制度性个人主义。把一个人视为臭名昭著的经济人并不典型。奥地利学派是一种现代制度主义,其历史根源可以追溯到其创始人的著作。这是因为它的内在重点不是资源分配,而是个人交换(catallaxy)。后者需要良好的制度。同时,决定人类行为意义的非正式制度(信仰、传统)也得到了强调。文章还探讨了自发秩序及其制度形式之一--无政府状态。文章最后呼吁从奥地利经济思想的角度出发,探讨其对各种研究计划的潜在贡献。
{"title":"Austrian school of economics: Fundamental principles, methodology, institutional analysis and perspectives","authors":"A. Zaostrovtsev, V. V. Matveev","doi":"10.32609/0042-8736-2024-2-67-83","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.32609/0042-8736-2024-2-67-83","url":null,"abstract":"The article presents the main characteristics of the modern Austrian school. Its fundamental principles are shown, from which its remaining gap with the economic mainstream becomes obvious. The task is solved to demonstrate that the Austrian economics as its initial methodological foundation has not strict methodological individualism, but institutional individualism. It is not typical for it to see a person as the notorious homo economicus. The Austrian school is a kind of modern institutionalism, the historical roots of which go back to the writings of its founders. This is due to its inherent focus not on the allocation of resources, but on individual exchange (catallaxy). The latter needs good institutions. At the same time, informal institutions (beliefs, traditions) that determine the meaning of human actions are highlighted. The spontaneous order and one of its institutional forms — anarchy are considered. The article concludes with an appeal to the perspectives of Austrian economic thought — its potential contribution to various research programs.","PeriodicalId":45534,"journal":{"name":"Voprosy Ekonomiki","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.8,"publicationDate":"2024-02-06","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"139861275","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Influence of preferential regimes on the Russian Far East development 优惠制度对俄罗斯远东地区发展的影响
IF 0.8 Q1 Arts and Humanities Pub Date : 2024-02-06 DOI: 10.32609/0042-8736-2024-2-103-124
G. Borshchevskiy
The purpose of the study is to assess the impact of preferential regimes on the socio-economic development of territories on the example of the Far Eastern regions. We use both quantitative (e.g. regression and correlation analysis, modeling, method of averages, index method, “difference in differences”, factor analysis) and qualitative methods (document analysis, case-study, benchmarking, classification). The creation of preferential regimes, such as the Territory of Advanced Development, Free Port of Vladivostok, Arctic Zone of the Russian Federation, was a key element of the Far East development policy. To manage these preferential regimes a development institution has been created named Corporation for the Far East and the Arctic Development (CFEAD). We carried out the evaluation of the indicators of preferential regimes functioning and the socio-economic development of the Far Eastern regions. We identified the regions where these regimes have a positive impact on economic growth, and estimated the degree of the CFEAD’s assistance to their success. Also we worked out recommendations for optimizing preferential regimes and development institutions activities, which are acceptable both for the regions of the Far Eastern Federal District and in the all-Russian context.
研究的目的是以远东地区为例,评估优惠制度对当地社会经济发展的影响。我们既使用定量方法(如回归和相关分析、建模、平均法、指数法、"差异中的差异"、因素分析),也使用定性方法(文件分析、案例研究、基准、分类)。建立优惠制度是远东发展政策的关键要素,如先进发展区、符拉迪沃斯托克自由港、俄罗斯联邦北极区等。为了管理这些优惠制度,成立了一个名为远东和北极发展公司(CFEAD)的发展机构。我们对远东地区优惠制度运作和社会经济发展的指标进行了评估。我们确定了这些制度对经济增长产生积极影响的地区,并估算了远东和北极开发公司(CFEAD)对这些地区的成功援助程度。此外,我们还提出了优化优惠制度和发展机构活动的建议,这些建议对远东联邦区和全俄都是可以接受的。
{"title":"Influence of preferential regimes on the Russian Far East development","authors":"G. Borshchevskiy","doi":"10.32609/0042-8736-2024-2-103-124","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.32609/0042-8736-2024-2-103-124","url":null,"abstract":"The purpose of the study is to assess the impact of preferential regimes on the socio-economic development of territories on the example of the Far Eastern regions. We use both quantitative (e.g. regression and correlation analysis, modeling, method of averages, index method, “difference in differences”, factor analysis) and qualitative methods (document analysis, case-study, benchmarking, classification). The creation of preferential regimes, such as the Territory of Advanced Development, Free Port of Vladivostok, Arctic Zone of the Russian Federation, was a key element of the Far East development policy. To manage these preferential regimes a development institution has been created named Corporation for the Far East and the Arctic Development (CFEAD). We carried out the evaluation of the indicators of preferential regimes functioning and the socio-economic development of the Far Eastern regions. We identified the regions where these regimes have a positive impact on economic growth, and estimated the degree of the CFEAD’s assistance to their success. Also we worked out recommendations for optimizing preferential regimes and development institutions activities, which are acceptable both for the regions of the Far Eastern Federal District and in the all-Russian context.","PeriodicalId":45534,"journal":{"name":"Voprosy Ekonomiki","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.8,"publicationDate":"2024-02-06","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"139858353","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
The relationship between the rate on unemployment and occupational injuries: A case of Russia 失业率与工伤之间的关系:俄罗斯案例
IF 0.8 Q1 Arts and Humanities Pub Date : 2024-02-06 DOI: 10.32609/0042-8736-2024-2-145-158
E. Zazdravnykh, T. I. Rodionova
This study aims to reveal how growth or decline in the rate of unemployment determines occupational injuries in Russia. Based on the regional statistics from 2009 to 2021 with the help of linear panel models we estimate the relationship between the rate of unemployment and fatal or non-fatal occupational injuries rates. The results show that when the economy is decreasing employees or employers prefer to underreport workplace accidents. This effect is especially strong in conditions of rising unemployment due to the release of workers, layoffs or liquidation of enterprises. At the same time, the fluctuations of unemployment do not change the fatal accidents; that is, injuries per se do not have a cyclical behavior. Thus, though there is a decreasing trend in the rate of occupational injuries in Russia, there is a problem of underreporting of accidents as we observe in high-income economies.
本研究旨在揭示失业率的增减如何决定俄罗斯的职业伤害。根据 2009 年至 2021 年的地区统计数据,在线性面板模型的帮助下,我们估算了失业率与致命或非致命工伤率之间的关系。结果显示,当经济下滑时,雇员或雇主更愿意少报工伤事故。这种效应在因工人下岗、裁员或企业清算而导致失业率上升的情况下尤为明显。同时,失业率的波动并不会改变致命事故的发生,也就是说,工伤事故本身并不具有周期性。因此,尽管俄罗斯的工伤事故率呈下降趋势,但与高收入经济体一样,也存在事故报告不足的问题。
{"title":"The relationship between the rate on unemployment and occupational injuries: A case of Russia","authors":"E. Zazdravnykh, T. I. Rodionova","doi":"10.32609/0042-8736-2024-2-145-158","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.32609/0042-8736-2024-2-145-158","url":null,"abstract":"This study aims to reveal how growth or decline in the rate of unemployment determines occupational injuries in Russia. Based on the regional statistics from 2009 to 2021 with the help of linear panel models we estimate the relationship between the rate of unemployment and fatal or non-fatal occupational injuries rates. The results show that when the economy is decreasing employees or employers prefer to underreport workplace accidents. This effect is especially strong in conditions of rising unemployment due to the release of workers, layoffs or liquidation of enterprises. At the same time, the fluctuations of unemployment do not change the fatal accidents; that is, injuries per se do not have a cyclical behavior. Thus, though there is a decreasing trend in the rate of occupational injuries in Russia, there is a problem of underreporting of accidents as we observe in high-income economies.","PeriodicalId":45534,"journal":{"name":"Voprosy Ekonomiki","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.8,"publicationDate":"2024-02-06","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"139858844","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Walras and Tugan-Baranovsky on socialism: Reconciling economic science and social ideal 瓦尔拉斯和图甘-巴拉诺夫斯基论社会主义:协调经济科学与社会理想
IF 0.8 Q1 Arts and Humanities Pub Date : 2024-02-06 DOI: 10.32609/0042-8736-2024-2-49-66
N. A. Makasheva
Nowadays, Leon Walras (1839—1910) is well-known first and foremost for his “Elements of pure political economy, or the theory of public wealth” (1874, 1877) and Mikhail Ivanovich Tugan-Baranovsky (1865—1919) gained a wide recognition due to his book “Industrial crises in contemporary England: Their causes and influences on the life of the people” (1894), which had a significant impact on the development of economics. At the same time, both economists were deeply concerned not only with theoretical problems, but also with those that are now considered beyond the scope of theory, the problem of social ideal and that of a more just social system being among them. Walras and Tugan-Baranovsky associated the embodiment of the social ideal with socialism and strived for an economic system that corresponded to that ideal, albeit their conceptions of socialism being different. The principal opportunity to achieve reconciliation between science and ideal was associated with a synthetic approach reconciling the scientific method and ideal, economics being considered “a bridge” between them, or a «testing ground», where the reconciliation was to take place. Although history has shown that Walras’s and Tugan-Baranovsky’s ideas of socialism were utopian, the very fact that two eminent economists were deeply concerned with the problem of social ideal and socialism at a time when the foundations of modern economics were being laid, shows that the striving of economists to create objective and rigorous science was, to a measure, driven by their aspiration to solve the social problem and to set up a social and economic system which is rational and more just than the existing one
如今,莱昂-瓦尔拉斯(1839-1910 年)首先因其《纯政治经济学要素或公共财富理论》(1874 年,1877 年)而闻名于世,米哈伊尔-伊万诺维奇-图甘-巴拉诺夫斯基(1865-1919 年)则因其《当代英国的工业危机》(1894 年)一书而广为人知:该书对经济学的发展产生了重大影响。同时,这两位经济学家不仅对理论问题深表关注,而且对那些现在被认为超出理论范畴的问题也深表关注,其中包括社会理想问题和更公正的社会制度问题。瓦尔拉斯和图甘-巴拉诺夫斯基将社会理想的体现与社会主义联系在一起,并努力寻求一种符合这一理想的经济制度,尽管他们对社会主义的概念有所不同。在科学与理想之间实现协调的主要机会是采用一种协调科学方法与理想的综合方法,经济学被认为是两者之间的 "桥梁 "或 "试验场",在这里可以实现协调。尽管历史证明瓦尔拉斯和图甘-巴拉诺夫斯基的社会主义思想是乌托邦式的,但在现代经济学奠基之时,两位著名经济学家对社会理想和社会主义问题的深切关注这一事实本身就表明,经济学家努力创造客观、严谨的科学,在一定程度上是出于解决社会问题、建立比现有制度更合理、更公正的社会经济制度的愿望。
{"title":"Walras and Tugan-Baranovsky on socialism: Reconciling economic science and social ideal","authors":"N. A. Makasheva","doi":"10.32609/0042-8736-2024-2-49-66","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.32609/0042-8736-2024-2-49-66","url":null,"abstract":"Nowadays, Leon Walras (1839—1910) is well-known first and foremost for his “Elements of pure political economy, or the theory of public wealth” (1874, 1877) and Mikhail Ivanovich Tugan-Baranovsky (1865—1919) gained a wide recognition due to his book “Industrial crises in contemporary England: Their causes and influences on the life of the people” (1894), which had a significant impact on the development of economics. At the same time, both economists were deeply concerned not only with theoretical problems, but also with those that are now considered beyond the scope of theory, the problem of social ideal and that of a more just social system being among them. Walras and Tugan-Baranovsky associated the embodiment of the social ideal with socialism and strived for an economic system that corresponded to that ideal, albeit their conceptions of socialism being different. The principal opportunity to achieve reconciliation between science and ideal was associated with a synthetic approach reconciling the scientific method and ideal, economics being considered “a bridge” between them, or a «testing ground», where the reconciliation was to take place. Although history has shown that Walras’s and Tugan-Baranovsky’s ideas of socialism were utopian, the very fact that two eminent economists were deeply concerned with the problem of social ideal and socialism at a time when the foundations of modern economics were being laid, shows that the striving of economists to create objective and rigorous science was, to a measure, driven by their aspiration to solve the social problem and to set up a social and economic system which is rational and more just than the existing one","PeriodicalId":45534,"journal":{"name":"Voprosy Ekonomiki","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.8,"publicationDate":"2024-02-06","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"139801455","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
State regulation of negative infrastructure-related externalities in the system of land relations 国家对土地关系体系中与基础设施相关的负外部性的监管
IF 0.8 Q1 Arts and Humanities Pub Date : 2024-02-06 DOI: 10.32609/0042-8736-2024-2-125-144
E. N. Bykova
The subject of the study is the system of land relations in Russia, the imperfection of which gives rise to negative infrastructural externalities caused by the modernization and development of linear engineering infrastructure The objective of the work is to develop methods for state regulation of the external effects, the main one of which is internalization through land taxation. In the work the concept of “negative infrastructure-related externalities”, their structure and economic nature in land relations are introduced. Also the consequences of negative infrastructure-related externalities on the economic interests of owners of encumbered land plots are determined. To overcome those issues the economic mechanism for regulating the use of land resources and their redistribution is developed. The scope of application of research results covers a lot of long-term aims: from the differentiation of land taxation for the internalization of negative infrastructure-related externalities to territorial planning at all levels.
研究的主题是俄罗斯的土地关系体系,该体系的不完善导致了线性工程基础设施的现代化和发展所引起的负面基础设施外部效应。工作中介绍了 "与基础设施相关的负面外部效应 "的概念、其结构以及在土地关系中的经济性质。此外,还确定了与基础设施相关的负外部性对抵押地块所有者经济利益的影响。为解决这些问题,制定了调节土地资源使用及其再分配的经济机制。研究成果的应用范围涵盖了许多长期目标:从土地税收的差异化以实现与基础设施相关的负面外部效应的内部化,到各级领土规划。
{"title":"State regulation of negative infrastructure-related externalities in the system of land relations","authors":"E. N. Bykova","doi":"10.32609/0042-8736-2024-2-125-144","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.32609/0042-8736-2024-2-125-144","url":null,"abstract":"The subject of the study is the system of land relations in Russia, the imperfection of which gives rise to negative infrastructural externalities caused by the modernization and development of linear engineering infrastructure The objective of the work is to develop methods for state regulation of the external effects, the main one of which is internalization through land taxation. In the work the concept of “negative infrastructure-related externalities”, their structure and economic nature in land relations are introduced. Also the consequences of negative infrastructure-related externalities on the economic interests of owners of encumbered land plots are determined. To overcome those issues the economic mechanism for regulating the use of land resources and their redistribution is developed. The scope of application of research results covers a lot of long-term aims: from the differentiation of land taxation for the internalization of negative infrastructure-related externalities to territorial planning at all levels.","PeriodicalId":45534,"journal":{"name":"Voprosy Ekonomiki","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.8,"publicationDate":"2024-02-06","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"139798968","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
High risks and weak pace of economic growth: Russia macroeconomic forecast for the medium term 高风险和经济增长乏力:俄罗斯中期宏观经济预测
IF 0.8 Q1 Arts and Humanities Pub Date : 2024-02-06 DOI: 10.32609/0042-8736-2024-2-5-22
A. L. Vedev, V. A. Eremkin, K. A. Tuzov
This paper examines prospects for the Russian economy in the mid-term until 2026. The authors identify four key factors that determine future dynamics: sanctions, the state of foreign trade, relations between Russian and foreign businesses, policy of the government and the Bank of Russia. The basic scenario of our forecast is based on the most probable future trends in development of foreign trade, investment activity, industrial dynamics, changes in exchange rate of the national currency, inflationary picture and monetary policy. The conservative scenario takes into account the manifestation of some negative risks, probability of which the authors consider as quite high. For both scenarios, the authors offer a list of risks that can have a significant impact on the forecast values. Results of modeling economic dynamics indicate that in the medium-term Russia will face moderate recovery growth, and there will be no real opportunities to accelerate it. By the end of 2026, the Russian economy will increase in the range of 5.6—7.8% compared to the level of 2021. The results of the presented work can be used for a critical comparison with official forecasts of the Bank of Russia and the Ministry of Economic Development of the Russian Federation in order to improve the efficiency of budget planning for future periods.
本文探讨了 2026 年之前俄罗斯经济的中期前景。作者指出了决定未来动态的四个关键因素:制裁、外贸状况、俄罗斯与外国企业之间的关系、政府和俄罗斯银行的政策。我们预测的基本方案是基于外贸发展、投资活动、工业动态、本国货币汇率变化、通货膨胀情况和货币政策等未来最可能的趋势。保守方案考虑到了一些负面风险的表现,作者认为这些风险的概率相当高。对于这两种方案,作者都列出了可能对预测值产生重大影响的风险清单。经济动态建模结果表明,在中期内,俄罗斯将面临温和的恢复性增长,并且没有真正的机会加快增长速度。到 2026 年底,俄罗斯经济将比 2021 年增长 5.6-7.8%。本研究成果可用于与俄罗斯银行和俄罗斯联邦经济发展部的官方预测进行重要比较,以提高未来预算规划的效率。
{"title":"High risks and weak pace of economic growth: Russia macroeconomic forecast for the medium term","authors":"A. L. Vedev, V. A. Eremkin, K. A. Tuzov","doi":"10.32609/0042-8736-2024-2-5-22","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.32609/0042-8736-2024-2-5-22","url":null,"abstract":"This paper examines prospects for the Russian economy in the mid-term until 2026. The authors identify four key factors that determine future dynamics: sanctions, the state of foreign trade, relations between Russian and foreign businesses, policy of the government and the Bank of Russia. The basic scenario of our forecast is based on the most probable future trends in development of foreign trade, investment activity, industrial dynamics, changes in exchange rate of the national currency, inflationary picture and monetary policy. The conservative scenario takes into account the manifestation of some negative risks, probability of which the authors consider as quite high. For both scenarios, the authors offer a list of risks that can have a significant impact on the forecast values. Results of modeling economic dynamics indicate that in the medium-term Russia will face moderate recovery growth, and there will be no real opportunities to accelerate it. By the end of 2026, the Russian economy will increase in the range of 5.6—7.8% compared to the level of 2021. The results of the presented work can be used for a critical comparison with official forecasts of the Bank of Russia and the Ministry of Economic Development of the Russian Federation in order to improve the efficiency of budget planning for future periods.","PeriodicalId":45534,"journal":{"name":"Voprosy Ekonomiki","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.8,"publicationDate":"2024-02-06","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"139798924","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Macroeconomic forecasting and macroeconomic forecasts 宏观经济预测和宏观经济预报
IF 0.8 Q1 Arts and Humanities Pub Date : 2024-02-06 DOI: 10.32609/0042-8736-2024-2-23-48
S. V. Smirnov, N. V. Kondrashov, A. S. Kachur
The specificity of macroeconomic forecasts is determined not so much by the list of predicted indicators or by mathematical tools used, but by the unavoidable human factor, which often generates great difference between forecasts made by various professionals. In Russian-language literature, this psychological aspect of macroeconomic forecasting has not received any attention; our work is designed to fill this gap. As a source of statistical data we used the forecasts extracted from the quarterly Poll of Professional Forecasters (PPF), which began in the first quarter of 2000. An analysis of real GDP and CPI forecasts made it possible to identify optimists and pessimists among independent experts, and also to show that the official forecasts by the Russian Ministry of Economic Development and the Bank of Russia are often too optimistic (with the possible exception of forecasts for a current year). It was also confirmed that the accuracy of consensus-forecasts exceeds (in the long run) not only that of official forecasts, but also forecasts made by the vast majority of independent experts. This asserts consensus-forecasts as a benchmark against which macroeconomic forecasts of other experts and organizations should be compared. An analysis of errors for different forecast horizons showed that in the medium term, the most significant ones are associated with underestimation of the resilience of the Russian economy to external shocks. This aspect of macroeconomic forecasting is closely related to forecasting cyclical dynamics (in particular, recessions, their beginning, depth and duration). Currently, this is just what requires additional attention by macroeconomic forecasters.
宏观经济预测的特殊性与其说是由预测指标清单或所使用的数学工具决定的,不如说是由不可避免的人为因素决定的。在俄语文献中,宏观经济预测的心理因素尚未得到关注;我们的工作旨在填补这一空白。作为统计数据来源,我们使用了从专业预测人员季度民意调查(PPF)中提取的预测数据,该调查始于 2000 年第一季度。通过对实际 GDP 和 CPI 预测的分析,我们发现了独立专家中的乐观主义者和悲观主义者,同时也表明俄罗斯经济发展部和俄罗斯银行的官方预测往往过于乐观(对当年的预测可能例外)。研究还证实,共识预测的准确性(从长远来看)不仅超过了官方预测,也超过了绝大多数独立专家的预测。这就证明了共识预测是一个基准,其他专家和组织的宏观经济预测应与之进行比较。对不同预测期误差的分析表明,从中期来看,最大的误差与低估俄罗斯经济对外部冲击的承受力有关。宏观经济预测的这一方面与周期性动态预测(特别是衰退、衰退的开始、深度和持续时间)密切相关。目前,这正是宏观经济预测人员需要额外关注的问题。
{"title":"Macroeconomic forecasting and macroeconomic forecasts","authors":"S. V. Smirnov, N. V. Kondrashov, A. S. Kachur","doi":"10.32609/0042-8736-2024-2-23-48","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.32609/0042-8736-2024-2-23-48","url":null,"abstract":"The specificity of macroeconomic forecasts is determined not so much by the list of predicted indicators or by mathematical tools used, but by the unavoidable human factor, which often generates great difference between forecasts made by various professionals. In Russian-language literature, this psychological aspect of macroeconomic forecasting has not received any attention; our work is designed to fill this gap. As a source of statistical data we used the forecasts extracted from the quarterly Poll of Professional Forecasters (PPF), which began in the first quarter of 2000. An analysis of real GDP and CPI forecasts made it possible to identify optimists and pessimists among independent experts, and also to show that the official forecasts by the Russian Ministry of Economic Development and the Bank of Russia are often too optimistic (with the possible exception of forecasts for a current year). It was also confirmed that the accuracy of consensus-forecasts exceeds (in the long run) not only that of official forecasts, but also forecasts made by the vast majority of independent experts. This asserts consensus-forecasts as a benchmark against which macroeconomic forecasts of other experts and organizations should be compared. An analysis of errors for different forecast horizons showed that in the medium term, the most significant ones are associated with underestimation of the resilience of the Russian economy to external shocks. This aspect of macroeconomic forecasting is closely related to forecasting cyclical dynamics (in particular, recessions, their beginning, depth and duration). Currently, this is just what requires additional attention by macroeconomic forecasters.","PeriodicalId":45534,"journal":{"name":"Voprosy Ekonomiki","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.8,"publicationDate":"2024-02-06","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"139798542","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
The Second Leontief Paradox: Economic Theory or Economic Engineering? 第二个列昂惕夫悖论:经济理论还是经济工程?
IF 0.8 Q1 Arts and Humanities Pub Date : 2024-02-06 DOI: 10.32609/0042-8736-2024-2-84-102
U. A. Parkhimenka
The article analyzes the situation, conventionally called the "Second Leontief Paradox", when a recognized scientist, Nobel laureate and undisputed authority in the academic environment, it turns out, has practically no place in modern economic theory - neither within the "mainstream" nor in unorthodox directions. This paradox is considered in the context of four questions: (1) does Leontief have a “theory” at all; (2) to which theoretical school Leontief belongs or at least gravitates; (3) what is the main factor in the formation of the paradox under consideration; (4) what are the prospects for Leontief's approach in macroeconomics. To understand this paradox, it is proposed to use the terms introduced by G. Mankiw - an economist as a scientist and an economist as an engineer. It is concluded that there is still a gap between "theory" and "engineering" in economics. It is assumed that such a gap, including in connection with the rapid growth of a large amount of economic data and universal digitalization, may gradually decrease.
文章分析了被称为 "第二个列昂惕夫悖论 "的情况,即一位公认的科学家、诺贝尔奖获得者和学术界无可争议的权威,竟然在现代经济理论中几乎没有一席之地--既不属于 "主流",也不属于非正统的方向。我们将从以下四个问题来探讨这一悖论:(1) 列昂惕夫到底有没有 "理论";(2) 列昂惕夫属于或至少倾向于哪个理论流派;(3) 形成当前悖论的主要因素是什么;(4) 列昂惕夫的方法在宏观经济学中的前景如何。为了理解这一悖论,建议使用 G. Mankiw 提出的术语--作为科学家的经济学家和作为工程师的经济学家。结论是,经济学中的 "理论 "与 "工程 "之间仍然存在差距。我们认为,随着大量经济数据的快速增长和数字化的普及,这种差距可能会逐渐缩小。
{"title":"The Second Leontief Paradox: Economic Theory or Economic Engineering?","authors":"U. A. Parkhimenka","doi":"10.32609/0042-8736-2024-2-84-102","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.32609/0042-8736-2024-2-84-102","url":null,"abstract":"The article analyzes the situation, conventionally called the \"Second Leontief Paradox\", when a recognized scientist, Nobel laureate and undisputed authority in the academic environment, it turns out, has practically no place in modern economic theory - neither within the \"mainstream\" nor in unorthodox directions. This paradox is considered in the context of four questions: (1) does Leontief have a “theory” at all; (2) to which theoretical school Leontief belongs or at least gravitates; (3) what is the main factor in the formation of the paradox under consideration; (4) what are the prospects for Leontief's approach in macroeconomics. To understand this paradox, it is proposed to use the terms introduced by G. Mankiw - an economist as a scientist and an economist as an engineer. It is concluded that there is still a gap between \"theory\" and \"engineering\" in economics. It is assumed that such a gap, including in connection with the rapid growth of a large amount of economic data and universal digitalization, may gradually decrease.","PeriodicalId":45534,"journal":{"name":"Voprosy Ekonomiki","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.8,"publicationDate":"2024-02-06","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"139798584","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
The Second Leontief Paradox: Economic Theory or Economic Engineering? 第二个列昂惕夫悖论:经济理论还是经济工程?
IF 0.8 Q1 Arts and Humanities Pub Date : 2024-02-06 DOI: 10.32609/0042-8736-2024-2-84-102
U. A. Parkhimenka
The article analyzes the situation, conventionally called the "Second Leontief Paradox", when a recognized scientist, Nobel laureate and undisputed authority in the academic environment, it turns out, has practically no place in modern economic theory - neither within the "mainstream" nor in unorthodox directions. This paradox is considered in the context of four questions: (1) does Leontief have a “theory” at all; (2) to which theoretical school Leontief belongs or at least gravitates; (3) what is the main factor in the formation of the paradox under consideration; (4) what are the prospects for Leontief's approach in macroeconomics. To understand this paradox, it is proposed to use the terms introduced by G. Mankiw - an economist as a scientist and an economist as an engineer. It is concluded that there is still a gap between "theory" and "engineering" in economics. It is assumed that such a gap, including in connection with the rapid growth of a large amount of economic data and universal digitalization, may gradually decrease.
文章分析了被称为 "第二个列昂惕夫悖论 "的情况,即一位公认的科学家、诺贝尔奖获得者和学术界无可争议的权威,竟然在现代经济理论中几乎没有一席之地--既不属于 "主流",也不属于非正统的方向。我们将从以下四个问题来探讨这一悖论:(1) 列昂惕夫到底有没有 "理论";(2) 列昂惕夫属于或至少倾向于哪个理论流派;(3) 形成当前悖论的主要因素是什么;(4) 列昂惕夫的方法在宏观经济学中的前景如何。为了理解这一悖论,建议使用 G. Mankiw 提出的术语--作为科学家的经济学家和作为工程师的经济学家。结论是,经济学中的 "理论 "与 "工程 "之间仍然存在差距。我们认为,随着大量经济数据的快速增长和数字化的普及,这种差距可能会逐渐缩小。
{"title":"The Second Leontief Paradox: Economic Theory or Economic Engineering?","authors":"U. A. Parkhimenka","doi":"10.32609/0042-8736-2024-2-84-102","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.32609/0042-8736-2024-2-84-102","url":null,"abstract":"The article analyzes the situation, conventionally called the \"Second Leontief Paradox\", when a recognized scientist, Nobel laureate and undisputed authority in the academic environment, it turns out, has practically no place in modern economic theory - neither within the \"mainstream\" nor in unorthodox directions. This paradox is considered in the context of four questions: (1) does Leontief have a “theory” at all; (2) to which theoretical school Leontief belongs or at least gravitates; (3) what is the main factor in the formation of the paradox under consideration; (4) what are the prospects for Leontief's approach in macroeconomics. To understand this paradox, it is proposed to use the terms introduced by G. Mankiw - an economist as a scientist and an economist as an engineer. It is concluded that there is still a gap between \"theory\" and \"engineering\" in economics. It is assumed that such a gap, including in connection with the rapid growth of a large amount of economic data and universal digitalization, may gradually decrease.","PeriodicalId":45534,"journal":{"name":"Voprosy Ekonomiki","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.8,"publicationDate":"2024-02-06","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"139858346","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Knowledge-based view of the firm and the phenomenon of knowledge encapsulation 基于知识的企业观和知识封装现象
IF 0.8 Q1 Arts and Humanities Pub Date : 2024-01-07 DOI: 10.32609/0042-8736-2024-1-115-136
V. Maltsev, A. Yudanov
The article is devoted to the development of the knowledge-based approach to the theory of the firm (KBV). It is noted that the modern mainstream KBV (R. Grant (1996) and numerous followers) sees the nature of the firm in effective integration of the knowledge of specialists employed in it. The article proposes to supplement this analysis with the second important function of the firm — its role as an encapsulator of knowledge. The foundations of such an approach to knowledge were laid by H. Demsetz, but have not yet been developed in the literature. The essence of encapsulation is to reduce complete knowledge to an algorithm of actions sufficient to achieve the goal, which is possible, say, with the help of instructions, directions of the manager, built in constructive “foolproofing”, etc. The compiler of the instruction does not integrate his knowledge with the knowledge of its performer, but prescribes the unquestioned implementation of the algorithm of behaviour. Thus, huge cost savings are achieved on the training of performers. The article considers the limiting case — the scheme of the firm functioning as a pure encapsulator of knowledge, the Markov property of the process is substantiated. The role of the entrepreneur as an architect and manager of the knowledge encapsulation scheme is revealed. At the same time, significant negative aspects of production based on the widespread use of encapsulated (incomplete — you do what you do not understand) knowledge are analyzed. In particular, the non-creative nature of labour in the encapsulationbased firm (a particular manifestation of which is the slow spread of horizontally organized or teal firms) and the threat of disqualification of performers when combining encapsulation with artificial intelligence are discussed
这篇文章专门论述了以知识为基础的企业理论(KBV)方法的发展。文章指出,现代主流知识型企业理论(R. Grant (1996) 及其众多追随者)认为,企业的本质在于有效整合企业中雇用的专家的知识。本文建议用企业的第二个重要功能--作为知识的封装者--来补充这一分析。德姆塞茨(H. Demsetz)为这种知识方法奠定了基础,但尚未在文献中得到发展。封装的本质是将完整的知识还原为足以实现目标的行动算法,例如,借助指令、管理者的指示、内置的建设性 "傻瓜化 "等来实现。指令的编制者并不将自己的知识与执行者的知识结合起来,而是规定毫无疑问地执行行为算法。因此,在培训表演者方面节省了大量成本。文章考虑了极限情况--公司作为知识的纯粹封装者的计划,证实了该过程的马尔可夫特性。文章揭示了企业家作为知识封装计划的设计者和管理者的作用。同时,还分析了在广泛使用封装知识(不完整--你做你不了解的事)的基础上进行生产的重大负面影响。特别是,讨论了在基于封装的公司中劳动的非创造性(其具体表现是横向组织或茶色公司的传播缓慢),以及在将封装与人工智能相结合时,执行者被取消资格的威胁。
{"title":"Knowledge-based view of the firm and the phenomenon of knowledge encapsulation","authors":"V. Maltsev, A. Yudanov","doi":"10.32609/0042-8736-2024-1-115-136","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.32609/0042-8736-2024-1-115-136","url":null,"abstract":"The article is devoted to the development of the knowledge-based approach to the theory of the firm (KBV). It is noted that the modern mainstream KBV (R. Grant (1996) and numerous followers) sees the nature of the firm in effective integration of the knowledge of specialists employed in it. The article proposes to supplement this analysis with the second important function of the firm — its role as an encapsulator of knowledge. The foundations of such an approach to knowledge were laid by H. Demsetz, but have not yet been developed in the literature. The essence of encapsulation is to reduce complete knowledge to an algorithm of actions sufficient to achieve the goal, which is possible, say, with the help of instructions, directions of the manager, built in constructive “foolproofing”, etc. The compiler of the instruction does not integrate his knowledge with the knowledge of its performer, but prescribes the unquestioned implementation of the algorithm of behaviour. Thus, huge cost savings are achieved on the training of performers. The article considers the limiting case — the scheme of the firm functioning as a pure encapsulator of knowledge, the Markov property of the process is substantiated. The role of the entrepreneur as an architect and manager of the knowledge encapsulation scheme is revealed. At the same time, significant negative aspects of production based on the widespread use of encapsulated (incomplete — you do what you do not understand) knowledge are analyzed. In particular, the non-creative nature of labour in the encapsulationbased firm (a particular manifestation of which is the slow spread of horizontally organized or teal firms) and the threat of disqualification of performers when combining encapsulation with artificial intelligence are discussed","PeriodicalId":45534,"journal":{"name":"Voprosy Ekonomiki","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.8,"publicationDate":"2024-01-07","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"139448521","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
期刊
Voprosy Ekonomiki
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1