首页 > 最新文献

Service Science最新文献

英文 中文
Exploring Customer Citizenship Behavior Through Customer–Organization Identification 透过顾客-组织认同探讨顾客公民行为
IF 2.3 4区 管理学 Q2 Business, Management and Accounting Pub Date : 2023-07-10 DOI: 10.1287/serv.2021.0051
Lishan Xie, Wenxuan Zhang, Xinhua Guan, T. Huan
This paper aims to investigate the influence of customer–organization identification from a customer–employee relationship perspective. Specifically, this paper examines the mediating effects of the customer–employee identification and customer–employee trust between the relationship between customer–organization identification and customer citizenship behavior. Based on social identity theory, this paper builds a research framework that is empirically tested using a sample of 465 patients or their families from one of the largest high-level hospitals in China. Structural equation modeling and a bootstrapping method were adopted to test the model and the mediation effects. Results of data analysis reveal that customer–organization identification has a direct positive influence on customer citizenship behavior, and customer–employee identification and customer–employee trust have positive mediation effects between customer–organization identification and customer citizenship behavior. Funding: This study was supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China [Grant 71772186 to L. Xie and Grant 71802052 to X. Guan].
本文旨在从顾客-员工关系的角度研究顾客-组织认同的影响。具体而言,本文考察了顾客-员工认同和顾客-员工信任在顾客-组织认同与顾客公民行为关系中的中介作用。基于社会认同理论,本文构建了一个研究框架,并以中国最大的一家高水平医院的465名患者或家属为样本进行了实证检验。采用结构方程模型和自举方法对模型和中介效应进行检验。数据分析结果表明,顾客-组织认同对顾客公民行为具有直接的正向影响,顾客-员工认同和顾客-员工信任在顾客-组织认同与顾客公民行为之间具有正向中介作用。基金资助:本研究由国家自然科学基金资助[基金资助:71772186 to L. Xie;基金资助:71802052 to X. Guan]。
{"title":"Exploring Customer Citizenship Behavior Through Customer–Organization Identification","authors":"Lishan Xie, Wenxuan Zhang, Xinhua Guan, T. Huan","doi":"10.1287/serv.2021.0051","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1287/serv.2021.0051","url":null,"abstract":"This paper aims to investigate the influence of customer–organization identification from a customer–employee relationship perspective. Specifically, this paper examines the mediating effects of the customer–employee identification and customer–employee trust between the relationship between customer–organization identification and customer citizenship behavior. Based on social identity theory, this paper builds a research framework that is empirically tested using a sample of 465 patients or their families from one of the largest high-level hospitals in China. Structural equation modeling and a bootstrapping method were adopted to test the model and the mediation effects. Results of data analysis reveal that customer–organization identification has a direct positive influence on customer citizenship behavior, and customer–employee identification and customer–employee trust have positive mediation effects between customer–organization identification and customer citizenship behavior. Funding: This study was supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China [Grant 71772186 to L. Xie and Grant 71802052 to X. Guan].","PeriodicalId":46249,"journal":{"name":"Service Science","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":2.3,"publicationDate":"2023-07-10","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"75707491","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"管理学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Service Science Editorial Board, 2023 服务科学编委会,2023
4区 管理学 Q2 Business, Management and Accounting Pub Date : 2023-06-01 DOI: 10.1287/serv.2023.eb.v15.n2
{"title":"<i>Service Science</i> Editorial Board, 2023","authors":"","doi":"10.1287/serv.2023.eb.v15.n2","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1287/serv.2023.eb.v15.n2","url":null,"abstract":"","PeriodicalId":46249,"journal":{"name":"Service Science","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2023-06-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"136107828","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"管理学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Frontiers in Service Science: Data-Driven Revenue Management: The Interplay of Data, Model, and Decisions 服务科学前沿:数据驱动的收益管理:数据、模型和决策的相互作用
4区 管理学 Q2 Business, Management and Accounting Pub Date : 2023-06-01 DOI: 10.1287/serv.2023.0322
Ningyuan Chen, Ming Hu
Revenue management (RM) is the application of analytical methodologies and tools that predict consumer behavior and optimize product availability and prices to maximize a firm’s revenue or profit. In the last decade, data has been playing an increasingly crucial role in business decision making. As firms rely more on collected or acquired data to make business decisions, it brings opportunities and challenges to the RM research community. In this review paper, we systematically categorize the related literature by how a study is “driven” by data and focus on studies that explore the interplay between two or three of the elements: data, model, and decisions, in which the data element must be present. Specifically, we cover five data-driven RM research areas, including inference (data to model), predict then optimize (data to model to decisions), online learning (data to model to decisions to new data in a loop), end-to-end decision making (data directly to decisions), and experimental design (decisions to data to model). Finally, we point out future research directions. Funding: The research of N. Chen is partly supported by Natural Sciences and Engineering Research Council of Canada Discovery [Grant RGPIN-2020-04038]. The research of M. Hu is in part supported by Natural Sciences and Engineering Research Council of Canada [Grant RGPIN-2021-04295].
收益管理(RM)是分析方法和工具的应用,预测消费者行为,优化产品的可用性和价格,以最大限度地提高公司的收入或利润。在过去的十年中,数据在商业决策中扮演着越来越重要的角色。由于企业更多地依赖于收集或获得的数据来做出商业决策,这给RM研究界带来了机遇和挑战。在这篇综述文章中,我们根据研究如何被数据“驱动”来系统地对相关文献进行分类,并将重点放在探索两个或三个要素之间相互作用的研究上:数据、模型和决策,其中数据要素必须存在。具体来说,我们涵盖了五个数据驱动的RM研究领域,包括推理(数据到模型),预测然后优化(数据到模型到决策),在线学习(数据到模型到决策到循环中的新数据),端到端决策(数据直接到决策)和实验设计(决策到数据到模型)。最后,提出了今后的研究方向。项目资助:陈n .的部分研究得到了加拿大自然科学与工程研究委员会的资助[Grant RGPIN-2020-04038]。胡先生的研究得到了加拿大自然科学与工程研究委员会的部分支持[Grant RGPIN-2021-04295]。
{"title":"Frontiers in Service Science: Data-Driven Revenue Management: The Interplay of Data, Model, and Decisions","authors":"Ningyuan Chen, Ming Hu","doi":"10.1287/serv.2023.0322","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1287/serv.2023.0322","url":null,"abstract":"Revenue management (RM) is the application of analytical methodologies and tools that predict consumer behavior and optimize product availability and prices to maximize a firm’s revenue or profit. In the last decade, data has been playing an increasingly crucial role in business decision making. As firms rely more on collected or acquired data to make business decisions, it brings opportunities and challenges to the RM research community. In this review paper, we systematically categorize the related literature by how a study is “driven” by data and focus on studies that explore the interplay between two or three of the elements: data, model, and decisions, in which the data element must be present. Specifically, we cover five data-driven RM research areas, including inference (data to model), predict then optimize (data to model to decisions), online learning (data to model to decisions to new data in a loop), end-to-end decision making (data directly to decisions), and experimental design (decisions to data to model). Finally, we point out future research directions. Funding: The research of N. Chen is partly supported by Natural Sciences and Engineering Research Council of Canada Discovery [Grant RGPIN-2020-04038]. The research of M. Hu is in part supported by Natural Sciences and Engineering Research Council of Canada [Grant RGPIN-2021-04295].","PeriodicalId":46249,"journal":{"name":"Service Science","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2023-06-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"135006081","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"管理学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Competitive Bundling and Offer Design in a Symmetric Bertrand Duopoly 对称Bertrand双寡头下的竞争捆绑与报价设计
IF 2.3 4区 管理学 Q2 Business, Management and Accounting Pub Date : 2023-05-31 DOI: 10.1287/serv.2023.0325
G. Roels, Araz Khodabakhshian, U. Karmarkar
How should digital service firms design and bundle their offering to capture a large market while seeking differentiation from competition? To answer this question, we consider the most generic model of competition, namely, two symmetric firms competing on price with regard to two (independent or complementary) components with an arbitrary distribution of valuations, without restrictions on their product offering. We show that three outcomes emerge in equilibrium, namely, a full-mixed bundling monopoly, a full-mixed bundling competitive duopoly leading to a price war, and a pure or partial-mixed bundling differentiated duopoly yielding positive profits for both firms. The latter equilibrium is the most plausible because it is the only one that is both trembling-hand perfect and not payoff dominated. We demonstrate the benefits of bundling under competition, thereby explaining the online platforms’ motivation for and success in expanding their offering horizontally. Yet not all products may be offered in equilibrium to avoid direct or indirect competition; hence, competition may lead to a narrower range of products available than a monopoly. Is bundling anticompetitive? It is a double-edged sword. On the one hand, it softens price competition by allowing firms to differentiate their offering. On the other hand, it stimulates competition by creating some product overlap.
数字服务公司应该如何设计和捆绑他们的产品,以占领一个巨大的市场,同时寻求从竞争中脱颖而出?为了回答这个问题,我们考虑了最通用的竞争模型,即两个对称的公司在价格上竞争两个(独立的或互补的)组件,它们的估值分布是任意的,对它们的产品供应没有限制。在均衡状态下出现了三种结果,即完全混合捆绑垄断、导致价格战的完全混合捆绑竞争双寡头垄断和对双方都产生正利润的纯粹或部分混合捆绑差异化双寡头垄断。后一种均衡是最合理的,因为它是唯一一种既完美又不受收益支配的均衡。我们展示了在竞争下捆绑销售的好处,从而解释了在线平台横向扩展其产品的动机和成功。然而,并非所有产品都可以均衡供应,以避免直接或间接的竞争;因此,竞争可能导致可获得的产品范围比垄断更窄。捆绑销售是否反竞争?这是一把双刃剑。一方面,它允许公司区分他们的产品,从而缓和了价格竞争。另一方面,它通过创造一些产品重叠刺激了竞争。
{"title":"Competitive Bundling and Offer Design in a Symmetric Bertrand Duopoly","authors":"G. Roels, Araz Khodabakhshian, U. Karmarkar","doi":"10.1287/serv.2023.0325","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1287/serv.2023.0325","url":null,"abstract":"How should digital service firms design and bundle their offering to capture a large market while seeking differentiation from competition? To answer this question, we consider the most generic model of competition, namely, two symmetric firms competing on price with regard to two (independent or complementary) components with an arbitrary distribution of valuations, without restrictions on their product offering. We show that three outcomes emerge in equilibrium, namely, a full-mixed bundling monopoly, a full-mixed bundling competitive duopoly leading to a price war, and a pure or partial-mixed bundling differentiated duopoly yielding positive profits for both firms. The latter equilibrium is the most plausible because it is the only one that is both trembling-hand perfect and not payoff dominated. We demonstrate the benefits of bundling under competition, thereby explaining the online platforms’ motivation for and success in expanding their offering horizontally. Yet not all products may be offered in equilibrium to avoid direct or indirect competition; hence, competition may lead to a narrower range of products available than a monopoly. Is bundling anticompetitive? It is a double-edged sword. On the one hand, it softens price competition by allowing firms to differentiate their offering. On the other hand, it stimulates competition by creating some product overlap.","PeriodicalId":46249,"journal":{"name":"Service Science","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":2.3,"publicationDate":"2023-05-31","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"85985406","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"管理学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Can Third-Party Sellers Benefit from a Platform’s Entry to the Market? 第三方卖家能否从平台进入市场中受益?
4区 管理学 Q2 Business, Management and Accounting Pub Date : 2023-03-24 DOI: 10.1287/serv.2023.0324
Yiting Deng, Christopher S. Tang, Wei Wang, Onesun Steve Yoo
Because of the informational advantage of online marketplaces (i.e., platforms), it is a common belief that a platform’s market entry will be detrimental to third-party sellers who sell similar products on the platform. To examine the validity of this belief, we conduct an exploratory analysis using the sales data for a single product category provided by JD.com for the month of March 2018. Our analysis reveals an unexpected result. Upon the platform’s entry, third-party sellers who sell similar products can afford to charge a higher price, obtain a higher demand, and earn a higher profit. To provide a plausible explanation for this unexpected exploratory result, we develop a duopoly model that incorporates the changing competitive dynamic before and after the platform’s entry. Specifically, before entry, the platform earns a commission (based on the seller’s revenue), whereas the seller sets its retail price as a monopoly. After entry, the platform earns a profit generated by its direct sales in addition to the commission from the seller. In addition, the seller and the platform operate in a duopoly and engage in a sequential game. By examining the equilibrium outcomes associated with this sequential game, we identify conditions under which the platform’s entry can create a win-win situation for both parties. Specifically, these conditions hold when the platform’s market potential is moderate and when the platform’s entry creates a sufficiently high spillover effect on the seller, providing a plausible explanation for our empirical finding that the seller can benefit from a platform’s entry. Funding: W. Wang acknowledges the financial support from the National Natural Science Foundation of China [Grant 72173019], the Beijing Social Science Foundation [Grant 20JJA004], the Chinese Ministry of Education Research Funds on Humanities and Social Sciences [Grant 21YJA790056], and the Excellent Young Scholar Funds of UIBE [Grant 19YQ17].
由于在线市场(即平台)的信息优势,人们普遍认为,平台进入市场将不利于在该平台上销售类似产品的第三方卖家。为了检验这一信念的有效性,我们使用京东2018年3月提供的单一产品类别的销售数据进行了探索性分析。我们的分析揭示了一个意想不到的结果。平台进入后,销售同类产品的第三方卖家可以收取更高的价格,获得更高的需求,获得更高的利润。为了对这一意想不到的探索结果提供一个合理的解释,我们开发了一个双寡头模型,该模型包含了平台进入前后不断变化的竞争动态。具体来说,在进入之前,平台赚取佣金(基于卖家的收入),而卖家设定其零售价格作为垄断。进入后,平台除了从卖家那里获得佣金外,还获得直销产生的利润。此外,卖方和平台处于双寡头垄断状态,进行序贯博弈。通过检查与此顺序博弈相关的均衡结果,我们确定了平台进入可以为双方创造双赢局面的条件。具体来说,当平台的市场潜力适中,且平台的进入对卖家产生了足够高的溢出效应时,这些条件成立,这为我们的实证发现——卖家可以从平台的进入中受益——提供了一个合理的解释。基金资助:王伟感谢国家自然科学基金[Grant 72173019]、北京市社会科学基金[Grant 20JJA004]、教育部人文社会科学研究基金[Grant 21YJA790056]、对外经济贸易大学优秀青年学者基金[Grant 19YQ17]的资助。
{"title":"Can Third-Party Sellers Benefit from a Platform’s Entry to the Market?","authors":"Yiting Deng, Christopher S. Tang, Wei Wang, Onesun Steve Yoo","doi":"10.1287/serv.2023.0324","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1287/serv.2023.0324","url":null,"abstract":"Because of the informational advantage of online marketplaces (i.e., platforms), it is a common belief that a platform’s market entry will be detrimental to third-party sellers who sell similar products on the platform. To examine the validity of this belief, we conduct an exploratory analysis using the sales data for a single product category provided by JD.com for the month of March 2018. Our analysis reveals an unexpected result. Upon the platform’s entry, third-party sellers who sell similar products can afford to charge a higher price, obtain a higher demand, and earn a higher profit. To provide a plausible explanation for this unexpected exploratory result, we develop a duopoly model that incorporates the changing competitive dynamic before and after the platform’s entry. Specifically, before entry, the platform earns a commission (based on the seller’s revenue), whereas the seller sets its retail price as a monopoly. After entry, the platform earns a profit generated by its direct sales in addition to the commission from the seller. In addition, the seller and the platform operate in a duopoly and engage in a sequential game. By examining the equilibrium outcomes associated with this sequential game, we identify conditions under which the platform’s entry can create a win-win situation for both parties. Specifically, these conditions hold when the platform’s market potential is moderate and when the platform’s entry creates a sufficiently high spillover effect on the seller, providing a plausible explanation for our empirical finding that the seller can benefit from a platform’s entry. Funding: W. Wang acknowledges the financial support from the National Natural Science Foundation of China [Grant 72173019], the Beijing Social Science Foundation [Grant 20JJA004], the Chinese Ministry of Education Research Funds on Humanities and Social Sciences [Grant 21YJA790056], and the Excellent Young Scholar Funds of UIBE [Grant 19YQ17].","PeriodicalId":46249,"journal":{"name":"Service Science","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2023-03-24","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"136091195","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"管理学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
The Impact of Healthcare Delivery Complexity on Practices for Clinical Quality Improvement: A Case of Healthcare Workers’ Hand Hygiene Compliance 医疗服务复杂性对临床质量改进实践的影响:一个医护人员手部卫生依从性的案例
IF 2.3 4区 管理学 Q2 Business, Management and Accounting Pub Date : 2023-03-24 DOI: 10.1287/serv.2023.0323
Wenlin Chen, C. Tseng, Cynthia Tseng
Healthcare providers often implement quality improvement (QI) practices to improve clinical quality, which may be measured as the extent to which healthcare workers (HCWs) comply with standardized procedures designed for ensuring patient safety. Unfortunately, the effectiveness of QI practices to improve clinical quality varies from facility to facility because of healthcare delivery complexity. In this paper, we consider the contextual complexity and the provider complexity arising from healthcare delivery processes, and we propose an exploratory study based on discrete choice experiments to examine their roles in the relationship between QI practices and clinical quality. By collecting and analyzing data from 320 HCWs at a university hospital in Taiwan, we found that healthcare delivery complexity significantly moderated the effectiveness of QI practices and how they improved clinical quality. We found that the contextual complexity influenced the level of effectiveness of the QI practices, whereas the provider complexity influenced whether a QI practice may be effective or not. We also studied the effect of implementing multiple QI practices simultaneously to counter the provider complexity. We found that implementing more QI practices does not necessarily lead to better outcomes, but implementing the right ones would. Our findings provide healthcare facilities with ex ante insights for designing QI practices to improve clinical quality. Funding: W. Chen was supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China [Grant 71902017], and C.-L. Tseng was supported by the University of New South Wales UNOVA Knowledge Hub. Supplemental Material: The online appendix is available at https://doi.org/10.1287/serv.2023.0323 .
医疗保健提供者经常实施质量改进(QI)实践来提高临床质量,这可以通过医疗保健工作者(HCWs)遵守为确保患者安全而设计的标准化程序的程度来衡量。不幸的是,由于医疗服务的复杂性,不同的医疗机构采用质量保证实践来提高临床质量的有效性各不相同。在本文中,我们考虑了医疗保健服务过程中产生的环境复杂性和提供者复杂性,并提出了一项基于离散选择实验的探索性研究,以检查它们在QI实践与临床质量之间的关系中的作用。通过收集和分析台湾某大学医院320名HCWs的数据,我们发现医疗服务的复杂性显著降低了QI实践的有效性以及它们如何提高临床质量。我们发现,上下文复杂性影响QI实践的有效性水平,而提供者复杂性影响QI实践是否有效。我们还研究了同时实现多个QI实践以对抗提供者复杂性的效果。我们发现实现更多的QI实践不一定会带来更好的结果,但是实现正确的实践会带来更好的结果。我们的研究结果为医疗机构提供了预先设计QI实践以提高临床质量的见解。基金资助:陈伟获国家自然科学基金[Grant 71902017]资助;曾教授得到了新南威尔士大学UNOVA知识中心的支持。补充材料:在线附录可在https://doi.org/10.1287/serv.2023.0323上获得。
{"title":"The Impact of Healthcare Delivery Complexity on Practices for Clinical Quality Improvement: A Case of Healthcare Workers’ Hand Hygiene Compliance","authors":"Wenlin Chen, C. Tseng, Cynthia Tseng","doi":"10.1287/serv.2023.0323","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1287/serv.2023.0323","url":null,"abstract":"Healthcare providers often implement quality improvement (QI) practices to improve clinical quality, which may be measured as the extent to which healthcare workers (HCWs) comply with standardized procedures designed for ensuring patient safety. Unfortunately, the effectiveness of QI practices to improve clinical quality varies from facility to facility because of healthcare delivery complexity. In this paper, we consider the contextual complexity and the provider complexity arising from healthcare delivery processes, and we propose an exploratory study based on discrete choice experiments to examine their roles in the relationship between QI practices and clinical quality. By collecting and analyzing data from 320 HCWs at a university hospital in Taiwan, we found that healthcare delivery complexity significantly moderated the effectiveness of QI practices and how they improved clinical quality. We found that the contextual complexity influenced the level of effectiveness of the QI practices, whereas the provider complexity influenced whether a QI practice may be effective or not. We also studied the effect of implementing multiple QI practices simultaneously to counter the provider complexity. We found that implementing more QI practices does not necessarily lead to better outcomes, but implementing the right ones would. Our findings provide healthcare facilities with ex ante insights for designing QI practices to improve clinical quality. Funding: W. Chen was supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China [Grant 71902017], and C.-L. Tseng was supported by the University of New South Wales UNOVA Knowledge Hub. Supplemental Material: The online appendix is available at https://doi.org/10.1287/serv.2023.0323 .","PeriodicalId":46249,"journal":{"name":"Service Science","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":2.3,"publicationDate":"2023-03-24","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"85708137","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"管理学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Health and Economic Impacts of Lockdown Policies in the Early Stage of COVID-19 in the United States 美国COVID-19早期封锁政策对健康和经济的影响
IF 2.3 4区 管理学 Q2 Business, Management and Accounting Pub Date : 2023-03-17 DOI: 10.1287/serv.2023.0321
Alireza Boloori, S. Saghafian
Lockdown policies, such as stay-at-home orders, are known to be effective in controlling the spread of the novel coronavirus disease 2019. However, concerns over economic burdens of these policies rapidly propelled U.S. states to move toward reopening in the early stage of the pandemic. Decision making in most states has been challenging, especially because of a dearth of quantitative evidence on health gains versus economic burdens of different policies. To assist decision makers, we study the health and economic impacts of various lockdown policies across U.S. states and shed light on policies that are most effective. To this end, we make use of detailed data from 50 U.S. states plus the District of Columbia on various factors, including number of tests, positive and negative results, hospitalizations, ICU beds and ventilators used, residents’ mobility obtained from cellphone data, and deaths. Our analyses allow quantifying the total cost versus the total quality-adjusted life year (QALY) associated with various lockdown policies. We utilize a compartmental model with Markov chain Monte Carlo simulation to estimate the spread of disease. To calibrate our model separately for each U.S. state, we make use of empirical data on the intensity of intervention policies, age, ratio of Black/Hispanic populations, per capita income, residents’ mobility, and number of daily tests and feed them to a longitudinal mixed-effect model. Finally, we utilize a microsimulation model to estimate the total cost and total QALY for each state and perform cost-effectiveness analysis to identify policies that would have worked best. Our results show that, compared with no intervention during March–June 2020, the policies undertaken across the United States saved, on average, about 41,284.51 years’ worth of QALY (per 100K capita), incurring $164.01 million (per 100K capita). Had the states undertaken more strict policies during the same time frame than those they adopted, these values would be 44,909.41 years and $117.28 million, respectively. By quantifying the impact of various lockdown policies separately for each state, our results allow federal and state authorities to avoid following a “one size fits all” strategy and instead enact policies that are better suited for each state. Specifically, by studying the trade-offs between health gains and economic impacts, we identify the particular states that would have benefited from implementing more restrictive policies. Finally, in addition to shedding light on the impact of lockdown policies during our study period (March–June 2020), our results have important implications on curbing future fast-spreading variants of the coronavirus or other related potential epidemics. Supplemental Material: The online appendix is available at https://doi.org/10.1287/serv.2023.0321 .
众所周知,居家令等封锁政策在控制2019年新型冠状病毒病的传播方面是有效的。然而,由于担心这些政策带来的经济负担,美国各州在疫情初期迅速转向重新开放。大多数州的决策一直具有挑战性,特别是因为缺乏关于不同政策的健康收益与经济负担的定量证据。为了帮助决策者,我们研究了美国各州各种封锁政策对健康和经济的影响,并阐明了最有效的政策。为此,我们利用了来自美国50个州和哥伦比亚特区的各种因素的详细数据,包括检测次数、阳性和阴性结果、住院情况、ICU床位和使用的呼吸机、从手机数据中获得的居民流动性以及死亡人数。我们的分析可以量化与各种封锁政策相关的总成本与总质量调整寿命年(QALY)。我们利用一个带有马尔可夫链蒙特卡罗模拟的室室模型来估计疾病的传播。为了分别为美国各州校准我们的模型,我们利用了干预政策强度、年龄、黑人/西班牙裔人口比例、人均收入、居民流动性和每日测试次数等经验数据,并将这些数据输入纵向混合效应模型。最后,我们利用微观模拟模型来估计每个州的总成本和总质量,并进行成本效益分析,以确定最有效的政策。我们的研究结果表明,与2020年3月至6月没有干预相比,美国各地采取的政策平均节省了约41,284.51年的QALY(每10万人均),产生了1.6401亿美元(每10万人均)。如果各州在同一时间段内采取比它们所采取的更严格的政策,这些价值将分别为44,909.41年和1.1728亿美元。通过分别量化各种封锁政策对每个州的影响,我们的研究结果使联邦和州当局能够避免遵循“一刀切”的策略,而是制定更适合每个州的政策。具体而言,通过研究健康收益和经济影响之间的权衡,我们确定了将从实施更多限制性政策中受益的特定州。最后,除了揭示我们研究期间(2020年3月至6月)封锁政策的影响外,我们的研究结果对遏制未来快速传播的冠状病毒变体或其他相关潜在流行病具有重要意义。补充材料:在线附录可在https://doi.org/10.1287/serv.2023.0321上获得。
{"title":"Health and Economic Impacts of Lockdown Policies in the Early Stage of COVID-19 in the United States","authors":"Alireza Boloori, S. Saghafian","doi":"10.1287/serv.2023.0321","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1287/serv.2023.0321","url":null,"abstract":"Lockdown policies, such as stay-at-home orders, are known to be effective in controlling the spread of the novel coronavirus disease 2019. However, concerns over economic burdens of these policies rapidly propelled U.S. states to move toward reopening in the early stage of the pandemic. Decision making in most states has been challenging, especially because of a dearth of quantitative evidence on health gains versus economic burdens of different policies. To assist decision makers, we study the health and economic impacts of various lockdown policies across U.S. states and shed light on policies that are most effective. To this end, we make use of detailed data from 50 U.S. states plus the District of Columbia on various factors, including number of tests, positive and negative results, hospitalizations, ICU beds and ventilators used, residents’ mobility obtained from cellphone data, and deaths. Our analyses allow quantifying the total cost versus the total quality-adjusted life year (QALY) associated with various lockdown policies. We utilize a compartmental model with Markov chain Monte Carlo simulation to estimate the spread of disease. To calibrate our model separately for each U.S. state, we make use of empirical data on the intensity of intervention policies, age, ratio of Black/Hispanic populations, per capita income, residents’ mobility, and number of daily tests and feed them to a longitudinal mixed-effect model. Finally, we utilize a microsimulation model to estimate the total cost and total QALY for each state and perform cost-effectiveness analysis to identify policies that would have worked best. Our results show that, compared with no intervention during March–June 2020, the policies undertaken across the United States saved, on average, about 41,284.51 years’ worth of QALY (per 100K capita), incurring $164.01 million (per 100K capita). Had the states undertaken more strict policies during the same time frame than those they adopted, these values would be 44,909.41 years and $117.28 million, respectively. By quantifying the impact of various lockdown policies separately for each state, our results allow federal and state authorities to avoid following a “one size fits all” strategy and instead enact policies that are better suited for each state. Specifically, by studying the trade-offs between health gains and economic impacts, we identify the particular states that would have benefited from implementing more restrictive policies. Finally, in addition to shedding light on the impact of lockdown policies during our study period (March–June 2020), our results have important implications on curbing future fast-spreading variants of the coronavirus or other related potential epidemics. Supplemental Material: The online appendix is available at https://doi.org/10.1287/serv.2023.0321 .","PeriodicalId":46249,"journal":{"name":"Service Science","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":2.3,"publicationDate":"2023-03-17","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"76131899","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"管理学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
The Dual Effects of Team Contest Design on On-Demand Service Work Schedules 团队竞赛设计对按需服务工作安排的双重影响
IF 2.3 4区 管理学 Q2 Business, Management and Accounting Pub Date : 2023-03-08 DOI: 10.1287/serv.2023.0320
Tingting Dong, Xiaotong Sun, Qi Luo, Jian Wang, Yafeng Yin
Emerging on-demand service platforms (OSPs) have recently embraced teamwork as a strategy for stimulating workers’ productivity and mediating temporal supply and demand imbalances. This research investigates the team contest scheme design problem considering work schedules. Introducing teams on OSPs creates a hierarchical single-leader multi-follower game. The leader (platform) establishes rewards and intrateam revenue-sharing rules for distributing workers’ payoffs. Each follower (team) competes with others by coordinating the schedules of its team members to maximize the total expected utility. The concurrence of interteam competition and intrateam coordination causes dual effects, which are captured by an equilibrium analysis of the followers’ game. To align the platform’s interest with workers’ heterogeneous working-time preferences, we propose a profit-maximizing contest scheme consisting of a winner’s reward and time-varying payments. A novel algorithm that combines Bayesian optimization, duality, and a penalty method solves the optimal scheme in the nonconvex equilibrium-constrained problem. Our results indicate that teamwork is a useful strategy with limitations. Under the proposed scheme, team contest always benefits workers. Intrateam coordination helps teams strategically mitigate the negative externalities caused by overcompetition among workers. For the platform, the optimal scheme can direct teams’ schedules toward more profitable market equilibria when workers have inaccurate perceptions of the market. History: This paper has been accepted for the Service Science Special Issue on Innovation in Transportation-Enabled Urban Services. Funding: This work was supported by the National Science Foundation [Grant FW-HTF-P 2222806]. Supplemental Material: The online appendices are available at https://doi.org/10.1287/serv.2023.0320 .
新兴的按需服务平台(ops)最近将团队合作作为一种策略,以刺激工人的生产力和调节暂时的供需失衡。本研究探讨了考虑工作时间安排的团队竞赛方案设计问题。在ops中引入团队将创造出一种分层的单领导者多追随者游戏。领导者(平台)建立奖励和团队内部收益分享规则,分配员工的报酬。每个追随者(团队)通过协调其团队成员的时间表来与其他成员竞争,以最大化总预期效用。团队内部竞争和团队内部协调的同时产生了双重效应,这通过对追随者博弈的均衡分析得到了体现。为了使平台的利益与工人的不同工作时间偏好保持一致,我们提出了一个利润最大化的竞赛方案,该方案由获胜者的奖励和随时间变化的支付组成。一种结合贝叶斯优化、对偶性和惩罚法的新算法解决了非凸均衡约束问题中的最优方案。我们的研究结果表明,团队合作是一种有用的策略,但存在局限性。在提议的方案下,团队竞赛总是有利于工人。团队内部协调有助于团队在战略上减轻员工之间过度竞争造成的负面外部性。对于该平台而言,当员工对市场的认知不准确时,最优方案可以将团队的日程安排引向更有利可图的市场均衡。历史:本文已被《服务科学》特刊《交通驱动城市服务创新》接受。基金资助:本研究由美国国家科学基金资助[Grant FW-HTF-P 2222806]。补充材料:在线附录可在https://doi.org/10.1287/serv.2023.0320上获得。
{"title":"The Dual Effects of Team Contest Design on On-Demand Service Work Schedules","authors":"Tingting Dong, Xiaotong Sun, Qi Luo, Jian Wang, Yafeng Yin","doi":"10.1287/serv.2023.0320","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1287/serv.2023.0320","url":null,"abstract":"Emerging on-demand service platforms (OSPs) have recently embraced teamwork as a strategy for stimulating workers’ productivity and mediating temporal supply and demand imbalances. This research investigates the team contest scheme design problem considering work schedules. Introducing teams on OSPs creates a hierarchical single-leader multi-follower game. The leader (platform) establishes rewards and intrateam revenue-sharing rules for distributing workers’ payoffs. Each follower (team) competes with others by coordinating the schedules of its team members to maximize the total expected utility. The concurrence of interteam competition and intrateam coordination causes dual effects, which are captured by an equilibrium analysis of the followers’ game. To align the platform’s interest with workers’ heterogeneous working-time preferences, we propose a profit-maximizing contest scheme consisting of a winner’s reward and time-varying payments. A novel algorithm that combines Bayesian optimization, duality, and a penalty method solves the optimal scheme in the nonconvex equilibrium-constrained problem. Our results indicate that teamwork is a useful strategy with limitations. Under the proposed scheme, team contest always benefits workers. Intrateam coordination helps teams strategically mitigate the negative externalities caused by overcompetition among workers. For the platform, the optimal scheme can direct teams’ schedules toward more profitable market equilibria when workers have inaccurate perceptions of the market. History: This paper has been accepted for the Service Science Special Issue on Innovation in Transportation-Enabled Urban Services. Funding: This work was supported by the National Science Foundation [Grant FW-HTF-P 2222806]. Supplemental Material: The online appendices are available at https://doi.org/10.1287/serv.2023.0320 .","PeriodicalId":46249,"journal":{"name":"Service Science","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":2.3,"publicationDate":"2023-03-08","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"80835294","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"管理学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Feeding the Nation—Dynamic Customer Contacting for E-Fulfillment in Times of Crisis 为危机时期的电子履行提供全国动态客户联系
4区 管理学 Q2 Business, Management and Accounting Pub Date : 2023-03-01 DOI: 10.1287/serv.2022.0304
Jonas Schwamberger, Moritz Fleischmann, Arne Strauss
The outbreak of the COVID-19 pandemic led demand for online grocery orders for both click & collect (C&C) and attended home delivery (AHD) to outstrip delivery capacity by a wide margin. In the United Kingdom, the booking systems of some e-retailers could not handle the flood of incoming requests, forcing the retailers to proactively reach out to certain priority customer segments with the aim of serving as many high-priority customers as possible. To determine when to contact each customer segment in this extraordinary demand environment, we investigate the new demand management concept of proactively contacting customers. We first develop a decision policy for the C&C fulfillment method to address the problem of when to contact customers. We then extend this approach to the AHD setting. To cope with increased problem complexity, we propose a three-step procedure to solve this problem. First, we subdivide the delivery area into smaller subareas; second, we select the most promising subareas; and third, we determine which customers to contact within the chosen subareas. To gain managerial insights and to show the practical benefits of our approaches, we apply both approaches to realistic data from the London area. Our results show that proactive customer contacting allows for a tailored allocation of scarce capacity in e-groceries. We conclude with a discussion on how these contacting techniques can be valuable in postcrisis times. History: This paper has been accepted for the Service Science Special Issue on Innovation in Transportation-Enabled Urban Services.
COVID-19大流行的爆发导致了对在线杂货订单的需求。托收(C&C)和上门送货(AHD)远远超过送货能力。在英国,一些电子零售商的预订系统无法处理大量涌入的请求,迫使零售商主动接触某些优先客户群,以服务尽可能多的高优先级客户。为了确定在这种特殊需求环境中何时与每个客户群体联系,我们研究了主动联系客户的新需求管理概念。我们首先为C&C履行方法制定决策政策,以解决何时与客户联系的问题。然后,我们将此方法扩展到AHD设置。为了应对日益增加的问题复杂性,我们提出了一个三步走的过程来解决这个问题。首先,我们将交付区域细分为更小的子区域;其次,我们选择最有前途的子领域;第三,我们决定在选定的子区域内联系哪些客户。为了获得管理见解并展示我们方法的实际好处,我们将这两种方法应用于伦敦地区的实际数据。我们的研究结果表明,积极主动的客户联系可以为电子杂货的稀缺容量提供量身定制的分配。最后,我们讨论了这些联系技术在后危机时代是如何有价值的。历史:本文已被《服务科学》特刊《交通驱动城市服务创新》接受。
{"title":"Feeding the Nation—Dynamic Customer Contacting for E-Fulfillment in Times of Crisis","authors":"Jonas Schwamberger, Moritz Fleischmann, Arne Strauss","doi":"10.1287/serv.2022.0304","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1287/serv.2022.0304","url":null,"abstract":"The outbreak of the COVID-19 pandemic led demand for online grocery orders for both click &amp; collect (C&amp;C) and attended home delivery (AHD) to outstrip delivery capacity by a wide margin. In the United Kingdom, the booking systems of some e-retailers could not handle the flood of incoming requests, forcing the retailers to proactively reach out to certain priority customer segments with the aim of serving as many high-priority customers as possible. To determine when to contact each customer segment in this extraordinary demand environment, we investigate the new demand management concept of proactively contacting customers. We first develop a decision policy for the C&amp;C fulfillment method to address the problem of when to contact customers. We then extend this approach to the AHD setting. To cope with increased problem complexity, we propose a three-step procedure to solve this problem. First, we subdivide the delivery area into smaller subareas; second, we select the most promising subareas; and third, we determine which customers to contact within the chosen subareas. To gain managerial insights and to show the practical benefits of our approaches, we apply both approaches to realistic data from the London area. Our results show that proactive customer contacting allows for a tailored allocation of scarce capacity in e-groceries. We conclude with a discussion on how these contacting techniques can be valuable in postcrisis times. History: This paper has been accepted for the Service Science Special Issue on Innovation in Transportation-Enabled Urban Services.","PeriodicalId":46249,"journal":{"name":"Service Science","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2023-03-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"135907509","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"管理学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Introduction to the Special Issue on Innovation in Transportation-Enabled Urban Services, Part 1 “交通驱动型城市服务创新”特刊导论,第一部分
IF 2.3 4区 管理学 Q2 Business, Management and Accounting Pub Date : 2023-03-01 DOI: 10.1287/serv.2023.0317
Niels A. H. Agatz, Soo-Haeng Cho, Hai Wang, S. Benjaafar
{"title":"Introduction to the Special Issue on Innovation in Transportation-Enabled Urban Services, Part 1","authors":"Niels A. H. Agatz, Soo-Haeng Cho, Hai Wang, S. Benjaafar","doi":"10.1287/serv.2023.0317","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1287/serv.2023.0317","url":null,"abstract":"","PeriodicalId":46249,"journal":{"name":"Service Science","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":2.3,"publicationDate":"2023-03-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"80477641","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"管理学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
期刊
Service Science
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1